Throughout most of history, it has generally been the case that a dominant regime of long-standing fails when it is defeated in war by another regime which has developed better weapons. Once defeated, such a regime is rarely able to regenerate itself even though its geography, its climate, its people and, apparently its culture, are much as they were before. It is nearly always the case also that the regime not only fails to regain some sort of normalcy but actually degenerates. Some vital spark is missing; its culture retains its outward form but the vitality has gone. We can instance almost all the ancient empires of Eurasia from the earliest, the Sumerian civilisation of about 3,000BC, right through to the fall of the Ottoman Empire in the 1920s which have gone through this cycle.

There are, of course, other reasons why regimes have failed historically (over-government is another) but, for the most part, it has been innovations in weaponry -- and, usually, just one outstanding innovation -- which has caused the downfall.  However, in more recent times, as hinted in my posting a few days ago ("123. Know-how economies"), it is not a lack of military innovation that directly brings a regime down but an inability to develop new non-military technologies which might have given it sufficient economic edge. Or, if they do -- and thereby flash forth brightly in the economic sky for a while -- they are unable to develop further ones. Thus, Germany was far ahead in superb mechanical engineering technology in the early part of the last century, the Soviet Union was far ahead in space technology in the 1950s, and the Japanese in electronic technology in the 70s and 80s.

Yet these countries developed very little else of equivalent inventiveness and, indeed, all three of these countries allowed most of the rest of their industry and commerce to become grossly inefficent and increasingly mired in regulations which diminished any possibility of inventors and entrepreneurs getting new technologies off the ground. Even the UK, which has blazed away modestly with a succession of new technologies and innovative ideas for most of the last two hundred years -- right up to inventing the computer in the 50s and discovering the structure of DNA in the 70s (albeit with the help of an American, James Watson!) -- seems to have given up the ghost now with no distinctive new technology in the offing (at least I can't think of one); we, too, seem to be in the early years of settling into a morass of regulation out of which no political party seems able to offer deliverance.

So far, America has escaped the fate of the other prime economies of the last century. It still seems to be developing innovative technologies such as genetics and nanotechnology, but it remains to be seen whether its lead can be retained or whether a revitalised China will overtake it in the coming years. In the meantime, we in Europe can only watch helplessly. It is possible perhaps that some European countries might heed the lessons of Russia, Japan and, more recently, Germany, and somehow shake off their lethargy, but it seems doubtful to me. I've read a lot about the present predicament of Russia and Japan but I can't say that I understand what goes on there -- their cultures are too different from my own mind-set -- but I think I understand better what is going on in Germany and the following article will be useful material for my project as it pauses here for a few moments before going into my database.  (Incidentally, since this article appeared in the Financial Times yesterday, Gerhard Schröder's deputy, Rudolph Scharping, has resigned in protest at his boss's reforms, so it look even less promising than before.)

Keith Hudson

<<<<
WHY SCHRÖDER'S REFORMS ARE BAD ECONOMICS

Wolfgang Munchau

Gerhard Schröder, the German chancellor, won an important political victory on Friday when the parliament endorsed his programme of structural reforms. Given his wafer-thin majority and the many sceptics in his own party, this was an object lesson in the use of political power.

The reforms consist of cuts in welfare payments for the long-term unemployed, a reorganisation of the employment administration and changes to local finances and corporate taxation. The test is whether these reforms will help improve economic performance. But they are bound to fail.

Germany's trend growth rate has been falling for decades but the decline has been accelerated by unification. It now stands at 1 per cent in real terms.

Three years of zero growth cannot be explained by macroeconomic policy alone. The government forecasts a deficit of 4 per cent of gross domestic product for this year. But there is a series of adjustments to come that will push the deficit close to 5 per cent. Nominal short-term interest rates are at 2 per cent -- perhaps not ideal, but hardly a cause for quite such a bad performance. Nor is competitiveness the problem, especially not in a year when Germany has overtaken the US as the world's largest exporter. The problem is a chronic incapacity to generate domestic growth. This is what any reform programme must address.

Economic history may provide a partial explanation for this imbalance. After two world wars and two periods of hyperinflation, modern Germany's founders turned stability into the prime objective of economic policy. But they made the mistake of subjecting the entire system, from monetary policy to labour market regulation, to this goal. In today's largely unchanged environment, DaimlerChrysler and Siemens can still operate profitably, having adjusted to the system. New entrants, however, find Germany a hostile environment in which to work and live. Stability has come at the expense of flexibility.

The weakness in domestic growth stems from low levels of investment and consumption. Consumption has been flat, but the fall in levels of investment has been dramatic. To foster domestic growth through higher investment, the German government should look at measures aimed at immediately improving efficiency and, in the long term, increasing growth potential. To realise the first objective the government needs to address reforms in financial, product and labour markets much more directly. Germany has yet to restructure its convoluted public sector banking system and establish a regulatory environment for a functioning venture capital industry. The capital markets remain underdeveloped, as companies still find it easier to raise finance directly through the banks rather than by issuing shares or debt.

Inefficiencies on the product market side include outdated competition laws, high barriers to entry -- such as professional qualification requirements for craftsmen -- and restrictions on shopping hours.

The list of labour market rigidities is even longer. High indirect labour costs coupled with the requirement for employers to co-finance the social security system have effectively prevented the emergence of a low-wage sector and transferred resources from those in work to those out of work, the long-term unemployed and pensioners. The wage cartel is also in need of reform, not because it has inflated salary levels, as is often falsely claimed, but because it has not allowed for sufficient flexibility.

Of course, one can still argue that Mr Schröder's reforms are only a first step. That may be so, but subsequent reforms will be from the same mould. The government is considering a few symbolic measures, such as a modest relaxation of the laws on hiring and firing, but not the deep structural reforms needed to increase investment:

Mr Schröder is a pragmatic man. It is realpolitik in its truest sense. But it is bad economics. His reforms are an attempt to adjust the welfare state to fit a less affluent society. He should do the opposite: focus on raising growth through higher investment, so he can afford the kind of society most Germans want to live in.
Financial Times -- 21 October 2003
>>>>



Keith Hudson, Bath, England, <www.evolutionary-economics.org>, <www.handlo.com>, <www.property-portraits.co.uk>

Reply via email to