>Resent-Date: Wed, 12 Apr 2000 11:53:04 +0200 >X-Authentication-Warning: emiliano.ras.eu.org: list set sender to >[EMAIL PROTECTED] using -f >Reply-To: "Laurent JESOVER" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> >From: "Laurent JESOVER" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> >To: "ATTAC LISTE WELCOME" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> >Date: Wed, 12 Apr 2000 11:56:56 +0200 >Organization: ATTAC >MIME-Version: 1.0 >X-Priority: 3 >X-MSMail-Priority: Normal >X-MimeOLE: Produced By Microsoft MimeOLE V5.00.2314.1300 >Subject: [ATTAC CHAT] What I learned at the world economic crisis. >Resent-From: [EMAIL PROTECTED] >X-Mailing-List: <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> archive/latest/646 >X-Loop: [EMAIL PROTECTED] >Precedence: list >Resent-Sender: [EMAIL PROTECTED] > >What I learned at the world economic crisis. >The Insider > >By JOSEPH STIGLITZ >Issue date: 04.17.00 >Post date: 04.06.00 > > >Next week's meeting of the International Monetary Fund will bring to >Washington, D.C., many of the same demonstrators who trashed the World >Trade Organization in Seattle last fall. They'll say the IMF is >arrogant. They'll say the IMF doesn't really listen to the developing >countries it is supposed to help. They'll say the IMF is secretive and >insulated from democratic accountability. They'll say the IMF's >economic "remedies" often make things worse--turning slowdowns into >recessions and recessions into depressions. > >And they'll have a point. I was chief economist at the World Bank from >1996 until last November, during the gravest global economic crisis in >a half-century. I saw how the IMF, in tandem with the U.S. Treasury >Department, responded. And I was appalled. > >The global economic crisis began in Thailand, on July 2, 1997. The >countries of East Asia were coming off a miraculous three decades: >incomes had soared, health had improved, poverty had fallen >dramatically. Not only was literacy now universal, but, on >international science and math tests, many of these countries >outperformed the United States. Some had not suffered a single year of >recession in 30 years. > >But the seeds of calamity had already been planted. In the early '90s, >East Asian countries had liberalized their financial and capital >markets--not because they needed to attract more funds (savings rates >were already 30 percent or more) but because of international >pressure, including some from the U.S. Treasury Department. These >changes provoked a flood of short-term capital--that is, the kind of >capital that looks for the highest return in the next day, week, or >month, as opposed to long-term investment in things like factories. In >Thailand, this short-term capital helped fuel an unsustainable real >estate boom. And, as people around the world (including Americans) >have painfully learned, every real estate bubble eventually bursts, >often with disastrous consequences. Just as suddenly as capital flowed >in, it flowed out. And, when everybody tries to pull their money out >at the same time, it causes an economic problem. A big economic >problem. > >The last set of financial crises had occurred in Latin America in the >1980s, when bloated public deficits and loose monetary policies led to >runaway inflation. There, the IMF had correctly imposed fiscal >austerity (balanced budgets) and tighter monetary policies, demanding >that governments pursue those policies as a precondition for receiving >aid. So, in 1997 the IMF imposed the same demands on Thailand. >Austerity, the fund's leaders said, would restore confidence in the >Thai economy. As the crisis spread to other East Asian nations--and >even as evidence of the policy's failure mounted--the IMF barely >blinked, delivering the same medicine to each ailing nation that >showed up on its doorstep. > >I thought this was a mistake. For one thing, unlike the Latin American >nations, the East Asian countries were already running budget >surpluses. In Thailand, the government was running such large >surpluses that it was actually starving the economy of much-needed >investments in education and infrastructure, both essential to >economic growth. And the East Asian nations already had tight monetary >policies, as well: inflation was low and falling. (In South Korea, for >example, inflation stood at a very respectable four percent.) The >problem was not imprudent government, as in Latin America; the problem >was an imprudent private sector--all those bankers and borrowers, for >instance, who'd gambled on the real estate bubble. > >Under such circumstances, I feared, austerity measures would not >revive the economies of East Asia--it would plunge them into recession >or even depression. High interest rates might devastate highly >indebted East Asian firms, causing more bankruptcies and defaults. >Reduced government expenditures would only shrink the economy further. > >So I began lobbying to change the policy. I talked to Stanley Fischer, >a distinguished former Massachusetts Institute of Technology economics >professor and former chief economist of the World Bank, who had become >the IMF's first deputy managing director. I met with fellow economists >at the World Bank who might have contacts or influence within the IMF, >encouraging them to do everything they could to move the IMF >bureaucracy. > >Convincing people at the World Bank of my analysis proved easy; >changing minds at the IMF was virtually impossible. When I talked to >senior officials at the IMF--explaining, for instance, how high >interest rates might increase bankruptcies, thus making it even harder >to restore confidence in East Asian economies--they would at first >resist. Then, after failing to come up with an effective >counterargument, they would retreat to another response: if only I >understood the pressure coming from the IMF board of executive >directors--the body, appointed by finance ministers from the advanced >industrial countries, that approves all the IMF's loans. Their meaning >was clear. The board's inclination was to be even more severe; these >people were actually a moderating influence. My friends who were >executive directors said they were the ones getting pressured. It was >maddening, not just because the IMF's inertia was so hard to stop but >because, with everything going on behind closed doors, it was >impossible to know who was the real obstacle to change. Was the staff >pushing the executive directors, or were the executive directors >pushing the staff? I still do not know for certain. > >Of course, everybody at the IMF assured me they would be flexible: if >their policies really turned out to be overly contractionary, forcing >the East Asian economies into deeper recession than necessary, then >they would reverse them. This sent shudders down my spine. One of the >first lessons economists teach their graduate students is the >importance of lags: it takes twelve to 18 months before a change in >monetary policy (raising or lowering interest rates) shows its full >effects. When I worked in the White House as chairman of the Council >of Economic Advisers, we focused all our energy on forecasting where >the economy would be in the future, so we could know what policies to >recommend today. To play catch-up was the height of folly. And that >was precisely what the IMF officials were proposing to do. > >I shouldn't have been surprised. The IMF likes to go about its >business without outsiders asking too many questions. In theory, the >fund supports democratic institutions in the nations it assists. In >practice, it undermines the democratic process by imposing policies. >Officially, of course, the IMF doesn't "impose" anything. It >"negotiates" the conditions for receiving aid. But all the power in >the negotiations is on one side--the IMF's--and the fund rarely allows >sufficient time for broad consensus-building or even widespread >consultations with either parliaments or civil society. Sometimes the >IMF dispenses with the pretense of openness altogether and negotiates >secret covenants. > >When the IMF decides to assist a country, it dispatches a "mission" of >economists. These economists frequently lack extensive experience in >the country; they are more likely to have firsthand knowledge of its >five-star hotels than of the villages that dot its countryside. They >work hard, poring over numbers deep into the night. But their task is >impossible. In a period of days or, at most, weeks, they are charged >with developing a coherent program sensitive to the needs of the >country. Needless to say, a little number-crunching rarely provides >adequate insights into the development strategy for an entire nation. >Even worse, the number-crunching isn't always that good. The >mathematical models the IMF uses are frequently flawed or out-of-date. >Critics accuse the institution of taking a cookie-cutter approach to >economics, and they're right. Country teams have been known to compose >draft reports before visiting. I heard stories of one unfortunate >incident when team members copied large parts of the text for one >country's report and transferred them wholesale to another. They might >have gotten away with it, except the "search and replace" function on >the word processor didn't work properly, leaving the original >country's name in a few places. Oops. > >It's not fair to say that IMF economists don't care about the citizens >of developing nations. But the older men who staff the fund--and they >are overwhelmingly older men--act as if they are shouldering Rudyard >Kipling's white man's burden. IMF experts believe they are brighter, >more educated, and less politically motivated than the economists in >the countries they visit. In fact, the economic leaders from those >countries are pretty good--in many cases brighter or better-educated >than the IMF staff, which frequently consists of third-rank students >from first-rate universities. (Trust me: I've taught at Oxford >University, MIT, Stanford University, Yale University, and Princeton >University, and the IMF almost never succeeded in recruiting any of >the best students.) Last summer, I gave a seminar in China on >competition policy in telecommunications. At least three Chinese >economists in the audience asked questions as sophisticated as the >best minds in the West would have asked. > >As time passed, my frustration mounted. (One might have thought that >since the World Bank was contributing literally billions of dollars to >the rescue packages, its voice would be heard. But it was ignored >almost as resolutely as the people in the affected countries.) The IMF >claimed that all it was asking of the East Asian countries was that >they balance their budgets at a time of recession. All? Hadn't the >Clinton administration just fought a major battle with Congress to >stave off a balanced-budget amendment in this country? And wasn't the >administration's key argument that, in the face of recession, a little >deficit spending might be necessary? This is what I and most other >economists had been teaching our graduate students for 60 years. Quite >frankly, a student who turned in the IMF's answer to the test question >"What should be the fiscal stance of Thailand, facing an economic >downturn?" would have gotten an F. > >As the crisis spread to Indonesia, I became even more concerned. New >research at the World Bank showed that recession in such an ethnically >divided country could spark all kinds of social and political turmoil. >So in late 1997, at a meeting of finance ministers and central-bank >governors in Kuala Lumpur, I issued a carefully prepared statement >vetted by the World Bank: I suggested that the excessively >contractionary monetary and fiscal program could lead to political and >social turmoil in Indonesia. Again, the IMF stood its ground. The >fund's managing director, Michel Camdessus, said there what he'd said >in public: that East Asia simply had to grit it out, as Mexico had. He >went on to note that, for all of the short-term pain, Mexico emerged >from the experience stronger. > > >But this was an absurd analogy. Mexico hadn't recovered because the >IMF forced it to strengthen its weak financial system, which remained >weak years after the crisis. It recovered because of a surge of >exports to the United States, which took off thanks to the U.S. >economic boom, and because of nafta. By contrast, Indonesia's main >trading partner was Japan--which was then, and still remains, mired in >the doldrums. Furthermore, Indonesia was far more politically and >socially explosive than Mexico, with a much deeper history of ethnic >strife. And renewed strife would produce massive capital flight (made >easy by relaxed currency-flow restrictions encouraged by the IMF). But >none of these arguments mattered. The IMF pressed ahead, demanding >reductions in government spending. And so subsidies for basic >necessities like food and fuel were eliminated at the very time when >contractionary policies made those subsidies more desperately needed >than ever. > >By January 1998, things had gotten so bad that the World Bank's vice >president for East Asia, Jean Michel Severino, invoked the dreaded >r-word ("recession") and d-word ("depression") in describing the >economic calamity in Asia. Lawrence Summers, then deputy treasury >secretary, railed against Severino for making things seem worse than >they were, but what other way was there to describe what was >happening? Output in some of the affected countries fell 16 percent or >more. Half the businesses in Indonesia were in virtual bankruptcy or >close to it, and, as a result, the country could not even take >advantage of the export opportunities the lower exchange rates >provided. Unemployment soared, increasing as much as tenfold, and real >wages plummeted--in countries with basically no safety nets. Not only >was the IMF not restoring economic confidence in East Asia, it was >undermining the region's social fabric. And then, in the spring and >summer of 1998, the crisis spread beyond East Asia to the most >explosive country of all--Russia. > >The calamity in Russia shared key characteristics with the calamity in >East Asia--not least among them the role that IMF and U.S. Treasury >policies played in abetting it. But, in Russia, the abetting began >much earlier. Following the fall of the Berlin Wall, two schools of >thought had emerged concerning Russia's transition to a market >economy. One of these, to which I belonged, consisted of a melange of >experts on the region, Nobel Prize winners like Kenneth Arrow and >others. This group emphasized the importance of the institutional >infrastructure of a market economy--from legal structures that enforce >contracts to regulatory structures that make a financial system work. >Arrow and I had both been part of a National Academy of Sciences group >that had, a decade earlier, discussed with the Chinese their >transition strategy. We emphasized the importance of fostering >competition--rather than just privatizing state-owned industries--and >favored a more gradual transition to a market economy (although we >agreed that occasional strong measures might be needed to combat >hyperinflation). > >The second group consisted largely of macroeconomists, whose faith in >the market was unmatched by an appreciation of the subtleties of its >underpinnings--that is, of the conditions required for it to work >effectively. These economists typically had little knowledge of the >history or details of the Russian economy and didn't believe they >needed any. The great strength, and the ultimate weakness, of the >economic doctrines upon which they relied is that the doctrines >are--or are supposed to be--universal. Institutions, history, or even >the distribution of income simply do not matter. Good economists know >the universal truths and can look beyond the array of facts and >details that obscure these truths. And the universal truth is that >shock therapy works for countries in transition to a market economy: >the stronger the medicine (and the more painful the reaction), the >quicker the recovery. Or so the argument goes. > >Unfortunately for Russia, the latter school won the debate in the >Treasury Department and in the IMF. Or, to be more accurate, the >Treasury Department and the IMF made sure there was no open debate and >then proceeded blindly along the second route. Those who opposed this >course were either not consulted or not consulted for long. On the >Council of Economic Advisers, for example, there was a brilliant >economist, Peter Orszag, who had served as a close adviser to the >Russian government and had worked with many of the young economists >who eventually assumed positions of influence there. He was just the >sort of person whose expertise Treasury and the IMF needed. Yet, >perhaps because he knew too much, they almost never consulted him. > >We all know what happened next. In the December 1993 elections, >Russian voters dealt the reformers a huge setback, a setback from >which they have yet really to recover. Strobe Talbott, then in charge >of the noneconomic aspects of Russia policy, admitted that Russia had >experienced "too much shock and too little therapy." And all that >shock hadn't moved Russia toward a real market economy at all. The >rapid privatization urged upon Moscow by the IMF and the Treasury >Department had allowed a small group of oligarchs to gain control of >state assets. The IMF and Treasury had rejiggered Russia's economic >incentives, all right--but the wrong way. By paying insufficient >attention to the institutional infrastructure that would allow a >market economy to flourish--and by easing the flow of capital in and >out of Russia--the IMF and Treasury had laid the groundwork for the >oligarchs' plundering. While the government lacked the money to pay >pensioners, the oligarchs were sending money obtained by stripping >assets and selling the country's precious national resources into >Cypriot and Swiss bank accounts. > >The United States was implicated in these awful developments. In >mid-1998, Summers, soon to be named Robert Rubin's successor as >secretary of the treasury, actually made a public display of appearing >with Anatoly Chubais, the chief architect of Russia's privatization. >In so doing, the United States seemed to be aligning itself with the >very forces impoverishing the Russian people. No wonder >antiAmericanism spread like wildfire. > >At first, Talbott's admission notwithstanding, the true believers at >Treasury and the IMF continued to insist that the problem was not too >much therapy but too little shock. But, through the mid-'90s, the >Russian economy continued to implode. Output plummeted by half. While >only two percent of the population had lived in poverty even at the >end of the dismal Soviet period, "reform" saw poverty rates soar to >almost 50 percent, with more than half of Russia's children living >below the poverty line. Only recently have the IMF and Treasury >conceded that therapy was undervalued--though they now insist they >said so all along. > >Today, Russia remains in desperate shape. High oil prices and the >long-resisted ruble devaluation have helped it regain some footing. >But standards of living remain far below where they were at the start >of the transition. The nation is beset by enormous inequality, and >most Russians, embittered by experience, have lost confidence in the >free market. A significant fall in oil prices would almost certainly >reverse what modest progress has been made. > >East Asia is better off, though it still struggles, too. Close to 40 >percent of Thailand's loans are still not performing; Indonesia >remains deeply mired in recession. Unemployment rates remain far >higher than they were before the crisis, even in East Asia's >best-performing country, Korea. IMF boosters suggest that the >recession's end is a testament to the effectiveness of the agency's >policies. Nonsense. Every recession eventually ends. All the IMF did >was make East Asia's recessions deeper, longer, and harder. Indeed, >Thailand, which followed the IMF's prescriptions the most closely, has >performed worse than Malaysia and South Korea, which followed more >independent courses. > > >I was often asked how smart--even brilliant--people could have created >such bad policies. One reason is that these smart people were not >using smart economics. Time and again, I was dismayed at how >out-of-date--and how out-of-tune with reality--the models Washington >economists employed were. For example, microeconomic phenomena such as >bankruptcy and the fear of default were at the center of the East >Asian crisis. But the macroeconomic models used to analyze these >crises were not typically rooted in microfoundations, so they took no >account of bankruptcy. > >But bad economics was only a symptom of the real problem: secrecy. >Smart people are more likely to do stupid things when they close >themselves off from outside criticism and advice. If there's one thing >I've learned in government, it's that openness is most essential in >those realms where expertise seems to matter most. If the IMF and >Treasury had invited greater scrutiny, their folly might have become >much clearer, much earlier. Critics from the right, such as Martin >Feldstein, chairman of Reagan's Council of Economic Advisers, and >George Shultz, Reagan's secretary of state, joined Jeff Sachs, Paul >Krugman, and me in condemning the policies. But, with the IMF >insisting its policies were beyond reproach--and with no institutional >structure to make it pay attention--our criticisms were of little use. >More frightening, even internal critics, particularly those with >direct democratic accountability, were kept in the dark. The Treasury >Department is so arrogant about its economic analyses and >prescriptions that it often keeps tight--much too tight--control over >what even the president sees. > > >Open discussion would have raised profound questions that still >receive very little attention in the American press: To what extent >did the IMF and the Treasury Department push policies that actually >contributed to the increased global economic volatility? (Treasury >pushed liberalization in Korea in 1993 over the opposition of the >Council of Economic Advisers. Treasury won the internal White House >battle, but Korea, and the world, paid a high price.) Were some of the >IMF's harsh criticisms of East Asia intended to detract attention from >the agency's own culpability? Most importantly, did America--and the >IMF--push policies because we, or they, believed the policies would >help East Asia or because we believed they would benefit financial >interests in the United States and the advanced industrial world? And, >if we believed our policies were helping East Asia, where was the >evidence? As a participant in these debates, I got to see the >evidence. There was none. > >Since the end of the cold war, tremendous power has flowed to the >people entrusted to bring the gospel of the market to the far corners >of the globe. These economists, bureaucrats, and officials act in the >name of the United States and the other advanced industrial countries, >and yet they speak a language that few average citizens understand and >that few policymakers bother to translate. Economic policy is today >perhaps the most important part of America's interaction with the rest >of the world. And yet the culture of international economic policy in >the world's most powerful democracy is not democratic. > >This is what the demonstrators shouting outside the IMF next week will >try to say. Of course, the streets are not the best place to discuss >these highly complex issues. Some of the protesters are no more >interested in open debate than the officials at the IMF are. And not >everything the protesters say will be right. But, if the people we >entrust to manage the global economy--in the IMF and in the Treasury >Department--don't begin a dialogue and take their criticisms to heart, >things will continue to go very, very wrong. I've seen it happen. > > > > >JOSEPH STIGLITZ is professor of economics at Stanford University (on >leave) and a senior fellow at the Brookings Institution. From 1997 to >2000, he was chief economist and vice president of the World Bank. He >served on the president's Council of Economic Advisers from 1993 to >1997. > > >from http://www.thenewrepublic.com/041700/stiglitz041700.html > > > >-- >Attac discussion list >The primary goal of this "e-community" is concrete: it is about gathering >information for the attac.org website around articles and other documents >regarding the fight against financial market dictatorship. >Nevertheless all opinions expressed in this mailing list don't represent >ATTAC's but the persons' who are publishing here > >New Documents: http://attac.org/journalnveau.htm >Directory Contacts: http://attac.org/fra/annu/index.html >Rendez-vous: http://attac.org/fra/cale/index.html > >If you want to be taken off the list >mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]?subject=unsubscribe >