http://www.stratfor.com/weekly/20080930_political_nature_economic_crisis
 
The Political Nature of the Economic Crisis



September 30, 2008 | 2115 GMT







By George Friedman
Classical economists like Adam Smith and David Ricardo referred to their 
discipline as “political economy.” Smith’s great work, “The Wealth of Nations,” 
was written by the man who held the chair in moral philosophy at the University 
of Glasgow. This did not seem odd at the time and is not odd now. Economics is 
not a freestanding discipline, regardless of how it is regarded today. It is a 
discipline that can only be understood when linked to politics, since the 
wealth of a nation rests on both these foundations, and it can best be 
understood by someone who approaches it from a moral standpoint, since 
economics makes significant assumptions about both human nature and proper 
behavior. 
The modern penchant to regard economics as a discrete science parallels the 
belief that economics is a distinct sphere of existence — at its best when it 
is divorced from political and even moral considerations. Our view has always 
been that the economy can only be understood and forecast in the context of 
politics, and that the desire to separate the two derives from a moral teaching 
that Smith would not embrace. Smith understood that the word “economy” without 
the adjective “political” did not describe reality. We need to bear Smith in 
mind when we try to understand the current crisis.
Societies have two sorts of financial crises. The first sort is so large it 
overwhelms a society’s ability to overcome it, and the society sinks deeper 
into dysfunction and poverty. In the second sort, the society has the resources 
to manage the situation — albeit at a collective price. Societies that can 
manage the crisis have two broad strategies. The first strategy is to allow the 
market to solve the problem over time. The second strategy is to have the state 
organize the resources of society to speed up the resolution. The market 
solution is more efficient over time, producing better outcomes and 
disciplining financial decision-making in the long run. But the market solution 
can create massive collateral damage, such as high unemployment, on the way to 
the superior resolution. The state-organized resolution creates inequities by 
not sufficiently punishing poor economic decisions, and creates long-term 
inefficiencies that are costly. But it has
 the virtue of being quicker and mitigating collateral damage. 
Three Views of the Financial Crisis
There is a first group that argues the current financial crisis already has 
outstripped available social resources, so that there is no market or state 
solution. This group asserts that the imbalances created in the financial 
markets are so vast that the market solution must consist of an extended period 
of depression. Any attempt by the state to appropriate social resources to 
solve the financial imbalance not only will be ineffective, it will prolong the 
crisis even further, although perhaps buying some minor alleviation up front. 
The thinking goes that the financial crisis has been building for years and the 
economy can no longer be protected from it, and that therefore an extended 
period of discipline and austerity — beginning with severe economic 
dislocations — is inevitable. This is not a majority view, but it is 
widespread; it opposes government action on the grounds that the government 
will make a terrible situation worse.
A second group argues that the financial crisis has not outstripped the ability 
of society — organized by the state — to manage, but that it has outstripped 
the market’s ability to manage it. The financial markets have been the problem, 
according to this view, and have created a massive liquidity crisis. The 
economy — as distinct from the financial markets — is relatively sound, but if 
the liquidity crisis is left unsolved, it will begin to affect the economy as a 
whole. Since the financial markets are unable to solve the problem in a time 
frame that will not dramatically affect the economy, the state must mobilize 
resources to impose a solution on the financial markets, introducing liquidity 
as the preface to any further solutions. This group believes, like the first 
group, that the financial crisis could have profound economic ramifications. 
But the second group also believes it is possible to contain the consequences. 
This is the view of the
 Bush administration, the congressional leadership, the Federal Reserve Board 
and most economic leaders.
There is a third group that argues that the state mobilization of resources to 
save the financial system is in fact an attempt to save financial institutions, 
including many of those whose imprudence and avarice caused the current crisis. 
This group divides in two. The first subgroup agrees the current financial 
crisis could have profound economic consequences, but believes a solution 
exists that would bring liquidity to the financial markets without rescuing the 
culpable. The second subgroup argues that the threat to the economic system is 
overblown, and that the financial crisis will correct itself without major 
state intervention but with some limited implementation of new regulations. 
The first group thus views the situation as beyond salvation, and certainly 
rejects any political solution as incapable of addressing the issues from the 
standpoint of magnitude or competence. This group is out of the political game 
by its own rules, since for it the situation is beyond the ability of politics 
to make a difference — except perhaps to make the situation worse. 
The second group represents the establishment consensus, which is that the 
markets cannot solve the problem but the federal government can — provided it 
acts quickly and decisively enough. 
The third group spoke Sept. 29, when a coalition of Democrats and Republicans 
defeated the establishment proposal. For a myriad of reasons, some 
contradictory, this group opposed the bailout. The reasons ranged from moral 
outrage at protecting the interests of the perpetrators of this crisis to 
distrust of a plan implemented by this presidential administration, from 
distrust of the amount of power ceded the Treasury Department of any 
administration to a feeling the problem could be managed. It was a diverse 
group that focused on one premise — namely, that delay would not lead to 
economic catastrophe.
>From Economic to Political Problem
The problem ceased to be an economic problem months ago. More precisely, the 
economic problem has transformed into a political problem. Ever since the 
collapse of Bear Stearns, the primary actor in the drama has been the federal 
government and the Federal Reserve, with its powers increasing as the nature of 
potential market outcomes became more and more unsettling. At a certain point, 
the size of the problem outstripped the legislated resources of the Treasury 
and the Fed, so they went to Congress for more power and money. This time, they 
were blocked. 
It is useful to reflect on the nature of the crisis. It is a tale that can be 
as complicated as you wish to make it, but it is in essence simple and elegant. 
As interest rates declined in recent years, investors — particularly 
conservative ones — sought to increase their return without giving up safety 
and liquidity. They wanted something for nothing, and the market obliged. They 
were given instruments ultimately based on mortgages on private homes. They 
therefore had a very real asset base — a house — and therefore had collateral. 
The value of homes historically had risen, and therefore the value of the 
assets appeared secured. Financial instruments of increasing complexity 
eventually were devised, which were bought by conservative investors. In due 
course, these instruments were bought by less conservative investors, who used 
them as collateral for borrowing money. They used this money to buy other 
instruments in a pyramiding scheme that rested
 on one premise: the existence of houses whose value remained stable or grew.
Unfortunately, housing prices declined. A period of uncertainty about the value 
of the paper based on home mortgages followed. People claimed to be confused as 
to what the real value of the paper was. In fact, they were not so much 
confused as deceptive. They didn’t want to reveal that the value of the paper 
had declined dramatically. At a certain point, the facts could no longer be 
hidden, and vast amounts of value evaporated — taking with them not only the 
vast pyramids of those who first created the instruments and then borrowed 
heavily against them, but also the more conservative investors trying to put 
their money in a secure space while squeezing out a few extra points of 
interest. The decline in housing prices triggered massive losses of money in 
the financial markets, as well as reluctance to lend based on uncertainty of 
values. The result was a liquidity crisis, which simply meant that a lot of 
people had gone broke and that those who still
 had money weren’t lending it — certainly not to financial institutions.
The S&L Precedent
Such financial meltdowns based on shifts in real estate prices are not new. In 
the 1970s, regulations on savings and loans (S&Ls) had changed. Previously, 
S&Ls had been limited to lending in the consumer market, primarily in mortgages 
for homes. But the regulations shifted, and they became allowed to invest more 
broadly. The assets of these small banks, of which there were thousands, were 
attractive in that they were a pool of cash available for investment. The S&Ls 
subsequently went into commercial real estate, sometimes with their old 
management, sometimes with new management who had bought them, as their 
depositors no longer held them. 
The infusion of money from the S&Ls drove up the price of commercial real 
estate, which the institutions regarded as stable and conservative investments, 
not unlike private homes. They did not take into account that their presence in 
the market was driving up the price of commercial real estate irrationally, 
however, or that commercial real estate prices fluctuate dramatically. As 
commercial real estate values started to fall, the assets of the S&Ls 
contracted until most failed. An entire sector of the financial system simply 
imploded, crushing shareholders and threatening a massive liquidity crisis. By 
the late 1980s, the entire sector had melted down, and in 1989 the federal 
government intervened.
The federal government intervened in that crisis as it had in several crises 
large and small since 1929. Using the resources at its disposal, the federal 
government took over failed S&Ls and their real estate investments, creating 
the Resolution Trust Corp. (RTC). The amount of assets acquired was about $394 
billion dollars in 1989 — or 6.7 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) — 
making it larger than the $700 billion dollars — or 5 percent of GDP — being 
discussed now. Rather than flooding the markets with foreclosed commercial 
property, creating havoc in the market and further destroying assets, the RTC 
held the commercial properties off the market, maintaining their price 
artificially. They then sold off the foreclosed properties in a multiyear 
sequence that recovered much of what had been spent acquiring the properties. 
More important, it prevented the decline in commercial real estate from 
accelerating and creating liquidity crises
 throughout the entire economy.
Many of those involved in S&Ls were ruined. Others managed to use the RTC 
system to recover real estate and to profit. Still others came in from the 
outside and used the RTC system to build fortunes. The RTC is not something to 
use as moral lesson for your children. But the RTC managed to prevent the 
transformation of a financial crisis into an economic meltdown. It disrupted 
market operations by introducing large amounts of federal money to bring 
liquidity to the system, then used the ability of the federal government — not 
shared by individuals — to hold on to properties. The disruption of the 
market’s normal operations was designed to avoid a market outcome. By holding 
on to the assets, the federal government was able to create an artificial 
market in real estate, one in which supply was constrained by the government to 
manage the value of commercial real estate. It did not work perfectly — far 
from it. But it managed to avoid the most feared
 outcome, which was a depression.
There have been many other federal interventions in the markets, such as the 
bailout of Chrysler in the 1970s or the intervention into failed Third World 
bonds in the 1980s. Political interventions in the American (or global) 
marketplace are hardly novel. They are used to control the consequences of bad 
decisions in the marketplace. Though they introduce inefficiencies and 
frequently reward foolish decisions, they achieve a single end: limiting the 
economic consequences of these decisions on the economy as a whole. Good idea 
or not, these interventions are institutionalized in American economic life and 
culture. The ability of Americans to be shocked at the thought of bailouts is 
interesting, since they are not all that rare, as judged historically.
The RTC showed the ability of federal resources — using taxpayer dollars — to 
control financial processes. In the end, the S&L story was simply one of bad 
decisions resulting in a shortage of dollars. On top of a vast economy, the 
U.S. government can mobilize large amounts of dollars as needed. It therefore 
can redefine the market for money. It did so in 1989 during the S&L crisis, and 
there was a general acceptance it would do so again Sept. 29.
The RTC Model and the Road Ahead
As discussed above, the first group argues the current crisis is so large that 
it is beyond the federal government’s ability to redefine. More precisely, it 
would argue that the attempt at intervention would unleash other consequences — 
such as weakening dollars and inflation — meaning the cure would be worse than 
the disease. That may be the case this time, but it is difficult to see why the 
consequences of this bailout would be profoundly different from the RTC bailout 
— namely, a normal recession that would probably happen anyway.
The debate between the political leadership and those opposing its plan is more 
interesting. The fundamental difference between the RTC and the current bailout 
was institutional. Congress created a semi-independent agency operating under 
guidelines to administer the S&L bailout. The proposal that was defeated Sept. 
29 would have given the secretary of the Treasury extraordinary personal powers 
to dispense the money. Some also argued that the return on the federal 
investment was unclear, whereas in the RTC case it was fairly clear. In the 
end, all of this turned on the question of urgency. The establishment group 
argued that time was running out and the financial crisis was about to morph 
into an economic crisis. Those voting against the proposal argued there was 
enough time to have a more defined solution. 
There was obviously a more direct political dimension to all this. Elections 
are just more than a month a way, and the seat of every U.S. representative is 
in contest. The public is deeply distrustful of the establishment, and 
particularly of the idea that the people who caused the crisis might benefit 
from the bailout. The congressional opponents of the plan needed to demonstrate 
sensitivity to public opinion. Having done so, if they force a redefinition of 
the bailout plan, an additional 13 votes can likely be found to pass the 
measure.
But the key issue is this: Are the resources of the United States sufficient to 
redefine financial markets in such a way as to manage the outcome of this 
crisis, or has the crisis become so large that even the resources of a $14 
trillion economy mobilized by the state can’t do the job? If the latter is 
true, then all other discussions are irrelevant. Events will take their course, 
and nothing can be done. But if that is not true, that means that politics 
defines the crisis, as it has other crisis. In that case, the federal 
government can marshal the resources needed to redefine the markets and the key 
decision-makers are not on Wall Street, but in Washington. Thus, when the chips 
are down, the state trumps the markets.
All of this may not be desirable, efficient or wise, but as an empirical fact, 
it is the way American society works and has worked for a long time. We are 
seeing a case study in it — including the possibility the state will refuse to 
act, creating an interesting and profound situation. This would allow the 
market alone to define the outcome of the crisis. This has not been allowed in 
extreme crises in 75 years, and we suspect this tradition of intervention will 
not be broken now. The federal government will act in due course, and an 
institutional resolution taking power from the Treasury and placing it in the 
equivalent of the RTC will emerge. The question is how much time remains before 
massive damage is done to the economy.



Mark R. Taylor
 
Take no prisoners!
 

http://americantruckersatwar.com
AmericanTruckersAtWar Discussion Group
http://youtube.com/ironponyexpress
 
--~--~---------~--~----~------------~-------~--~----~
You received this message because you are a member of the "News Sarasota" 
Google group...

To read more, go to: 


http://www.newssarasota.com 
http://newssarasotaezine.talkspot.com 


To hear more, go to: 


http://thecaptainsamerica.podomatic.com 


Enjoy the priviledge you now share with others who want to know what others 
don't...

Thanks, 

Matt Bruce
Managing Editor
News Sarasota.com
Retired 25 Year Fire-Rescue Captain
Host Of:
"The Captain's AMERICA" Show
Heard From 12 noon to 1 PM ET Monday Thru Friday
LIVE On Net Talk World.com
Across America & Around The Globe At The Speed Of The Internet...
Weekend's Overnight on The Accent Radio Network...
Check Out:
http://thecaptainsamerica.com
http://www.nettalkworld.com

For more options, visit this group at 
http://groups.google.com/group/News-Sarasota...

To post to this group, send email to [EMAIL PROTECTED]

To unsubscribe from this group, send email to [EMAIL PROTECTED]
-~----------~----~----~----~------~----~------~--~---

Reply via email to