The Wall Street Journal article was approximately 2,500 words long so I
wrote:

(ROUGHLY) THE SAME NUMBER OF WORDS ABOUT A "SAME AMOUNT OF WORK"

By Tom Walker

On August 8, 2002 a strangely familar article appeared in the Wall Street
Journal. Headlined "Europe's Prized Leisure Life Becomes Economic Obstacle",
by Christopher Rhoads, it purported to assess the failure of the European
experiment of working fewer hours.

Rhoads sprinkled a few anodyne remarks from economists through his article
dealing with what is a complex and important policy issue. "You have to work
to grow," pronounced Michael Burda, professor of labor economics at Humboldt
University. "We have fewer job opportunities distributed across people who
work less," was the incisive summary offered by Andrea Ichino, professor of
economics at the European University Institute in Florence, Italy. For
balance, Rhoads quoted Juan Dolado, professor of economics at University
Carlos III in Madrid, "Usually, when people get richer, they work less."

Other than that, the article consisted of a variety of anecdotes, loosely
connected facts, sweeping generalizations and unsupported but definitively
stated conclusions. Intriguingly, several of the most Euro-skeptical
anecdotes had nothing directly to do with the hours of work but pertained to
union strength and the generosity of unemployment benefits.

One might surmise that the real point of the article was about how so-called
labor market rigidities -- the code phrase for union protection and social
programs worthy of the name -- were stifling economic growth in Europe. That
is a point, by the way, that is not supported by cross-country economic
comparisons.

But the recurring theme of the article was that the crux of Europe's
difficulties lay in the Europeans' culture of working fewer hours. The nub
of the argument appeared in a pair of paragraphs located about midway
through the article:

"Enter the shorter working week. Unions argued that reduced hours would spur
job growth by spreading the same amount of work among more people. Most
economists dismissed the theory, but some argued it could force Europeans to
become more efficient, squeezing more work into less time.

"Neither turned out to be true. Unemployment stayed high and productivity --
the measure of the amount of output achieved by one worker in an hour --
still lags behind the U.S. and fell further behind in the last few years,
according to the OECD."

The second paragraph demonstrates only the truism that you can prove
anything with statistics that have been carefully selected to support your
point -- especially if you leave out the actual figures and present only
your self-serving interpretation of them.

Rhoads' first paragraph, however, calls for closer scrutiny. It seems to
report on some ethereal debate between unions and economists in which the
unions argue for a "theory" that most economists then dismiss.

It so happens that reports of such a debate have been greatly exaggerated.
The debate between unions and economists about "spreading the same amount of
work" has never occurred. But reports in the press have persisted for at
least 131 years.

THE STRANGE CAREER OF A TELLTALE PHRASE

The earliest reported sighting of this mythical debate appeared in the
Quarterly Review in 1871, where the alleged union theory was described as a
"Unionist reading of the Wage-fund theory" that the unions sought to put
into action through "the enforcement of all sorts of arbitrary restrictions
on the combined workmen with the avowed object of securing that the work to
be done shall be divided among as many (Unionist) hands as possible."

Some twenty years later, in 1891, David F. Schloss gave a name to the
elusive theory, "the theory of the Lump of Labour... In accordance with this
theory it is held that there is a certain fixed amount of work to be done,
and that it is best in the interests of the workmen that each shall take
care not to do too much work, in order that thus the Lump of Labour may be
spread out thin over the whole body of work-people."

It wasn't until ten years later, that the imaginary debate became a standard
feature of the popular press. In 1901 a series of reports appeared in the
London Times under the running title of "The Crisis in British Industry."
The dispatches from an unnamed correspondent claimed to document abuses by
unions that were undermining British competitiveness. The lead article in
the series revealed the sinister motive underlying this presumed union
scheme for "spreading the same amount of work among more people":

"It was hoped to "absorb" all the unemployed in course of time, not by the
laudable and much-to-be-desired means of increasing the volume of trade, and
hence, also, the amount of work to be done, but simply by obtaining
employment for a larger number of persons on such work as there was already.
The motive of this aspiration, however, was not one of philanthropy pure and
simple. When all the unemployed had been absorbed the workers would have the
employers entirely at their mercy, and would be able to command such wages
and such terms as they might think fit."

It later was revealed that Edwin A. Pratt was the author of the series,
although a fellow named William Collison took credit for having "provided
the information." Mr. Collison, who billed himself as "The Apostle of Free
Labour" in the title of his autobiography , was publicist for a
labor-contracting agency that supplied scab labor and strikebreaking thugs.

In 1905, the National Association of Manufacturers of the U.S.A. sponsored
Mr. Collison on a speaking tour of the U.S. David M. Parry, the virulently
anti-union President of the N.A.M. wrote a dystopian novel published in 1906
that borrowed generously from Pratt/Collison's "amount of work to be done"
theme. In the novel's historical recap scene, a dissident doctor from the
lost civilization of Atlantis explains to the sojourning hero, John Walker,
how the Federation of Labor had sown the seeds of the place's degradation:

"The leaders of the Federation said that there was a certain amount of work
to be done in Atlantis, and that the competition among the workers for the
chance to do this work made it possible for the employers to reduce wages.
'Now,' said they, 'all that needs to be done is to get rid of this
competition. Let us shorten the hours and let no man perform any greater
share of this labor than he can possibly avoid, and then we shall have a
condition in which the competition will be transferred to the employers -- a
condition in which the employers will bid against each other to secure men
to perform the necessary work of the nation. This will result in the
enrichment of the masses instead of the few, as is now the case.'"

There begins to appear a suspicious similarity of phrasing throughout these
examples, which are by no means the only ones -- a certain amount of work to
be done... the amount of work to be done... a certain fixed amount of work
to be done... the work to be done... the same amount of work. Is it also
coincidence that the alleged theory is invariably attributed to "unions" but
never to a specific source?

The early examples may have been merely repeating a clichéd middle class
complaint against unions. But the London Times series and its obvious appeal
to violently anti-union leadership of the N.A.M. marked a change from cliché
to set piece. Between 1902 and 1913 -- when a congressional investigation
brought the activities of this so-called "invisible government" to light --
whenever N.A.M. leaders could spare precious moments from their literary
pursuits, they worked overtime bribing public officials, extorting newspaper
publishers, intimidating opponents, buying academic mouthpieces,
infiltrating and sabotaging unions and breaking strikes. In its 1917
History, Encyclopedia and Reference Book, the American Federation of Labor
called the episode "deception, corruption, and perfidy that has never before
been equaled in the United States for scope of operation, audacity of
conception, and inhumanity of purpose."

The purpose of the N.A.M. propaganda campaign was to portray their activity
as a public-spirited campaign against the "lump of labor" theory and output
restricting practice of the labor unions. The real goal, as articulated by
Parry at the Association's 1903 convention was no less than "pulling up,
root and branch, the un-American institution of trades unionism."

Parry was only slightly more circumspect when he described the role he
envisioned for the free press in his avowed enterprise of crushing the
unions, "The newspapers finding that they have the moral support of a strong
employers' association, can, I think, be depended upon to take a more
positive stand against the outrageous practices of unionism than it is wise
for them to do without such support." What this meant in practice, according
to a contemporary account was that local affiliates of the N.A.M.'s
civic-action front group, the Citizens Industrial Association of America,
were expected to see to it that "pressure is brought to bear upon the local
newspapers through its advertising members."

WAITER! THERE'S SOME LOOSE TEETH IN MY GRAPE-NUTS!

Three years later, Parry's successor as president of the N.A.M., cereal
magnate Charles W. Post, looked back proudly at the organization's
accomplishments, "two years ago the press and pulpit were delivering
platitudes about the oppression of the workingman. Now this has all changed
... The people have been aroused and are now acting. It has been the duty of
this Association to place the facts before the people by various forms of
publicity in the work of moulding public opinion to a point of active
self-defense."

It may help to know that Mr. Post made his fortune by adopting the methods
of 19th century patent medicine sales for the promotion of packaged foods.
Post advertised 'Grape-Nuts' and 'Postum' as cure-alls for everything from
consumption, appendicitis and malaria to 'Loose Teeth Made Sound by Eating
Grape Nuts.' It may also help to know that Post was notorious for spending
what for the time were extravagant sums of money on advertising and for
using the leverage of this spending to keep the press from criticizing his
fraudulent claims.

In 1907, Post launched a campaign of intimidation and slander against the
publisher of Collier's Magazine in response to an editorial that denounced
as "lying, and potentially deadly lying" the advertising claims of the
Postum Cereal Company that Grape-Nuts could cure appendicitis. Collier's
sued Post for libel and was awarded $50,000 damages, at the time the largest
sum ever been awarded in a libel case in New York County "and possibly the
United States."

THE LUMP OF LABOR GOES TO COLLEGE

Although the National Association of Manufacturers had to tone down its
stridency after the 1913 congressional investigation into its corrupt
activities, the lump of labor charge against unions drifted into the pages
of introductory economics textbooks. From 1924, Raymond Bye's widely used
textbook introduced first-year economics students to the supposed fallacy.

In the late 1930s, Harry Millis and Royal Montgomery co-authored a labor
economics textbook that summed up an otherwise well-considered discussion of
the health, productivity and social benefits of reduced work time by
dismissing the unions' real motive for wanting a shorter work week as based
on the infamous lump of labor fallacy.

Say what? Reduced work time is good for all these reasons. O.K. The unions
say they want it for all the right reasons. O.K. But we know the real reason
they want it is for that other reason. Therefore they shouldn't get it. Huh?

After the war, the first edition of Paul Samuelson's Economics, published in
1948, warned against the lump of labor fallacy, as did the 16th edition by
Samuelson and Nordhaus published in 1998. "Whenever unemployment is high,
people often think that the solution lies in spreading existing work more
evenly among the labor force."

When asked to verify the source of this supposed belief, the Nobel Prize
winning textbook author could be no more specific than to reckon that, "the
'lump of labor' fallacy that my textbook wrote about was widespread during
the Great Depression 1929-1935 and is still encountered in today's France."

It is probably only a coincidence that Samuelson's publisher and the
publisher of Millis and Montgomery was McGraw-Hill, a key participant - both
technically and as a member of the association - in the National Association
of Manufacturers' public relations efforts to counter the policies of the
Roosevelt New Deal.

So it turns out the "theory" about spreading a fixed amount of work is not
an argument put forward by any bona fide advocate for shorter work time but
a fabrication concocted by the opponents of shorter work time. But if the
case against shorter work time is as strong as these critics pretend, why
would it be necessary for them to misrepresent the case in favour?

Could it be that the case against shorter work time is no more substantive
than Post's bogus claims that eating grape nuts would fix loose teeth or
cure appendicitis? That is what the economic theory of the hours of labor
would suggest and what more than a century of empirical study has confirmed.
S.J. Chapman, the orthodox Cambridge economist who produced the
authoritative statement of the theory of hours of labor in a free market,
scoffed at the notion of workers believing in a lump of labor theory. Even
if they did, he remarked, it would protect them from making the worse error
of overworking themselves and thus depreciating the value of their labor.

Around the time that Parry and Post were rallying the anti-union troops to
defend against the depredations of the eight-hour day, the 1902 final report
of a major congressional industrial commission concluded:

"On the side of the working population there can be no question respecting
the desirability of fewer hours, from every standpoint. They gain not only
in health, but also in intelligence, morality, temperance, and preparation
for citizenship... A reduction of hours is the most substantial and
permanent gain which labor can secure... Having once secured the shorter
working day, the question of wages can be adjusted from time to time
according to the stress of the market."

And while the Wall Street Journal conjures up phantom unionists arguing in
favour of spreading the same amount of work, an actual European trade union
economist, Gerhard Bosch maintains that working time reductions are "not
just a question of 'whether' but also of 'how'." Surveying the empirical
research, Bosch notes that, "...most studies conclude that working-time
reductions have positive employment effects of between 25 and 70% of the
arithmetically possible effect. Only a few studies find zero or even
negative effects. Thus the employment effects of working-time reductions are
better than their reputation would suggest."

The moral of this phoney tale about spreading "the same amount of work" is:
if you want to weaken  unions and dismantle social programs, then the lump
of labor fallacy is your battle cry. If you like low wages, you'll love long
hours.


Tom Walker
604 254 0470

Reply via email to