It seems to me that lost in the invective of this debate is some
of the history of the 'expropriation of the aboriginal commons', at
least as I understand it in the NA context.

First, with regard to the intermingling of the (mercantile) capitalist
mode of production with the aboriginal domestict mode of production during
the period of the fur trade, the conclusion of most of the recent
research work (as expressed by the 'articulation of modes of production
literature') is that the process of the subjegation of native economies
and social structures (including European technology) came quite late in
the contact period, largely after the European began the forceful
expropriation of land (and resources) with the spread of settlement and
the agricultural frontier.  For Canadian plains indians, the end of
the buffalo economy came quite late -- between the first and second
Riel Rebellions, the end result of which was the final movement
(outside BC) of the Indian population onto reserves (but not the
Metis, Innuit or Dene).

Even then, a year or two ago I finished supervising a superb thesis
on the economic fortunes of the Indians on reserves in the period
from the 1870s to the 1940s.  Through much of this period, the
natives population did adjust to the market economy and, while
hardly prospering or growing rich, did actually quite well; so
much so that the government and local business conspired to buy,
seize, expropriate or otherwise dislodge Indian land because, in
many cases, the Indians were out competing white farmers (such as
in hay markets.)  Indeed, the federal government in canada denied
the Indians their money to buy farm machinery
because the government argued that, to maintain their way of
life, the Indians had to use traditional, labour intensive,
non-machinery mathods.  That is, the natives were denied the
right to chose to adopt modern technology and when they did and
out competed the whites, they had their land and/or resources
restricted.
  The real collapse of the native economies came, according to
this thesis on Saskatchewan (and a similar book on Manitoba)
during the depression when the aboriginals suffered the same
fate as the white farmers.  The difference was that the native
economies never recovered with the war and the rise of paternal
welfarism led to the dependency of the reserve structure which
was not (the reserve resource base) sufficient to maintain or
increase the income level.

Nevertheless, Bhoddi is right in the sense that even if we
restored to all the aboriginals all that we have expropriated
since the original treaties, and even allocated all or most of
the unallocated crown lands, it would do little now to bring
the native peoples up to a decent standard of living.  Just to
give an example, Canada is now overrun with Beaver -- aboriginals
can catch as many as they want and most of us wish that they
would as they have become a nuisance and a hazard -- but the
price of beaver pelts is so low (thanks in large part to the
so-called animal rights activists) that the cost of catching
beaver is greater than the revenue.  Look at what has happened
in BC with the salmon fishery.  The combination of overfishing
by US and Canadian fishers, pollution from logging and mining,
etc. has driven the salmon dangerously close to extinction such
that, even returning the exclusive fishing rights to the Indians
on most rivers would barely provide for a subsistence fishery,
etc. etc.

Plus, the fact that many Native people don't want to live by
the traditional ways -- i.e. want to come to the cities, get
good educations, become doctors and even economists, or get
good trades jobs.  The preservation of traditional (and in
many cases isolated) economies denies those kids who want
to integrate the tools (social and educational) to do so.

  I certainly don't have the answer to this problem  -- but
it surely is not as clear cut as either Louis or Bhoddi make
out.

Paul Phillips,
Economics,
University of Manitoba



Reply via email to