Thanks Keith,

Always glad to have your help.

REH

----- Original Message -----
From: "Keith Hudson" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
To: "Ray Evans Harrell" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
Cc: <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
Sent: Tuesday, November 05, 2002 3:29 PM
Subject: Re: A more rational economics


> Ray,
>
> Thank you for posting such an excellent article from today's NYT. (I've
> re-formatted it below for the benefit of those who might like a little
more
> spacing.)
>
> Keith
>
> <<<<
> ON PROFIT, LOSS AND THE MYSTERIES OF THE MIND
>
> By Erica Goode
>
>
> "Kahnemanandtversky."
>
> Everybody said it that way.
>
> As if the Israeli psychologists Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky were a
> single person, and their work, which challenged long-held views of how
> people formed judgments and made choices, was the product of a single
mind.
>
> Last month, Dr. Kahneman, a professor at Princeton, was awarded the Nobel
> in economics science, sharing the prize with Vernon L. Smith of George
> Mason University. But Dr. Kahneman said the Nobel, which the committee
does
> not award posthumously, belongs equally to Dr. Tversky, who died of cancer
> in 1996 at 59.
>
> "I feel it is a joint prize," Dr. Kahneman, 68, said. "We were twinned for
> more than a decade."
>
> In Jerusalem, where their collaboration began in 1969, the two were
> inseparable, strolling on the grounds of Hebrew University or sitting at a
> cafe or drinking instant coffee in their shared office at the Van Leer
> Jerusalem Institute and talking, always talking. Later, when Dr. Tversky
> was teaching at Stanford and Dr. Kahneman at the University of British
> Columbia, they would call each other several times a day.
>
> Every word of their papers, now classics studied by every graduate student
> in psychology or economics, was debated until "a perfect consensus" was
> reached. To decide who would appear as first author, they flipped a coin.
>
> Wiry, charismatic, fizzing with intelligence, Dr. Tversky was younger by a
> few years. Dr. Kahneman, as intellectually keen, was gentler, more
> intuitive, more awkward.
>
> Together, the psychologists developed a new understanding of judgments and
> decisions made under conditions of risk or uncertainty.
>
> Economists had long assumed that beliefs and decisions conformed to
logical
> rules. They based their theories on an ideal world where people acted as
> "rational agents," exploiting any opportunity to increase their pleasure
or
> benefit.
>
> But Dr. Kahneman and Dr. Tversky demonstrated that in some cases people
> behaved illogically, their choices and judgments impossible to reconcile
> with a rational model. These departures from rationality, the
psychologists
> showed, followed systematic patterns.
>
> For example, the exact same choice presented or "framed" in different ways
> could elicit different decisions, a finding that traditional economic
> theory could not explain.
>
> In an oft-cited experiment, the psychologists asked a group of subjects to
> imagine the outbreak of an unusual disease, expected to kill 600 people,
> and to choose between two public health programs to combat it.
>
> Program A, the subjects were told, had a 100 percent chance of saving 200
> lives. Program B had a one-third chance of saving 600 lives and a
> two-thirds probability of saving no lives.
>
> Offered this choice, most of the subjects preferred certainty, selecting
> Program A.
>
> But when the identical outcomes were framed in terms of lives lost, the
> subjects behaved differently. Informed that if Program A were adopted, 400
> people would die, while Program B carried a one-third probability that no
> one would die and a two-thirds probability that 600 people would die, most
> subjects chose the less-certain alternative.
>
> Over more than two decades, working together or with others, Dr. Kahneman
> and Dr. Tversky elaborated many situations in which such psychological
> "myopia" influenced people's behavior and offered formal theories to
> account for them.
>
> They established, among other things, that losses loom larger than gains,
> that first impressions shape subsequent judgments, that vivid examples
> carry more weight in decision making than more abstract - but more
accurate
> - information.
>
> Anyone who read their work, illustrated, as one admirer put it, with
> "simple examples of irresistible force and clarity," was drawn to their
> conclusions.
>
> Even economists, unused to looking to psychology for instruction, began to
> take notice, their attention attracted by two papers, one published in
1974
> in Science, the other in 1979 in the economics journal Econometrica.
> Eventually, the psychologists' work provided the undergirding for
> behavioral economics, the approach developed by Dr. Richard Thaler.
>
> In a recent conversation, Dr. Kahneman, who carries both American and
> Israeli citizenship, talked about what happens when psychology and
> economics meet.
>
> Q. Did you set out to challenge the way economists were thinking?
> A. We certainly didn't have in mind to influence economics.
>
> In the first years, economists, and philosophers, too, were simply not
> interested in the trivial errors that we as psychologists were studying.
>
> I have a clear memory of a party in Jerusalem around 1971, attended by a
> famous American philosopher. Someone introduced us and suggested that I
had
> an interesting story to tell him about our research. He listened to me for
> about 30 seconds, then cut me off abruptly, saying, "I am not really
> interested in the psychology of stupidity."
>
> Our work was completely ignored until our 1974 paper, which eventually had
> an impact on both economics and epistemology. Of course, we did not mind
in
> the least because economists were not our intended audience anyway; we
were
> talking to psychologists. It came as a pleasant surprise when others
> started to pay attention.
> Q. Why is the rational model of human behavior so entrenched in economic
> theory?
> A. There's a very good reason for why economics developed the way it did,
> and that is that in many situations, the assumption that people will
> exploit the opportunities available to them is very plausible, and it
> simplifies the analysis of how markets will behave.
>
> You know, when you're thinking of two stalls next to each other selling
> apples at different prices, then you're assuming that the fellow who is
> selling them at too high a price is just not going to have customers.
>
> So you get rationality at this level, and it buys a lot of predictive
power
> by this assumption. When you are building a formal theory, you want to
> generalize that assumption, and then you end up making people completely
> rational.
> Q. You and Amos Tversky are perhaps best known for prospect theory. Could
> you explain what this is based on?
> A. When I teach it, I go back to 1738. In 1738, Daniel Bernoulli wrote the
> big essay that introduced utility theory. Utility really means pleasure
> more than anything else.
>
> The question that Bernoulli put to himself was "How do people make risky
> decisions?" And he analyzed really quite a nice problem: a merchant
> thinking of sending a ship from Amsterdam to St. Petersburg at a time of
> year when there would be a 5 percent probability of the ship being lost.
>
> Bernoulli evaluated the possible outcomes in terms of their utility. What
> he said is that the merchant thinks in terms of his states of wealth: how
> much he will have if the ship gets there, if the ship doesn't get there,
if
> he buys insurance, if he doesn't buy insurance.
>
> And now it turns out that Bernoulli made a mistake; in some sense it was a
> bewildering error to have made. For Bernoulli, the state of wealth is the
> total amount you've got, and you will have the same preference whether you
> start out owning a million dollars or a half million or two million. But
> the mistake is that no merchant would think that way, in terms of states
of
> wealth. Like anybody else, he would think in terms of gains and losses.
>
> That's really a very simple insight but it turns out to be the insight
that
> made the big difference. Because, if that's not the way that people think,
> if people actually think in terms of gains and losses and not in terms of
> states of wealth, then all the mathematical analysis that has been done
> which assumed people do it that way is not true. It took us a long time to
> figure it out.
> Q. What kinds of things does prospect theory explain?
> A. I think the major phenomenon we observed is what we called "loss
> aversion." There is an asymmetry between gains and losses, and it really
is
> very dramatic and very easy to see. In my classes, I say: "I'm going to
> toss a coin, and if it's tails, you lose $10. How much would you have to
> gain on winning in order for this gamble to be acceptable to you?"
>
> People want more than $20 before it is acceptable. And now I've been doing
> the same thing with executives or very rich people, asking about tossing a
> coin and losing $10,000 if it's tails. And they want $20,000 before
they'll
> take the gamble.
>
> So the function for gains and losses is sort of kinked. People really
> discriminate sharply between gaining and losing and they don't like
losing.
> Q. How did prospect theory influence economists?
> A. Correcting Bernoulli's error was influential, because it was picked up
> by Richard Thaler, who started behavioral economics. We provided cover for
> behavioral economics, because the challenge to the rational model was
taken
> seriously and presented in a way that readers of the work found
compelling.
>
> But it's not as if this has swept economics. It hasn't, and for very deep
> structural reasons, it's not going to. The rational model has a hold on
> economics, and it's going to stay that way. Behavioral economists fiddle
> with it, improving the assumptions and making them psychologically
> sensible. But it's not a completely different way of doing economic
theory.
> Q. One of the things you are studying now is well-being. Does this connect
> in any way to economics?
> A. I would like to develop a measure of well-being that economists would
> take seriously, an alternative to the standard measure of quality of life.
>
> We're attempting to measure it not by asking people, but by actually
trying
> to measure the quality of their daily lives. For example, we are studying
> one day in the lives of 1,000 working women in Texas. We have people
> reconstruct the day in successive episodes, as recalled a day later, and
we
> have a technique that recovers the emotions and the feelings. We know who
> they were with and what they were doing. They also tell us how satisfied
> they are with various aspects of their lives. We know a lot about these
> ladies.
> Q. What are you finding out?
> A. I'll give you a striking finding. Divorced women, compared to married
> women, are less satisfied with their lives, which is not surprising. But
> they're actually more cheerful, when you look at the average mood they're
> in in the course of the day. The other thing is the huge importance of
> friends. People are really happier with friends than they are with their
> families or their spouse or their child.
>
> Q. Why would divorced women be more cheerful?
> A. So far, I don't understand it, but that's what the data says.
> >>>>
>
>
>
>
> --------------------------------------------------------------------------
--
> --------------
> Keith Hudson,6 Upper Camden Place, Bath BA1 5HX, England
> Tel:01225 312622/444881; Fax:01225 447727; E-mail: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
> ________________________________________________________________________

Reply via email to