-Caveat Lector-

from:
http://www.economist.com/1yffsV36/editorial/freeforall/current/index_ld5324.ht
ml
<A HREF="http://www.economist.com/">The Economist    </A>
-----
The new danger

FOR several decades the bogeyman for most rich economies has been
inflation. Policymakers began to fight it seriously 20 years ago, when
Paul Volcker, chairman of America’s Federal Reserve, dramatically
tightened monetary policy. Countries from Britain to Brazil then joined
the fray. With great success: the average inflation rate in the G7
economies is now a mere 1%, the lowest for half a century. But even as
the old enemy seems quiescent, a new and possibly more dangerous one may
be rising up: deflation.

This is not a claim that The Economist makes lightly. We have long urged
central banks on in their determination to resist inflation. And isn’t
the sign of a good central bank its willingness to turn a deaf ear to
calls for monetary expansion, whatever the circumstances? Actually, no.
The right target is broadly stable prices, which requires that a central
bank should be ready to attack deflation as fiercely as it does
inflation. Not only that, but a good central bank also keeps in mind
that deflation can be more damaging than inflation, if it creates a
downward spiral in which the expectation of falling prices reduces
demand and pushes prices lower still, as happened in the Great
Depression.

Seen it all before

In much of the world outside America, the risk of falling consumer
prices (ie, deflation) is at its greatest since the 1930s (see article) .
 Japan is already in the grip of deflation. Prices are falling in China
and some other parts of East Asia. Continental Europe’s inflation rate,
if correctly measured, is close to zero. Prices are coming down partly
thanks to the beneficial effects of new technology and deregulation, and
partly thanks to cheaper oil and other commodities. Such deflation is
generally benign. But alongside it are signs of a more malign deflation,
caused by excess capacity and weak demand. On current forecasts, the
global “output gap” between actual and potential production will, by the
end of 1999, be at its widest since the 1930s. If the economies of
America or Europe were now to take a sudden lurch downwards, the world
might easily experience outright depression, with prices and output
falling together, just as they did 70 years ago.

Given such a risk, monetary policy in the rich world, taken as a whole,
looks dangerously tight. Real interest rates are only slightly below
their long-term average, which hardly seems appropriate when growth is
so far below trend. Nominal GDP in the G7 economies is forecast to grow
this year by only 21/2%, virtually the slowest since the war and well
below what is required to sustain healthy growth with stable prices.
True, monetary policy has been eased since last summer, but the easing
has often come in the wrong places. The biggest drop in real interest
rates has been in America, where growth of almost 6% in the fourth
quarter of 1998 hardly points to imminent deflation. In a less gloomy
world the Fed might be raising rates to cool the economy. In contrast,
monetary easing has been more cautious in Japan and Europe, where the
danger of deflation is much more immediate.

Japan seems to be stuck in a classic liquidity trap: it needs lower real
interest rates to boost demand, but because of deflation they are stuck
painfully high. At the same time, government debt has exploded to a size
that makes fiscal policy less potent. Yet there is still another
instrument in the Bank of Japan’s tool-kit: it can increase the quantity
of money by buying government bonds—ie, by printing money. This solution
is not without its drawbacks (see article), and banks weighed down by
bad debts may still prove reluctant to lend more. But such a monetary
boost would push down the yen, and so both lift exports and push prices
up. Moreover, unless it is backed by monetary easing, Tokyo’s latest
policy twist (trying to talk down the yen) will simply not work.
The European Central Bank (ECB) also needs to relax more. In response to
pressure to cut rates from European politicians, notably Oskar
Lafontaine, Germany’s finance minister, the ECB has argued that its
rates are already at a historical low and that European unemployment is
structural, making it in the long run impervious to monetary policy. But
real rates are not in fact that low. And not all European unemployment
is structural—some is caused by economies operating below full
potential. Forecasts last year suggested that the euro-11 economies
would, on average, enjoy growth of almost 3% this year. But now most
economists reckon it will be no bigger than 2%, meaning that the euro
area’s output gap will widen. Given a risk that deflation is looming,
that seems to make it safe and prudent to cut interest rates further. If
Mr Lafontaine really wants this, however, he might be wise to shut up:
his demands are encouraging the ECB to delay any cut, to avoid seeming
to bow to political pressure.

Indeed, the Bank of Japan and the ECB are resisting an easing of
monetary policy partly for similar reasons. They fear that their
independence and credibility might be damaged. But to seek to keep
inflation above zero is hardly to risk hyperinflation. And central
banks’ credibility would suffer far more if they allowed deflation to
take root.

The world economy is precariously lop-sided. Even as America’s economy
continues to surge, much of the rest of the globe is drifting towards
deflation. It is scary that America’s boom, fuelled by an unsustainable
stockmarket, is now the main prop for global demand. For how much
longer? Global deflationary pressures are already choking American
profits, making its share prices look ever more overvalued. This could
yet topple the stockmarket. No wonder American policymakers are urging
Japan and Europe to reflate.

Most economists believe that a repeat of the 1930s is unlikely, if only
because people ought to have learned from their mistakes. Yet central
banks failed to foresee either the 1930s depression or the great
inflation of the 1970s. A big concern for the world economy may now be
that central bankers, having successfully scotched that inflation, will
prove too slow to come to grips with the prospect of deflation.

©1999 The Economist Newspaper Limited. All Rights Reserved.
-----
Aloha, He'Ping,
Om, Shalom, Salaam.
Em Hotep, Peace Be,
Omnia Bona Bonis,
All My Relations.
Adieu, Adios, Aloha.
Amen.
Roads End
Kris
=====
from:
http://www.economist.com/1yffsV36/editorial/freeforall/current/index_sf1223.ht
ml
<A HREF="http://www.economist.com/1yffsV36/editorial/freeforall/current/index_
sf1223.html">The Economist</A>
-----
Could it happen again?

For the past 25 years the biggest economic enemy in most countries has
been inflation. Today, in most of the world, a greater danger may be
deflation


MOST people take it for granted that prices will always rise, and
understandably so. A 60-year-old American has seen them go up by more
than 1,000% in his lifetime. Yet prolonged inflation is a recent
phenomenon. Until about 60 years ago prices in general were as likely to
fall as to rise. On the eve of the first world war, for example, prices
in Britain, overall, were almost exactly the same as they had been at
the time of the great fire of London in 1666.

Now the world may be reverting to that earlier normality. The prices of
many things have fallen over the past 12 months or so. Not only
computers and video players, whose prices have been declining for many
years, but a wide range of goods—from cars and clothes to coffee and
petrol—are, in many countries, cheaper than they were a year ago. It is
conceivable that the world may be in for a new period of global
deflation (meaning falling consumer prices) for the first time since the
1930s.

Talk of deflation is certainly at its highest level since then. The
number of newspaper articles mentioning the D-word is running at more
than 20 times the rate of a decade ago (see chart 1). Japan has been
flirting with deflation for several years, but the complaint may be
catching. Gary Shilling, an American economist, predicts in a new book*,
that American consumer prices will fall by an average of 1-2% a year
over the next decade. In Britain, the Centre for Economics and Business
Research expects to see falling prices by 2002. Several pundits reckon
that continental Europe is heading for deflation rather sooner.

Just how dangerous would that be? The answer is, it depends. In the
1930s, falling prices locked economies into a downward spiral, in which
shrinking demand, deepening pessimism, financial distress and the
apparent inability of governments to put things right led to economic
collapse. But deflation can also take a friendlier form—when it is
driven by rapid growth in productivity, for instance. Look around the
world, and you see both kinds of deflation at work, and in some places a
mixture of the two. That makes things horribly complicated for
policymakers.

A long way down

Almost wherever you look though, you see falling prices. The cost of raw
materials, for a start, is plunging. Oil prices have more than halved
since the start of 1997; in the past two years, The Economist’s index of
industrial-commodity prices has fallen by 30%. In real terms commodity
prices are at their lowest since this index was first published a
century and a half ago.

This long decline partly reflects technological progress that has
boosted crop yields and mineral-extraction rates. But the most recent
collapse in prices was largely triggered by the slump in East Asia, a
big importer of raw materials. Producers in Latin America, Russia and
South Africa have responded to lower prices by boosting output to keep
up export revenues, but this has pushed prices lower still.

Producer prices have also fallen over the past 12 months in 14 of the 15
rich industrial economies that The Economist monitors each week in its
indicator pages (see article). Currency devaluations in East Asia
released a flood of cheap manufactured goods on to world markets—to
which Brazil will now add. Thanks to enormous over-investment,
especially in Asia, the world is awash with excess capacity in computer
chips, steel, cars, textiles, ships and chemicals. The car industry, for
instance, is already reckoned to have at least 30% unused capacity
worldwide—yet new factories in Asia are still coming on stream.

Consumer-price inflation is also dropping, perhaps to an average of only
1% in the rich economies this year—the lowest for almost half a century
(see chart 2). Consumer prices have fallen over the past year in
Switzerland, Sweden, China, Hong Kong and Singapore. In the year to
January, China’s consumer prices fell by 1.2% and producer prices by 8%.

The Chinese government has responded by introducing price controls—not
to hold down prices, but to keep them up. As for Japan, its measured
consumer-price inflation is slightly positive, but this reflects a
distortion caused by a jump in food prices. In underlying terms,
Japanese consumer prices are falling.

Even in Brazil, once famed for hyperinflation, consumer prices (as
measured by Sao Paulo’s FIPE index) fell by 1.8% last year. The
devaluation of the real may now push up prices; but Brazil’s deflation
is likely to be exported to the rest of Latin America and beyond. And in
the euro area consumer prices have been falling since the summer,
although they are still up by 0.8% on a year ago. French and German in
flation rates are teetering on the brink of deflation, at 0.3% and 0.5%
respectively.

Official consumer-price indices in any case overstate inflation rates
because they fail to take full account of improvements over time in the
quality of goods (today’s cars or televisions have many more features
than 20 years ago), and because the weights given to different goods and
services tend to be out of date. The overstatement is usually reckoned
to be up to one percentage point a year. So any country with measured
inflation of less than 1% may, in reality, be experiencing falling
prices.

However, all these numbers need to be treated with care. “Deflation”,
like many economic concepts, is a widely misunderstood and often misused
term. Its proper definition is a persistent fall in the general price
level of goods and services; it is not to be confused with a decline in
prices in one economic sector, or with a fall in the inflation rate
(which is known as disinflation). Thus falling commodity prices do not,
of themselves, constitute deflation—they are a shift in relative prices
that reduces real incomes in producing countries and boosts them in
importing countries. Likewise a fall in manufacturing prices is not
deflation if it is offset by rising prices for services. In America, for
example, the average price of goods has fallen over the past year, but
the prices of services have risen by 2.5%, to produce an overall
(measured) consumer-price inflation rate of 1.6%.

Kill or cure

Deflation is not necessarily bad. Indeed, productivity-driven deflation,
in which costs and prices are pushed lower by technological advances or
by deregulation, is beneficial, because lower prices lift real incomes
and hence spending power. In the last 30 years of the 19th century, for
example, consumer prices fell by almost half in America, as the
expansion of railways and advances in industrial technology brought
cheaper ways to make everything; yet annual real growth over the period
averaged more than 4%.

Today, the computer and telecoms revolutions are similarly pushing down
costs. By reducing barriers to entry and making price information more
widely available, the Internet is pushing down the prices of goods
ranging from cars to books, and of services from insurance to air
travel. The arrival of Europe’s single currency will also increase price
competition in the euro area. A study by ING Barings concludes that this
might trim a quarter of a percentage point off the euro area’s annual
inflation rate over the next five years. Further downward pressure on
prices in Europe and Japan has also been caused by deregulation of
electricity and telephones. All these sources of deflation are good for
economies, not bad.

Deflation is dangerous, on the other hand, when it reflects a sharp
slump in demand, excess capacity and a shrinking money supply—as in the
early 1930s. In the four years to 1933, American consumer prices fell by
25% and real GDP by 30%. Runaway deflation of this sort can be much more
damaging than runaway inflation, because it creates a vicious spiral
that is hard to escape.

Thus, the expectation that prices will be lower tomorrow may encourage
consumers to delay purchases, depressing demand and forcing firms to cut
prices by even more. Falling prices also inflate the real burden of
debt, causing bankruptcies and bank failures. That makes deflation
particularly dangerous for economies that have large corporate debt—such
as Japan’s. Most serious of all, deflation can make monetary policy
ineffective: nominal interest rates cannot be negative, so real rates
can get stuck too high.

Today’s deflation comes in both benign and malign guises. New technology
and deregulation are pushing down prices of many goods and services
around the globe, which should be good for most economies. But weak
demand is also creating harmful deflationary pressures in some
countries. A good way to detect this is to look at countries’ “output
gaps”: the difference between actual output and output at full capacity.
Japan’s output gap is forecast to widen to a record 7% of GDP this year.
The country is on the brink of a vicious deflationary spiral, with
falling prices swelling companies’ real debts and keeping real interest
rates high. The rest of East Asia also has huge spare capacity. Even if
growth resumes this year, Thailand’s GDP is unlikely to regain its level
of 1996 until 2001. If so, output will in total have fallen by almost
one-third relative to productive potential (as measured by the economy’s
trend growth rate of 7%). Meanwhile, China has 40% excess capacity in
manufacturing.

None of this excess capacity is likely to be shut down quickly, because
cash-strapped firms have an incentive to keep factories running, even at
a loss, to generate income. The global glut is pushing prices
relentlessly lower. Devaluation cannot make excess capacity disappear;
it simply shifts the problem to somebody else. But in the process,
global demand will contract as emerging economies are forced to raise
interest rates to deter capital outflows.

The European Union has been running a modest, though persistent, output
gap of around 2% of GDP for several years, but this is likely to widen
in 1999 if, as widely forecast, growth falls below trend. The American
economy, in contrast, is running above its productive potential. Indeed,
without the recent fall in oil and commodity prices, America’s inflation
rate would have risen, forcing the Federal Reserve to raise interest
rates. America may be enjoying some deflation of the benign variety, as
a result of information technology and increased competition; but
booming consumer spending and double-digit money-supply growth suggest
that it will not, at least in the near future, suffer from malign
deflation.

Fear of falling

Only a handful of economies are clearly experiencing true deflation.
Even Japan, despite dreadful policy errors, has not experienced declines
in prices as bad as those in the 1930s. America and Europe have so far
benefited from cheaper import prices. Indeed, most countries are now
simply enjoying price stability. This should help, not harm future
growth. Yet the risk of outright deflation has clearly increased. A
sharp slowdown in America or Europe could easily send overall price
levels falling for the first time since the 1930s.

There are several causes for concern:

•  Global excess supply is unprecedentedly high. Output gaps are tricky
to measure, but The Economist’s best guess is that the world output gap
is approaching its biggest since the 1930s (see chart 3). Deflation
could occur even without a contraction in global output. All that is
needed is a protracted period of growth below trend, which causes the
output gap to widen and hence the inflation rate to fall, until it
eventually turns negative. Thus, even if Asia’s growth picks up this
year and next, but (as widely expected) remains below trend, the
region’s output gap will continue to widen.

•  Nominal GDP growth in the G7 economies looks set to fall this year to
around 2.5%—close to its slowest rate since the second world war.
(Japan’s nominal GDP fell by 3.4% in the year to the third quarter of
1998). This suggests that, on a global level, policy is too tight.
Ideally, in a developed economy, a central bank that has the medium-term
goal of price stability should aim for nominal GDP growth of 4-5%. This
allows room for long-term growth of 2-3% and inflation of 1-2%.

•  A third danger is that lower commodity prices, while boosting real
incomes in most rich economies, are hurting producers in the already
troubled emerging economies. This may not be a zero-sum game.
Cash-starved emerging economies are likely to cut spending faster than
rich countries spend their windfall.

•  But the biggest risk of all is a failure to adjust on the part of
policymakers, workers, companies and investors, all of whom are used to
coping with high inflation, not deflation. In past periods of benign
deflation, as in the late 19th century, everyone was used to the notion
of falling prices. But today, few have had any such experience—making
the risk of mistakes much greater.

For instance, in response to calls for lower interest rates, the
European Central Bank (like the Bank of Japan before it) has retorted
that European interest rates are already at record low levels. But real
interest rates, which rise as inflation falls, are nowhere near their
record lows.

Workers also need to learn the new rules of the game. If unions continue
to demand big annual wage increases—Germany’s IG Metall is currently
seeking a pay rise of 6.5%—despite flat or falling prices, firms may
have no alternative but to cut jobs. And falling goods prices could also
provoke trade friction. Cheaper imports of manufactured goods from Asia,
say, could trigger renewed protectionism in America and Europe, further
depressing world growth.

Deflation is especially painful for debtors. Not only does the real
burden of debt rise, but falling property prices also reduce the value
of collateral, forcing banks to write down debts. It is worrying,
therefore, argues Ian Harwood, an economist at Dresdner Kleinwort
Benson, that since deflation was last experienced on a global scale, the
level of private debt has risen sharply, thanks to a combination of
financial deregulation with years of inflation that made borrowing
attractive. Total private-sector debt is now around 130% of GDP in
America and 200% in Japan, compared with less than 100% of GDP in
America in 1928.

Companies too will find it hard to adjust to falling prices. Wages
rarely fall, so deflation tends to squeeze profit margins. This may
explain why surveys in Europe and America suggest that businessmen are
so much gloomier than consumers: deflation tends to be good news for
consumers, but bad news for companies. It is often easy to increase
profits by raising prices in inflationary times; when there is
deflation, the only way is to cut costs.

Deflation could be a particular problem for property, retailing and
financial markets. Inflationary times favour property investment:
inflation erodes the real value of a mortgage and delivers capital
gains. In a world of falling prices, buying a house becomes less
attractive than renting. Deflation also squeezes retailers’ profits,
because wages (a big chunk of total costs) are less flexible downwards
than prices. Retailers will also see volume and profit margins squeezed
as consumers delay purchases in the hope that prices will fall.
As for financial markets, consider only the alarming gap between
investors’ expectations of American profits, which are said to support
current share prices on Wall Street, and the more likely actual path of
profits as global deflationary pressures squeeze American firms. Total
American profits have already fallen slightly over the past year.
Indeed this could be the factor that finally bursts America’s
stockmarket bubble. And when that happens, and America’s
consumer-spending boom goes into reverse, the economy could quickly be
dragged into recession, increasing the risk that the world as a whole
might tip into a period of outright deflation or even slump.

Time to reflate

There seems little likelihood that prices will ever fall by anything
like as much as in the 1930s. Prices and wages are today much stickier,
especially in services (which account for a far bigger chunk of
economies), and policymakers reckon, post-Keynes, that they now
understand better how to use monetary and fiscal weapons to prevent
deflation. Yet Japan shows that the threat of deflation is real even in
a modern economy if policymakers blunder.

Inflation, as Milton Friedman once said, “is always and everywhere a
monetary phenomenon”. So it is with deflation. It can be prevented by
appropriate policies. Overly tight monetary policies, and the
straitjacket imposed by the gold standard, were largely to blame for the
prolonged deflation in the 1930s.

So how to respond to today’s deflationary risks? The widening output gap
and sluggish nominal GDP growth are both signals that monetary policy in
the G7 economies, taken as a whole, is too tight. Not in America,
certainty; but both Europe and Japan are operating below normal
capacity. Yet oddly, as John Makin, an economist at the American
Enterprise Institute, points out, these economies have done less to ease
monetary policy since the middle of last year than America, whose
economy least needed a boost.

Japan’s monetary conditions have, in effect, tightened as a result of
higher bond yields and a stronger yen, though policymakers are trying to
reverse these. In the euro area, nominal short-term interest rates have
been cut, but real rates are barely any lower than they were last June,
because inflation has fallen. American real interest rates, in contrast,
have fallen by two-thirds of a percentage point.

The world economy is, in short, precariously balanced on the edge of a
deflationary precipice. Policymakers still have ample time to use their
monetary and fiscal weapons to prevent deflation. The danger for some
central bankers is that, having for now seen off the threat of
inflation, they rest on their laurels and fail to confront the
possibility of deflation. That would be foolish indeed. For history has
shown that once deflation takes hold, it can be far more damaging than
inflation.

* “Deflation”, by Gary Shilling, Lakeview Publishing Company.

©1999 The Economist Newspaper Limited. All Rights Reserved.
-----
Aloha, He'Ping,
Om, Shalom, Salaam.
Em Hotep, Peace Be,
Omnia Bona Bonis,
All My Relations.
Adieu, Adios, Aloha.
Amen.
Roads End
Kris

DECLARATION & DISCLAIMER
==========
CTRL is a discussion and informational exchange list. Proselyzting propagandic
screeds are not allowed. Substance—not soapboxing!  These are sordid matters
and 'conspiracy theory', with its many half-truths, misdirections and outright
frauds is used politically  by different groups with major and minor effects
spread throughout the spectrum of time and thought. That being said, CTRL
gives no endorsement to the validity of posts, and always suggests to readers;
be wary of what you read. CTRL gives no credeence to Holocaust denial and
nazi's need not apply.

Let us please be civil and as always, Caveat Lector.
========================================================================
Archives Available at:
http://home.ease.lsoft.com/archives/CTRL.html

http:[EMAIL PROTECTED]/
========================================================================
To subscribe to Conspiracy Theory Research List[CTRL] send email:
SUBSCRIBE CTRL [to:] [EMAIL PROTECTED]

To UNsubscribe to Conspiracy Theory Research List[CTRL] send email:
SIGNOFF CTRL [to:] [EMAIL PROTECTED]

Om

Reply via email to