Barely two years after its release, Re-Orient may already be read in 
Chinese. And why not? Chinese elites have every reason to celebrate 
a book which  resurrects their long held belief  that the Celestial Kingdom, 
except for a temporary setback in the 19h-20th century, is the center of 
human civilization. For Frank is determined to challenge the 
Marxian-Weberian notion that China, after dominating the 
world economy throughout the medieval period, until 1500, failed 
to advance thereafter because it remained sunk in irrationality.

Not only did China prevail until 1800, but its decision to continue 
to rely on its old technology was "rational" since it was the most 
cost-effective available path of action. I mentioned before China's 
cheap labor, but Frank's argument is more complicated than this, 
as it  involves three interconnected variables: 1) low wages, 2) a 
higher population/land-resource ratio, and 3) a more polarized 
distribution of income. (Remember these are comparative cost 
assessments within a world market).

Considering Frank's earlier statistical claims about China's superior 
economy, a gift for mental gymnastics will be required to balance all 
these facts. The balancing act goes like this: 1) it was China's 
agricultural efficiency and productivity which, by providing cheap 
and plentiful foodstuffs, allowed wages to stay low. 2) As the 
greatest beneficiary of the long post-1400 growth "A" phase, which 
caused China's population to grow at a much faster rate than that 
of Europe, China had a population/land-resource ratio of 3.6/3.8 people 
per hectare as compared to England's 1.5 or France's 1.1 in 1700 
(p.308; Bairoch's figures) - which in turn kept or pushed wages down. 

3) The long growth "A" phase after 1400 also "polarized the 
distribution of income and thereby constrained effective domestic 
demand of mass consumer goods" (301). 

Number 2 is really the point around which the other explanatory 
variables revolve. But we can start with variable number 3 to show this. 
How would a long period of  economic expansion lead to 
polarization and lack of effective demand? Because such growth led 
to increases in population which led to 
scarcity of resources (land), which led to polarization. But Frank 
tip toes as well into the idea that much of the newly created wealth 
was diverted into the pockets of the elites. About India he cites Habib 
to the effect that the "Mughal Empire had been its own grave-digger", 
adding himself that "its governing class got much of its wealth through 
the expropriation of the surplus produced by the peasantry" (306). 
Tip toes because he knows he is suggesting that (a) the masses of Asia 
were indeed poorer than those of Europe (where wages were higher), 
and (b) that the phase "A" growth of Asia may have been achieved 
through increased exploitation of the peasantry, rather than through 
increased productivity. 

I shall qualify that Frank does *not know*, or want to know he is 
also suggesting  (b). But that he wants to tip toe out of  (a), when it 
suits him, is clear in his additional remarks, following Pomeranz, that 
Asia's distribution of income may not have been as skewed as 
that of Europe once we consider that China's workers could still
draw on family support. 

Yes, Frank wants the best of all possible worlds for 
China:"However, no matter through what institutional mechanisms those 
cheap subsistence wage goods were or were not distributed, they could 
only have been made available by an agriculture that was more 
productive and thereby able to produce those wage goods cheaper in 
China that in Britain and Europe" (307).    
   
But (b) takes us to number 2, which, when examined closely, betrays 
Frank's whole thesis. However we are dealing with an older, more 
experienced  Frank;  variable number 2 relies on Mark Elvin's highly  
sophisticated explanation about the failure of late-traditional China's 
economy, a model known as the "high-level equilibrium trap". This 
model needs to be carefully studied. 

thanks, ricardo  



Reply via email to