Wealth and the Culture of Nations


Gregory Clark


 


Modern economists have turned Adam Smith into a prophet,
just as Communist regimes once deified Karl Marx. The central tenet they
attribute to Smith – that good incentives, regardless of culture, produce good
results – has become the great commandment of economics. Yet that view is a
mistaken interpretation of history (and probably a mistaken reading of Smith).


Modern growth came not from better incentives, but from
the creation of a new economic culture in societies like England
and Scotland.
To get poor societies to grow, we need to change their cultures, not just their
institutions and associated incentives, and that requires exposing more people
in these societies to life in advanced economies.


Despite the almost universal belief by economists in the
primacy of incentives, three features of world history demonstrate the
dominance of culture.


·       
In the past, excellent governments
– that is, governments that fully incentivized the citizenry – have gone hand
in hand with economic stagnation.


·       
The incentives for economic
activity are much better in most poor economies, including pre-industrial
economies, than in such prosperous and contented economies as Germany
or Sweden.


·       
The Industrial Revolution itself
was the product of changes in basic economic preferences by people in England,
not changes in institutions.


For example, the cotton textile industry that developed in
Bombay between 1857 and 1947 operated with no employment restrictions, complete
security of capital, a stable and efficient legal system, no import or export
controls, freedom of entry by entrepreneurs from around the world, and free
access to the British market. Moreover, it had access to some of the world’s
cheapest capital and labor, in an industry where labor accounted for more than
60% of manufacturing costs. Profit rates of only 6-8% in the early twentieth
century were enough to induce construction of new mills.


Yet India’s
textile industry could not compete against Britain’s,
even though British wages were five times higher. Incentives alone could not
produce growth.


At the opposite end of the spectrum, Scandinavia
is notorious among economists for high taxes and government spending. Wage
income is effectively taxed at a whopping rate of 50-67%. Economic activity is
everywhere hedged by rules, regulations, and restrictions. Yet these are
successful economies, producing as much per worker hour as the United
  States, and growing steadily.


By contrast, in medieval England,
typical tax rates on labor and capital income were 1% or less, and labor and
product markets were free and competitive. Yet there was no economic growth.
Even though assets such as land were completely secure (in most English
villages, land had passed from owner to owner unchallenged through the courts
for 800 years or more), investors had to be paid real returns of 10% to hold
land.


The Industrial Revolution occurred in a setting where the
economy’s basic institutional incentives were unchanged for hundreds of years,
and, if anything, were getting worse. Yet, over the centuries, the responses to
these incentives gradually strengthened and entrepreneurship took hold. Profit
opportunities from converting common land into private land, which had existed
since the Middle Ages, were finally pursued. Roads that had been largely
impassable from neglect for hundreds of years were repaired and improved by
local efforts. The rate of return required on safe investments declined from
10% to 4%.


Thus the crucial determinants of wealth and poverty are
not differences in incentives, but differences in how people respond to them.
In successful economies, people work hard, accumulate, and innovate even when
their incentives are poor. In failed economies, people work little, save
little, and stick with outmoded techniques even when incentives are good.


How can we transform the economic cultures of poor
societies to be more like rich ones?


When workers move from a poor to a rich economy, there is
rapid adaptation to the economic mores of the new society. In the textile
industry in the early twentieth century, for example, output per worker hour of
Polish workers in New England was four times greater
than that of Polish workers using the same machines in Poland.
One reason for illegal migration from the poor to the rich economies is many
such migrants’ ability to adapt to economic life in rich economies.


Migrants accustomed to conditions in successful economies
are a potential nucleus for industrialization in poor societies. But these
workers usually choose to remain in rich economies. A skilled Nigerian
immigrant in the US,
for example, has more opportunities there than if he returned to Nigeria.
The flow of migrants is all from poor to rich economies, particularly for
workers with skills and education.


Thus, the problem is to engineer a sufficient flow of
return migration to poor societies by those with exposure to the social
conditions of economically successful societies. Aid to poor societies in the
form of programs designed to expose their students and workers to the
experience of living and working in the US before returning home will be more
effective than trying to make these societies’ governments and institutions
more like those of the advanced economies. People come first.


** Gregory Clark is
Chairman of the Department of Economics at the University of California, Davis. 
His most recent book is A Farewell to Alms: A Brief
Economic History of the World.


Copyright: Project
Syndicate, 2007. http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/clark1







      
____________________________________________________________________________________
Fussy? Opinionated? Impossible to please? Perfect.  Join Yahoo!'s user panel 
and lay it on us. http://surveylink.yahoo.com/gmrs/yahoo_panel_invite.asp?a=7 

Kirim email ke