It turns that real live voters (including real live politicians) care a lot about the later-no-harm criterion, even if they don't know what it's called.

--Bob Richard


On 7/7/2011 3:43 PM, Juho Laatu wrote:
I actually already touched this question in another mail. And the argument was that (in two-party 
countries) IRV is not as risky risky from the two leading parties' point of view as methods that 
are more "compromise candidate oriented" (instead of being "first preference 
oriented"). I think that is one reason, but it is hard to estimate how important.

Juho



On 7.7.2011, at 23.56, Jameson Quinn wrote:

Russ's message about simplicity is well-taken. But the most successful voting 
reform is IRV - which is far from being the simplest reform. Why has IRV been 
successful?

I want to leave this as an open question for others before I try to answer it myself. The 
one answer which wouldn't be useful would be "Because CVD (now FairVote) was looking 
for a single-winner version of STV". There's a bit of truth there, but it's a long 
way from the whole truth, and we want to find lessons we can learn from moving forward, 
not useless historical accidents.

JQ
----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info
----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


--
Bob Richard
Executive Vice President
Californians for Electoral Reform
PO Box 235
Kentfield, CA 94914-0235
415-256-9393
http://www.cfer.org

----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to