Interesting take on the Syrian situation and on the differences, in general, 
between functional and dysfunctional countries.

Ed


http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/economics/10284077/Syria-needs-liberal-capitalism-not-missiles.html




Telegraph.co.uk
Thursday 05 September 2013
        * Home
        * News
        * World
        * Sport
        * Finance
        * Comment
        * Blogs
        * Culture
        * Travel
        * Life
        * Women
        * Fashion
        * Tech
        * Dating
        * Offers
        * Jobs
        * Companies
        * Comment
        * Personal Finance
        * Economics
        * Markets
        * Festival of Business
        * Your Business
        * Business Club
        * Money Deals
        1. HOME»
        2. FINANCE»
        3. ECONOMICS
Syria needs liberal capitalism, not missiles
Revolutions, wars and the emergence of totalitarian movements are rarely just 
about grand ideals, political philosophy or theological disputes.
The economic backdrop to the Arab Spring debacle and now Syria’s barbaric civil 
war is equally self-evident Photo: Reuters
By Allister Heath
4:31PM BST 03 Sep 2013
124 Comments
Abstract ideas matter, of course, but economic forces are usually central to 
the violent upheavals that regularly tear apart human societies. Sometimes the 
economic factors are hidden but mostly they are glaringly obvious, as with the 
rise of Nazism, which followed the catastrophic Weimar hyperinflation of the 
1920s and the German economic crisis of 1931.
The economic backdrop to the Arab Spring debacle and now Syria’s barbaric civil 
war is equally self-evident. With only a small number of exceptions, states in 
the region have long specialised in economic failure of the most abject kind, 
seemingly competing to become the most shocking case study in how to squander 
oil money, ruin a nation’s economy and keep ordinary people impoverished.
Syria’s GDP per person is just $3,289 (£2,122) a year, an abysmally low number; 
it is no coincidence that it is almost identical to Egypt’s, another country 
where a small ruling class has mastered the art of kleptocratic exploitation. 
Add to that a despotic political system, high and rising food prices, a 
youthful population with little hope of fulfilling its dreams – including many 
underemployed graduates – and well-organised extremist movements and you get a 
predictably explosive cocktail.
There have been plenty of explanations over the years for the failure of almost 
all of the economies in the region, their dalliance with extremism and apparent 
inability to reform themselves. Some have blamed geography, others culture, yet 
more the “resource curse” that has been oil. Activists denounce insufficient 
foreign aid; others resort to various conspiracy theories; many cite history 
and the colonial and Ottoman Empire legacies.
Yet none of these narratives convinces. Some Middle Eastern countries – Israel 
and the United Arab Emirates – have done much better than the rest by opening 
their economies; other countries in poor continents have broken free by 
reforming their economies and societies and unleashing economic growth, 
including Botswana in Africa. Clearly, no country anywhere in the world need 
remain a prisoner of circumstances or history forever; so why do so many fail 
to break free, or botch their transition, as Russia has done?
Related Articles
        * Tens of thousands of Syrian refugees stranded on Jordanian border 03 
Sep 2013
        * Obama says military strikes against Assad will help Syria 'free 
itself' 03 Sep 2013
        * Boris Johnson: MPs should 'think again' over Syria if US Congress 
backs action 03 Sep 2013
        * First Syria rebels armed and trained by CIA 'on way to battlefield' 
03 Sep 2013
        * Mayor: UK should 'think again' if US acts 03 Sep 2013
        * PM: 'No plans' for second Syria vote 03 Sep 2013
        * Sponsored Using 4G to the max in the NHS
The best explanation of what is going wrong in Syria and why the Arab Spring 
has turned into a bloody winter of discontent can be found in Why Nations Fail: 
the Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty, a fascinating tome by two US 
economists, Daron Acemoglu and James A Robinson, which ought to be on 
everybody’s reading list at the Foreign Office. The book, one of the best 
written on economics in recent years, has a thesis that is as simple as it is 
powerful. Countries can be divided into two broad groups, it argues, depending 
on economic and political structures.
The first, small but fortunate group of countries includes Britain, other 
Western economies and countries such as Australia, New Zealand, Singapore, 
South Korea, Japan and Botswana. These nations have in common something that is 
far more important than their differences: inclusive economic institutions that 
encourage and incentivise the vast majority to take part in freely chosen 
economic activities that make the best use of their talents, skills and 
interests.
Such benign economic institutions include secure and well-respected property 
rights; a good, reliable and trusted system of law and order, upholding the 
sanctity of contracts; a decent infrastructure; a sound and supportive 
regulatory framework for markets; low barriers to entry that allow individuals 
and firms to enter new markets and compete with incumbents; and access to 
education and economic opportunity for the great majority of the public.
These economic institutions are buttressed by equally inclusive political 
institutions of a sort that allows widespread participation from the public and 
imposes careful checks and balances on politicians.
The only revolutions that ever succeed in sustainably improving a country – 
such as the Glorious Revolution of 1688 in Britain and especially the Bill of 
Rights, or the reforms in South Korea that started in the 1960s – are those 
that establish such inclusive economic and political institutions.
By contrast, the second group of countries, which include Syria, Egypt and all 
of the other failed states globally, have been saddled with what Acemoglu and 
Robinson describe as extractive political institutions. These are deliberately 
designed to grab the incomes and wealth generated by the economy for the 
benefit a small elite and are buttressed by equally extractive political 
institutions which have handed all the power to these same few, with limited or 
no checks and balances and no rule of law. In these countries, the best and 
often only way to get rich is to have good connections and to exploit the power 
of the state to crush competitors.
Supposedly private firms don’t stay ahead because they provide the best 
products but because they have friends in high places, are able to ensure that 
laws and red tape keep out competitors and pay bribes to grab all the best 
contracts.
Most depressingly of all, the elites don’t have an incentive to change. Bashar 
al-Assad’s barbaric exploitation of his people is a deliberate strategy to 
maximise his own power and wealth and that of his associates: he needs some 
economic growth but doesn’t have any incentive to unleash the creative 
destruction of proper free-market capitalism, which would disrupt the status 
quo, threaten his power base and eventually destroy him. Syria’s mass poverty 
and lack of opportunity is thus a feature of the system, not a bug; informal 
grassroots businesses are no match for the corporatist oligopolies at the top 
of the pile.
Instead, regimes across the region rely excessively on oil, remittances from 
expatriate workers and handouts from foreign governments – income flows that 
actually help perpetuate the extractive institutions. The poor have been the 
greatest losers. As Adeel Malik and Bassem Awadallah note in The Economics of 
the Arab Spring, published by Oxford University, the Middle East and North 
Africa account for less than 1pc of total non-fuel exports, against 10pc for 
East Asia and 4pc for Latin America. A few years back, one academic found that 
the region’s entire output of manufactured goods was less than that of just one 
Asian nation, the Philippines.
It is difficult but by no means impossible to overthrow a well-entrenched set 
of extractive political and economic institutions. But merely replacing a 
dictator is not enough, as we saw in Egypt, where nothing substantive changed 
after Hosni Mubarak was ousted and where the army, which itself has vast 
commercial interests, has now regained power.
The only answer is a complete economic, political and cultural transformation, 
including an embrace of a real, liberal capitalism, the dismantling of 
monopolies, a bonfire of privileges and the introduction of genuine pluralism 
and constitutionally limited government. None of this tells us definitively 
whether the West should intervene in Syria or not but it certainly confirms 
that merely lobbing a few missiles at the regime won’t be enough to make a real 
difference.
Allister Heath is editor of City AM
_______________________________________________
Futurework mailing list
Futurework@lists.uwaterloo.ca
https://lists.uwaterloo.ca/mailman/listinfo/futurework

Reply via email to