http://www.marxist.com/imf-report-contradictions-in-chinese-economy.htm

 From exports to investment: contradictions in the Chinese economy
intensify<http://www.marxist.com/imf-report-contradictions-in-chinese-economy.htm>
Written by Adam Booth Wednesday, 12 September 2012
[image: 
Print]<http://www.marxist.com/imf-report-contradictions-in-chinese-economy/print.htm#>

*The picture of the Chinese economy painted by commentators in the West is
often one of strength; an economy dominated by exports, with unstoppable
growth and development; in short, a model to emulate. Recent figures
released by the International Monetary Fund, however, describe a very
different situation; a situation where contradictions are intensifying
below the surface; a situation that is pregnant with crisis and
revolutionary consequences.*

[image: Chinese
Economy]<http://www.marxist.com/images/stories/china/NIKE_Alex_Mahan.jpg>In
previous 
articles<http://www.marxist.com/the-limitations-and-contradictions-of-the-chinese-model.htm>,
we described and analysed some of the contradictions and limitations facing
the “Chinese Model", such as the accumulation of local government debt and
the looming crisis of overproduction facing the economy. In their recent
report <http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2012/cr12195.pdf> on the
Chinese economy (which was written in association with the Chinese
authorities), the IMF provide facts, figures, and statistics that emphasise
the points that we previously highlighted.

However, in addition, the IMF report demonstrates that the Chinese economy
has reorientated away from the export-led growth that it has been famous
for, and is now heavily based on internal investment. Such investment paves
the way for a new, greater crisis in the economy, as the IMF themselves
recognise.
Background

As we have explained
previously<http://www.marxist.com/china-long-march-capitalism021006.htm>,
in the thirty year period following the “market reforms”, which were first
introduced by Deng in 1978, capitalist relations in China became
increasingly strengthened. A pivotal point in this capitalist restoration
was in 2001 when China joined the World Trade Organisation. Joining the WTO
meant giving up state control of foreign trade, opening China up to the
world market. This breaking down of the Chinese walls resulted in a large
investment boom as foreign capital flooded into China. In addition, the
admission of China into the WTO gave businesses in China increased access
to the world market for their exports.

The use of joint ventures, in which multinational firms were allowed access
into China on the condition that they do so in partnership with Chinese
state companies, was used to strengthen these Chinese companies to the
point whereby they could compete on the world market. In doing so, Chinese
companies were also able to acquire foreign technology on the cheap, thus
paving the way for a massive expansion of China’s productive apparatus.

Between 2001 and 2008, the Chinese economy grew at a tremendous pace,
largely thanks to exports. Growth of over 8% of GDP per year was seen
throughout this period, and by 2007 growth had reached 14.2%, with net
exports accounting for almost one fifth of this growth.

Over the same period, huge numbers of people flocked from the countryside
to the cities and the productivity of labour exponentially increased as a
greater quantity (and better quality) of machinery was put at the elbow of
each worker. According to a recent special report on the Chinese economy in
*The Economist *(May 26th 2012):

“From 1990 to 2008 China's workforce swelled by about 145m people, many of
them making the long journey from its rural backwaters to its coastal
workshops. Over the same period the productivity of the workforce increased
by over 9% a year, according to the Asian Productivity Organisation (APO).
Output that used to take 100 people in 1990 required fewer than 20 in 2008.
All this meant that growth of 8-10% a year was not a luxury but a
necessity.”

This vast expansion of industry in China created an equally vast mass of
commodities that had to find a market. “Excess capacity” (i.e.
overproduction) was seen across the economy, but especially in industries
such as cars, construction materials, and steel. With the Chinese currency
(the “yuan”, or “renminbi”) and labour costs held low, these commodities
were exported abroad to markets in the USA and Europe, and profits flowed
both to the multinational firms that had set up shop in China and also to
the newly strengthened Chinese companies (both state-owned and private).

By 2007, China registered a huge trade surplus with the rest of the world,
at 9% of Chinese GDP (equal to approximately US315bn), which contributed
towards a current account surplus of 10.1% of GDP (the current account of a
country is a measure of the flow of goods and services – i.e. the value of
commodities – that crosses the borders of a country). But such export-led
growth was extremely fragile, and this fragility was exposed by the onset
of the global crisis in 2008.
Crisis and stimulus

As a result of the 2008 crisis, demand for Chinese exports in the key
markets of the USA and Europe contracted significantly The Chinese
authorities responded in November 2008 by implementing a vast government
stimulus, much of which was on large-scale infrastructure projects,
construction, and property, which gave a large impetus to increased
quantities of imports into China, especially of raw materials. This
combination of declining exports and increased imports has led to a
reduction of the current account surplus to only 2.8% of GDP. In fact,
rather than contributing to economic growth, since 2009 net exports have
actually detracted from growth.

Much of this investment and stimulus by the Chinese government in 2008 was
fuelled by credit, in the form of loans to fund local government projects.
Lending rose from 122% of GDP in 2008 to 171% in 2010, a larger increase of
credit than that seen in the USA in the run up to the financial crisis of
2007.

Whilst the government stimulus may have temporarily saved the Chinese
economy from the effects of the global crisis, the rise in credit has gone
hand in hand with a rise in local government debt and an increase in
financial risk, especially as much of the lending has been done in the
shadows of the economy. As the IMF reports:

“The side effects of the last stimulus are still winding their way through
the economy. As a result, there is a clear risk of deterioration in bank
asset quality, which would be amplified in a low-growth scenario.”

The IMF report continues:

“The authorities’ strong response to the last crisis helped maintain robust
growth in China and provided needed support to the global economy. It also
relied heavily on a large expansion in bank credit – especially to local
government financing vehicles – which is now raising concerns about bank
asset quality, the size and efficiency of investment, and the financial
health of some local government entities.”

[image: Chinese ghost
town]<http://www.marxist.com/images/stories/china/ghost_town4.jpg>Chinese
ghost townIn addition, the government stimulus has led to an enormous
property bubble in China. In order to find an outlet for their savings,
wealthy Chinese have “invested” in property, the result being whole
developments that lie empty without any inhabitants in sight. Both the IMF
and the Chinese authorities are all too aware of the problem. According to *The
Economist *(July 28th 2012), “It [the property bubble] remains the biggest
fear hanging over the world’s second-biggest economy.”

However, the Chinese government is equally wary of the impact of bursting
the bubble, due to the knock on effects that this would have. Many other
sectors within the Chinese (and international) economy rely on the demand
from construction, and a slowdown in house building would have a severe
effect, as the IMF reports:

“Real estate investment accounts for a quarter of total fixed asset
investment in China...

“...Following a decline in real estate investment, activity would fall in a
broad range of sectors, given the real estate industry’s strong backward
linkages to other domestic industries (such as consumer durables,
construction, light industry, electricity). Weakening domestic demand would
depress China’s imports and, in turn, impact trading partners’ production,
employment and domestic demand.”

Global interconnectivity

What this particular example highlights is the extreme interconnectivity of
the global economy. Not only is China reliant on the health of the
economies in the West (e.g. exporting to the USA and Europe), but, in turn,
the rest of the world is reliant on Chinese demand. According to the IMF:

“Assuming no policy response in China, growth could decline by as much as 4
percentage points in response to a 1.75 percentage point slowdown in global
growth.”

And this slowdown in China would have an impact on several other important
countries, which have built their economies around exporting basic
commodities to China, such as coal, oil, steel, and food, as well as more
valuable capital goods, i.e. machinery; as the IMF states:

“The combination of China’s reliance on investment for growth and its
growing footprint of commodities and capital goods imports leave several
economies exposed to a slowdown in China’s fixed-asset investment. The
growth impact would be significant for G20 economies such as Japan,
Germany, Canada, and Brazil.”

Many other countries could be added to this list, such as Australia and
several African economies, which have seen their economies grow on the back
of a commodity export boom to China, whose investment led growth has sucked
up raw materials from across the globe, leading to increased prices that
have contributed towards inflation.

These statements by the IMF debunk the myth of “decoupling”, put forward by
many in the naive hope that the crisis in the USA and Europe would not
affect the emerging economies, such as Brazil, or the industrialised
nations, such as Australia, that have seen consistent growth over the last
few years, despite the crisis. As Marx and Engels long ago explained in the
Communist Manifesto, capitalism has created a world market; a system in
which the fate of each nation is dependent on every other.
Investment and overproduction

As a result of the 2008 stimulus, investment now accounts for almost 50% of
Chinese GDP and for a majority of the growth in GDP. But unlike the
investment boom that followed the admission of China into the WTO in 2001,
which was primarily due to an influx of foreign direct investment into new
factories and production, based around the export-dominant coastal areas of
the country, this latest investment boom is, in essence, a giant Keynesian
experiment. As *The Economist *special report highlights:

“The post-crisis investment boom was also different from the post-WTO one.
It was weighted towards inland provinces, far from the seaports that ship
China's goods to the rest of the world. Inland China's share of fixed-asset
investment matched that of the coastal provinces for the first time in
2009, then exceeded it in 2010. The investment boom in 2009-10 was also
concentrated in infrastructure and property. Neither can be traded across
borders.”

As the example of empty properties indicates, a significant part of this
investment has been unproductive, yet again emphasising the Keynesian
nature of the investment – i.e. government stimulus to artificially
maintain effective demand and thus delay the crisis.

Nevertheless, much of the investment has been productive and has
contributed towards increasing the local and global crisis of
overproduction. This serves to point out the major contradiction inherent
within the Chinese economy: by delaying the crisis today through investment
and stimulus, the Chinese state is simply preparing the conditions for an
even deeper crisis in the future.

According to the IMF report:

“China has had excess capacity for most of the past decade. The gap was
closing in the run-up to the financial crisis, but did so based on an
unsustainable level of external demand...”

“...By most standards, including a cross-country comparison and the
historical experience of other fast-growing economies, China’s investment
is very high. Approaching 50% of GDP, investment has been sustaining
China’s high growth and is creating large excess capacity in the economy,
with the *capacity utilization rate declining from just under 80% before
the crisis to around 60% today*...”

“...Maintaining high investment will add to overcapacity and thereby create
problems over the medium term... persistent overcapacity could lead to
deflationary pressure, a rise in bankruptcies, and large financial losses.
It could also drive up exports and depress prices to maintain high global
market shares in a range of products, which could trigger retaliatory trade
action... under this scenario, a sharp correction in investment would
become inevitable, with significant negative implications for growth and
employment...”

“...It [investment] is also leading to excess capacity that could result in
problems down the road if domestic and global markets are unable to absorb
the output, leading potentially to trade frictions, price declines,
bankruptcies, and a worsening of bank asset quality. *This model,
therefore, is not sustainable*.” (our emphasis)

To put this in perspective, a capacity utilisation rate of 80% means that
the equivalent of 20% of the productive forces – e.g. two in every ten
factories – are lying idle. A decline of capacity utilisation to only 60%
means the equivalent of four in every ten factories lying idle.

This demonstrates the extreme crisis of overproduction facing the Chinese
economy. The vast mass of wealth that is being produced by the low paid,
super exploited workers in China cannot be absorbed by these same workers
and must find an outlet somewhere. For years this was achieved by exporting
to the USA and Europe – whose debt-fuelled consumption was equally
unsustainable. Now the recent attempts to overcome this contradiction of
overproduction – a contradiction that is inherent within the capitalist
mode of production and the system of private property that it is based on –
can do nothing but exacerbate the contradictions, delaying the crisis and
paving the way for an even bigger crisis further down the line.
“Rebalancing” the economy

Faced with such a problem, the IMF proposes one simply sounding solution:
“rebalancing” the Chinese economy. In other words: reducing investment;
keeping exports down; and increasing internal consumption. In order to do
this, the IMF proposes a few measures, such as increasing public spending
on welfare (e.g. pensions, healthcare, and education), ensuring that the
social and environmental impacts of production are taken into account (e.g.
taxing pollution), and opening up the Chinese service sector to competition
(e.g. in utilities and banking).

There is a strong sense within this IMF report that these suggestions and
recommendations are made not so much in the interests of the Chinese
economy, but in the interests of global capitalism (whose interests, after
all, the IMF are designed to represent). Many foreign firms would very much
like to gain greater access to the Chinese market – including both selling
to Chinese consumers and buying up Chinese companies – and would like to
see Chinese businesses competing on a “level playing field” on the world
market – i.e. reducing the competitiveness of Chinese capitalism by
ensuring that Chinese firms pay higher wages to their workers and that they
are forced to pay the same additional costs (e.g. for pollution and waste)
that regulation in the USA and the EU demands.

In essence, what the IMF (and many other similar commentaries) are
suggesting is not so much a rebalancing of the Chinese economy – away from
exports and investment, and towards greater internal consumption – but a
rebalancing of the global economy, in which the Chinese internal market is
expanded so that the crisis-ridden nations of the West can export their
problems elsewhere.

The same refrain is also frequently heard within the EU: “Germany must
reduce its trade surplus and increase its internal consumption.” But both
the Chinese and the German capitalists have their own interests, separate
from those of the capitalists in the rest of Europe and the USA, and will
not be so keen for any “rebalancing” of their economies. This highlights
the other great contradiction of capitalism, the contradiction of the
nation state, which, alongside the ownership of private property, hems in
the productive forces and the development of society.

In the final analysis, any “rebalancing” to create greater internal
consumption would require an increased share of the country’s wealth to go
towards wages – which form this internal market –and a decreased share to
go towards profits. In other words, the wealth of a society must fall to
one of two camps: the working class or the capitalists.

But this process is not happening in China. According to the IMF,
“corporate profit ratios have been rising on average... Recent data suggest
that while profit margins may be weakening in some sectors, they continue
to remain healthy on aggregate.”

Whilst wages have been increasing in real terms (in many cases due to the
increased militancy and organisation of the Chinese working class), the
wealth being produced has increased even more dramatically, meaning that
workers are not receiving a greater share of the country’s wealth overall,
as the IMF reports:

“In the labor market, official data show wages growing at an average 15
percent over the past couple of years. Wages have been rising faster in
inland provinces as more companies relocate there from the coast. However,
the rise in aggregate wages has been only marginally above that of
productivity, and the available data suggest *that the household income to
GDP ratio is not yet on a firm upward trend*.” (our emphasis)

The IMF continues:

“...the reduction in the current account surplus to date does not yet
represent the ‘rebalancing’ in China advocated by staff over the past
several years. In particular, there is little evidence, as yet, of a
decisive shift toward consumption... This raises concerns related to the
sustainability of the recent decline in the current account surplus and the
risk of growing domestic imbalances.

“...With growing excess capacity and demographic shifts around the corner,
time is running out on the current growth model.”

Explosions on the horizon

All of the signs point to an impending economic implosion within the
Chinese economy. But more important is the social explosion that will
result from this – and which is, in fact, already occurring, as
demonstrated by the increasing level of strikes and demonstrations,
including the recent
protests<http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-asia-china-19026464>in the
eastern city of Qidong.

The expansion of industry in China has occurred at a tremendous rate over
the past decade; but this has been accompanied by an equally vast expansion
of the working class, as millions have moved from the countryside to the
cities. A whole new, fresh, militant layer of workers has been created, not
only in the previously industrialised coastal urban areas, but now also in
the inland provinces. As Marx and Engels explained, capitalism creates its
own gravediggers.

All the conditions are being prepared for a gigantic revolutionary movement
of the Chinese working class – the most powerful working class in history.
Such a movement will change the global balance of forces in a way that will
make the Chinese revolution of 1949 look like a mere rehearsal. The growth
of China’s industrial apparatus has been phenomenal in the recent decades.
But in the words of Leon Trotsky, it has dynamite built into its
foundations.


[Non-text portions of this message have been removed]



------------------------------------

---------------------------------------------------------------------------
LAAMN: Los Angeles Alternative Media Network
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Unsubscribe: <mailto:laamn-unsubscr...@egroups.com>
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Subscribe: <mailto:laamn-subscr...@egroups.com>
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Digest: <mailto:laamn-dig...@egroups.com>
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Help: <mailto:laamn-ow...@egroups.com?subject=laamn>
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Post: <mailto:la...@egroups.com>
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Archive1: <http://www.egroups.com/messages/laamn>
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Archive2: <http://www.mail-archive.com/laamn@egroups.com>
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Yahoo! Groups Links

<*> To visit your group on the web, go to:
    http://groups.yahoo.com/group/laamn/

<*> Your email settings:
    Individual Email | Traditional

<*> To change settings online go to:
    http://groups.yahoo.com/group/laamn/join
    (Yahoo! ID required)

<*> To change settings via email:
    laamn-dig...@yahoogroups.com 
    laamn-fullfeatu...@yahoogroups.com

<*> To unsubscribe from this group, send an email to:
    laamn-unsubscr...@yahoogroups.com

<*> Your use of Yahoo! Groups is subject to:
    http://docs.yahoo.com/info/terms/

Reply via email to