http://21stcenturysocialism.com/article/review_red_plenty_by_francis_spufford_01992.html
Tuesday, 27th July 2010

by Paul Cockshott / May 23rd 2010
Review: Red Plenty by Francis Spufford

This is a marvelous and unusual book. It sits in a remarkable way in
between science popularisation, social history and fiction. The author
describes it variously as a novel whose hero is an idea and a fairytale.
The hero idea is that of optimal planning. The idea of running a planned
economy in just such a way as to ensure that resources are optimally
used in order to deliver the ?red plenty? of the title.

Combining real and imagined characters, politicians like Khrushchev,
mathematicians and economists like Kantorovich and Nemchinov with
fictionalised minor characters, it gives a gripping and apparently
realistic picture of life in the USSR during the 50s and 60s. It is not
a single narrative as one expects from historical fiction. Instead it
gives us a series of snapshots from the lives of individuals, separated
by years. The common link is the project of the Cybernetic economic
reformers, and the ambitions of Khrushchev to attain communist plenty.

The author shows real skill as a science populariser, explaining such
diverse topics as how the Pentode valve logic of the early BESM
computers worked, to the molecular mechanics of the carcinogenesis
mechanism that eventually killed its designer. He vividly portrays the
enthusiasm and self confidence of the USSR in the late 50s when
Khrushchev?s boasts that they would overtake the USA by 1980 and achieve
communism seemed plausible. He gives a good didactic account both of the
basic mechanisms of the Soviet Economy, and, through the lives of
incidental characters paints a picture of its real operation that is
more detailed and convincing than any academic history.

He traces the idea of cybernetic economic management from the hope of
the 50s and early 60s to its sidelining under Kosygin, and the eventual
relegation of Kantorovich to the less ambitious task of optimisating
steel tube output for the oil and natural gas industry. Ironically, says
Spufford, as growth rates slipped in the 70s, it was only the
exploitation of petroleum for export that allowed Soviet living
standards to rise.

This is a book that should be read by anyone who is seriously interested
in the possibility of a different sort of economy from the one we now
have. It shows both the strengths, and the hidden weaknesses of the most
serious attempt so far to construct an alternative to capitalism, an
attempt that was born when the idea of a communist future was taken very
seriously by a whole society. To read it is to be convinced that
whatever the truth of standard leftist criticism of the USSR as being
undemocratic and bureacratic, there was much more than that at issue in
this tragedy.

It raises real political and philosophical issues that would have to be
faced by any future socialist project, and draws attention to a
forgotten history that today?s socialists ignore at their peril.

The bulk of what we read and hear about the USSR focuses on the 20s and
30s. The remaining 50 years of its history fade before the glamour,
grandeur and horror of the early years. But the early 1960s, when Russia
was already an industrial country, with many areas of internationally
competitive technology in aviation, space, computing holds more relevant
lessons for the European left than its early years.

It is clear what lesson orthodox economists will draw:

    "It?s a timely exploration, now so many people have gone off the
idea of markets, of why the alternative is worse."

But such conclusions betray an unjustified and callous smugness. It is a
smugness not justified by the elegaic last paragraph of the book. The
restoration of the market mechanism in Russia was a vast controlled
experiment. Nation, national character and culture, natural resources
and productive potential remained the same, only the economic mechanism
changed. If Western economists were right, then we should have expected
economic growth and living standards to have leapt forward after the
Yeltsin shock therapy. Instead the country became an economic
basket-case. Industrial production collapsed, technically advanced
industries atrophied, and living standards fell so much that the death
rate shot up by over a third leading to some 7.7 million extra deaths.

If you were old, if you were farmer, if you were a manual worker, the
market was a great deal worse than even the relatively stagnant Soviet
economy of Brezhnev. The recovery under Putin, such as it was, came
almost entirely as a side effect of rising world oil prices, the very
process that had operated under Brezhnev.

But this does not excuse us from seriously considering the problems so
vividly raised in the book. Spufford recounts how the attempt to follow
the reformers' recomendations and raise the price of food to provide
more income for farmers provoked strikes by industrial workers, which
were suppressed with great brutality. The same scenario played itself
out in Poland in the 70s and 80s, when any attempt to raise the
ridiculously low subsidised meat prices led to strikes.

Spufford brings out the disconnection between the recomendations of the
reform economists and the real lives of the people that the reforms
would impact on. Food subsidies were the bad conscience of inequality.
They were necessary because without them, those on the lower wage rates
could scarcely have survived. Marx had advocated that in the first stage
of communism everybody would be paid in labour vouchers not money - 1
hour's work getting 1 hour's vouchers. Goods would be directly priced in
terms of the labour required to make them and social expenditure would
be met out of a tax or time-levy on incomes. Soviet prices deviated
considerably from labour values for two reasons:

    * The well known subsidies on essential foods and housing.
    * The turnover tax was, I think, calculated on the basis of total
turnover not just wages, as such it was similar to the fixed percent
markup Marx posited for prices of production. Given that due to
subsidies, wages underestimated the real value of labour power, this
sort of markup would mean that the deviation of prices from labor value
would actually have been bigger than under capitalism.

To have furthered Khrushchev?s avowed aim of communism, Kantrovich would
have had to propose egalitarian pay rates and a shift in state finance
from turnover taxes to income taxes, before prices could be rationalised.

Spufford gives greatest emphasis to the policies of those around
Kantorovich and Nemchinov, who were advocating price reforms as part of
a programme to allow optimal operation of the economy. Kantorovich
argued that these prices - objectively determined valuations - arose out
of the objective technical structure of the economy. If actual prices
corresponded to objectively determined values, then the signals that
these prices provided would guide individual factories to produce in
accordance to what the plan needed.

There is of course a strong similarity between this argument and that
put forward by Western economists about the role of prices in guiding
resource allocation in a market economy. It is probably no accident then
that Kantorovich was the only Soviet economist to get a Nobel Prize for
economics.

But there was a fatal paradox in this whole notion, one that Spufford
brought out in a meeting between Kosygin and a leading reformer: how
were these optimal prices to be calculated? The maths was well
understood, but the technical problems of handling that much data with
1960s computers were vast. And if Gosplan could concentrate the
information and could have done the computations, then the indicative
prices would have been unneccessary - the whole process of calculation
could have been done in-natura with the Objective Valuations only having
a fleeting existence as coefficients within the matrices of the planning
computers.

So the programme of Kantorovich ended up requiring the same level of
computing resources as that of his rival cyberneticist Victor Gluschov
who apparently advocated the complete abolition of money - something
superficially closer to Krushchev's vision of communism. In this context
it is worth reading InterNyet: why the Soviet Union did not build a
nationwide computer network by Slava Gerovitch. It would have been
interesting had Gluschov appeared as a character in the book, rather
than just as someone who is refered to indirectly. In the afterword it
becomes clear why Gluschov remains such a shadowy figure to Spufford.
Spufford reveals that he relied entirely on English language sources.
What he knew of Gluschov came from Gerovitch?s brief account.

All in all, let me say again, this is a book that should be read by
anyone with a serious interest in economic alternatives.

_______________________________________________
Marxism-Thaxis mailing list
Marxism-Thaxis@lists.econ.utah.edu
To change your options or unsubscribe go to:
http://lists.econ.utah.edu/mailman/listinfo/marxism-thaxis

Reply via email to