Can someone please explain something for me?

During Pres. Bush's speech on Wall Street last week, during a rambling
period he muttered something I thought sounded like
"if a CEO's compensation exceeds the revenue/value of the company, well,
that's okay".

I was not completely focused on his speech at that time, having let my mind
wander with his performance, and simply raised an eyebrow at this statement.

How does one justify that?  I guess I don't understand a lot about reserves
and capital holdings but it just seemed such an odd statement to include in
a "major address" on corporate excess and accountability.

If I were Karen Hughes, I would have greeted my "alter-ego" boss at the end
of that speech with a sound thumping on the noggin. What good could that
statement possible do besides reassure corporate maverick outlaws that sound
economics doesn't matter, compensation rules?

Consider my state of mind: after 3 days of 95-degree heat, it's a blessedly
cool Saturday morning in the Pacific Northwest and I've had 2 mugs of
espresso listening to Handel's concerti grossi oboe concerti.

Karen Watters Cole

-----Original Message-----
From: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
[mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]On Behalf Of Keith Hudson
Sent: Saturday, July 13, 2002 4:08 AM
To: Dennis Paull
Cc: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: Taken for a ride

Hi Dennis,

Since firing off my earlier posting into the ether, my dog-walk reading was
my newly-delivered Economist and it contained a relevant item on the matter
of CEO salaries. It would seem that some economists have attempted to
justify, or at least, explain stratospheric earnings by something called
"optimal contracting theory". However, a forthcoming paper in the
University of Chicago Law Review has pretty well taken this bundle of
rationalisations apart.

Here's a precis of the paper as printed in the Economist:

<<<<
TAKEN FOR A RIDE

The pay of chief executives can seem ridiculous. Often, it is


In corporate America's crisis of confidence, bosses' pay looms large.
Public opinion probably sees this as the worst of the scandals in question.
Many economists, inclined to give markets a chance, take a different view.
They reckon the market for scarce talent is working pretty well. They are
most likely wrong.

In thinking about executive pay, economists reach first for optimal
contracting theory. According to this view, corporate boards design
executive pay to mitigate the "principal-agent problem" that bedevils the
relationship between shareholders and managers. Boards aim to align the
interests of managers with the interests of owners by building various
incentives into managers' contracts.

Seen this way, the technology for aligning incentives has been improving
lately-witness the growing, and in some cases dominant, role of stock
options in top executives' pay. These schemes sometimes hand out vast sums.
According to the optimal contracting model, this is good for owners,
because it rewards managers for doing things that increase the value of the
company. Once in a while, advocates concede, such plans may be abused.
Crooked bosses may manipulate stock-option plans to subvert the principle;
no scheme is proof against outright dishonesty. By and large, though, the
growth of stock-option plans is not to be deplored, but should be welcomed
as a step forward in corporate governance.

Does the optimal-contracting view make sense? A recent paper* by three
scholars from Harvard Law School and the University of California,
Berkeley, says it does not. They advocate another approach, which they call
the managerial-power view. They plausibly argue that it makes better sense
theoretically and empirically. And they draw from this approach the
interesting implication that many (not a few) top executives are skimming
mighty rents-incomes in excess of what market efficiency and maximum
shareholder value would dictate-from the people who employ them.

The key assumption of the optimal-contracting view is that managers and
shareholders, in effect, negotiate at arm's length over pay. Basic training
in economics is needed to blind one to the absurdity of this assumption.
Top managers direct or at the very least influence the board members who
set their pay: that means they will succeed in collecting some rent. The
only question is how much.

One of the constraints on this activity will be how angry shareholders and
the public at large get about bosses' pay: the paper talks of norms of
acceptable behaviour and "the outrage constraint". The importance of public
relations puts a premium on compensation schemes that disguise managers'
terms. In theory, stock options could align managers' incentives with
shareholders' interests. In practice, very often, they are used mainly to
conceal the diligent collection of rent-quite possibly with perverse, not
merely neutral, implications for incentives.

Consider the following features of stock-option plans as typically
implemented by big American companies:

•Rewarding mediocrity. Optimal contracting would lead you to expect a
stock-option design that filtered out general rises in stock prices, so
that bonuses were paid only for better-than-average performance against
some relevant benchmark. Such features, the paper shows, are rare.

•At-the-money options. Optimal contracting would suggest great variety,
according to circumstances, in the exercise price of the options granted.
(By varying the exercise price, the power of the incentive can be
fine-tuned.) There is no such variety. Options are almost universally
granted with an exercise price equal to the prevailing market price.

•Resetting. The incentive effects of options are undone if executives
expect prices to be reset when the company's shares fall. This is a
widespread practice.

•Unwinding. A requirement of optimal stock options is that managers should
be unable to hedge the risks the options create. Hedging is almost never
prohibited. Also, almost invariably, managers are allowed to cash out their
options as soon as they are vested. (Incentives aside, managers have inside
information: this allows profits to be made at the expense of public
shareholders.) Logically, boards should restrict and control the sale of
bosses' shares. They rarely do.

•Reloading. This is the practice of letting executives exercise options
when the share price is high, at the same time granting new options with
the old expiration date. This lets managers profit from volatility in share
prices even if the overall trend in the company's value is flat. It should
be rare. It is common.

This is to say nothing of "gratuitous payments" (bonuses, often related to
acquisitions, for which the firm was under no contractual requirement, and
which served no incentive-related purpose). None of these aspects of
executive pay in practice, the authors contend, can be easily explained by
optimal contracting. They can be easily explained by managerial power-that
is, by rent extraction.

How to remedy this is not an easy question. Aggressive regulation could do
more harm than good. But note that outrage, as in the outrage constraint,
has its uses. Economists who defend bosses' outlandish pay may be serving
the cause of market forces badly. Tighten that constraint. More deploring
and less defending would help curb those rents.

* "Managerial Power and Rent Extraction in the Design of Executive
Compensation" by Lucian Bebchuk, Jesse Fried and David Walker. Forthcoming
in the University of Chicago Law Review.
>>>>





----------------------------------------------------------------------------
--------------

Keith Hudson,6 Upper Camden Place, Bath BA1 5HX, England
Tel:01225 312622/444881; Fax:01225 447727; E-mail: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
________________________________________________________________________

Reply via email to