---------- Forwarded message ----------
Date: Sun, 23 Aug 1998 22:53:38 -0400 (EDT)
From: Robert Weissman <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
To: Multiple recipients of list STOP-IMF <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
Subject: FT/Martin Wolf: Exchange Rate Regimes in a Fix

Financial Times
WEDNESDAY AUGUST 19 1998  

Columnists 
Martin Wolf

EXCHANGE RATES: Regimes in a fix

Adjustable exchange rates and free capital flows do not mix. If crises are to
be avoided, countries must choose between them

<Picture: Graph>Some countries devalue; others default. Few do both on the
same day. Never inclined to do things by halves, the Russians are the
exception.


By combining a devaluation with a forced restructuring of domestic debt,
imposition of capital controls and a 90-day moratorium on foreign commercial
debts, the Russian authorities have sacrificed their stabilisation policy and
initiated a general default. In just one day, the fruit of the long effort to
give Russia a stable currency and win a reputation for financial reliability
has, it appears, been thrown away (see opposite).


Whatever the direct repercussions turn out to be for Russia and the world at
large, this failure underlines and amplifies lessons that must be drawn from
all the crises of the past 14 months.


First, the International Monetary Fund cannot eliminate the confidence crises
to which adjustable peg exchange-rate regimes are so prone.


Second, attempts to operate such regimes in the absence of tight controls on
capital inflows and strong regulation of domestic financial system have
potentially devastating effects on economic stability.


Third, for particular countries, the choices of regime break down into a
freely floating exchange rate or a currency board (without capital controls)
or pegged exchange rates (with them).


Finally, if there is to be a world with pegged exchange rates, but no capital
controls, there must also be a true international lender of last resort.


Consider each of these points in turn.


On the first, only last month the IMF agreed to a $23bn support package for
Russia. The main purpose was to increase confidence in the government's
ability and willingness to service debt and maintain the exchange rate.


Although that lack of confidence had, at its root, the political, financial
and economic frailties of the country, it was also self-fulfilling: the
extraordinarily high interest rates (of well over 100 per cent in real terms)
that the government was forced to offer undermined credibility rather than
reinforced it.


This package has failed. When a borrower has to cope with a run, it needs a
lender of last resort able to supply the desired funds without limit. But the
IMF can never provide funds in this way. Worse, what it does provide is
available only in tranches, with the delivery of each depending on the
borrower's ability to satisfy demanding conditions. Thus the new funds are not
merely limited in aggregate, but the chances of delivery are also uncertain.


Any exceptionally large IMF programme is therefore more likely to convince
creditors of the extent of the crisis than persuade them to wait while it is
resolved. As the IMF's money comes in the front door, creditors leave by the
back, carrying as many sacks as they can.


IMF funds will always be both limited and subject to tough conditions. It is
difficult enough to get the money from legislators, particularly the US
Congress. It would be impossible to do so without the promise of tough
conditionality. Yet this means that the IMF is unable to remedy a crisis of
confidence in an adjustable-peg regime that is not buttressed by effective
controls on capital inflows and outflows.


Turn, then, to the second point. The failure of an adjustable-peg regime can,
as the chart indicates, be devastating. Currencies are prone to collapse. The
principal reason for this, powerfully demonstrated in east Asia and likely to
prove true in Russia as well, is that the devaluation validates one side of
what were previously highly divergent expectations.


When governments implement pegged exchange rates over a reasonably lengthy
period, some investors will start trusting them, while others will not.
Believers are likely to look at interest rates abroad and compare them with
often much higher interest rates at home and decide to borrow in foreign
currency and lend at home. Behind such divergences often lie efforts by the
monetary authorities to target the exchange rate and curb domestic credit
expansion at one and the same time.


This form of speculation is precisely what financial institutions and private
companies did in Thailand, Indonesia and South Korea. They borrowed abroad,
under what they thought would be a stable exchange rate, to replace expensive
borrowing at home. For these borrowers, devaluation is devastating.
Institutions that have borrowed foreign exchange find themselves cut off from
further credit. They have to sell domestic assets to obtain foreign currency.
The currency falls, exacerbating speculation against it, and spreading
insolvency throughout the private sector. This is what lay behind the
devastating collapse of east-Asian currencies.


The danger explains the third point. Where capital flows are uncontrolled -
and implicit and explicit speculation correspondingly easy - governments have
to avoid potentially expensive divergences in expectations about their future
policies. They need to establish a clear and over-riding exchange rate regime,
buttressed by robust flanking policies for the budget and financial
regulation. Of the alternatives only free floating and currency boards pass
muster.


Under free floating, a country must establish stable inflation. The best way
to achieve this is via an independent central bank with an inflation target.
For small countries, or countries unable to establish autonomous domestic
institutions, the alternative is a currency board. In this, the country's cash
is fully backed by foreign currency, and exchange between the two is at an
irrevocably fixed rate. Autonomous monetary policy is then eliminated.


If it is impossible for a country to make any commitment to monetary
stability, neither alternative will work. But an intermediate policy will also
fail, as Russian experience demonstrates. After this latest debacle, the case
made by Steve Hanke of the Johns Hopkins University for a currency board needs
consideration, even in the case of Russia.* It may be impossible to make such
a disciplined system work there. But it is difficult to see what else will.


The point can be turned round. If a country wants the flexibility of an
adjustable-peg regime, it cannot also allow free speculation on the durability
of the rate. It must have some control over capital flows. The old Bretton
Woods system was logical. With exchange controls, that regime was manageable.
Without them, it was not.


Finally, all this also says something important about the aim of putting
capital account convertibility into the IMF's articles. There is a case for
this. But one must also insist that countries have exchange-rate regimes,
fiscal policies and a system of financial regulation fully consistent with
such freedom. Alternatively, there must be an international lender of last
resort capable of supplying enough money to deal with the inevitable crises of
confidence.


Indeed, it is very likely that there will need to be both, particularly if
emerging market economies, with all their economic, political and financial
weaknesses, are to take the recommended plunge. The alternative is one ruinous
financial crisis after another. Russia's is just the latest in a long line. It
is not going to be the last.


Steve H. Hanke, Lars Jonung and Kurt Schuler, Russian Currency and Finance: a
Currency Board Approach to Reform, London, Routledge, 1993.




Reply via email to