At 02:52 PM 5/29/2013, David L Wetzell wrote:
Also, the bottom line is that when you're advocating for a change in which single-winner election rule alternative ought to be used, it's not right to dump the burden of proof on IRV advocates. The amount of time spent marketing IRV already is a sunk cost and so the burden of proof for switching ought to lie on the challengers not the defenders of the status quo progressive electoral alternative to fptp.

Sunk cost for you, David. The rest of us are singularly unimpressed. We didn't ask you to spend that time and money. Voting systems scientists have been advising strongly against the method you adopted since the 19th century.

The voting system community, including *many* former IRV supporters and even FairVote activists, settled on a first voting system reform propoosal, not as the "ideal voting system," but as a do-no-harm improvement, Count All the Votes. I.e,. Approval Voting.

It will not fix all problems. But it costs almost nothing.

It has an obvious problem, but that problem only arises because, with it, voters who support a minor party will be able to express a vote for their favorite party, and all analysts agree that they will do this, it is strategically sound. Approval always allows voting for your favorite.

However, once voters can do this, they will *also* want to be able to express a preference for their favorite, which they cannot do in Approval where they choose to support, say, their minor party favorite and to cast a vote in the major election.

This is the problem that IRV solves. However, the problem was solved long ago, with a voting system that does not have IRV's serious malfunctions: Bucklin. It's ranked approval voting. It actually uses a truncated Range ballot, this has often been missed by analysts. A voter who has a strong preference can skip ranks to express it, causing the second preference vote to show up in a later round of canvassing. I call that "Limited Later-no-Harm protection." Voters will use this -- or bullet vote -- depending on preference strength, which is precisely how the system performs well in utility evaluations.

Bucklin was oversold, as was IRV recently, as a way to guarantee majorities. No voting system can do that except by restricting the freedom of the voter, in which case the majority is coerced or artificial. However, in contested public elections, Bucklin *did* find majorities even with many candidates on the ballot. Later, in party primary elections, with many candidates and bullet voting rates approaching 90%, it didn't find majorities. In that context, runoff voting makes *much more sense,* because what voters need is *information.* It's not about Later-no-Harm failure, an old speculation that FairVote enshrined as being The Reason why Bucklin didn't find majorities. And, given that, what would really have made sense would have been a Bucklin primary, with intelligent choice of runoff candidates if needed. And maybe a Bucklin runoff; with an advanced voting system, finding a optimal winner with three candidates should be possible.

Bucklin is *vastly* easier to canvass than IRV, it is just sums of votes.

So, David, sunk cost is also water under the bridge. What you have left is an organization with some established reputation. How you use that will determine if all the cost is truly sunk, or there is something that can be salvaged and used to build a brighter future.
----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to