(Feel free to distribute)

Expense those options!

By Stephen F. Diamond*

 As the dust clears from the collapse of Enron, WorldCom and Arthur
Andersen, major structural change in the behavior of American corporations
and financial markets seems less likely.  The lobbying power of accounting
firms, investment banks and large corporations appears to have convinced
Congress that its best interests lies with the insiders in our economy not
with the broader public interest.  But there is one possible reform that
still has a chance: ending the practice of granting absurdly generous stock
option packages to top corporate insiders.

 The defenders of stock options argue that they help align the interests of
inside managers with outside shareholders.  This is a laudable goal, in and
of itself.  Share ownership in the last twenty years has spread to a wide
percentage of the public.  Millions of Americans, for better or worse, now
look to the stock market as the source of their retirement income.  Because
no single shareholder can afford to monitor the behavior of corporate
insiders, the public relies instead on institutions like the board of
directors to protect their interests.  Granting corporate insiders huge
option packages has been one board tactic that allegedly motivates insiders
to manage the corporation in the long-term interest of the public
shareholders.

 But this argument is based on an important mistaken assumption that stock
"options" are the same as stock.  They are not.  "Options" are different
financial instruments from the stock that underlies the option and they are
priced to reflect that difference.  Stock is priced based on a long-term
assessment of the potential earning power of a corporation.  But stock
options are priced to take into account a range of factors that includes the
value of the stock but also the time to expiration of the option and, most
importantly, the volatility of the underlying stock.  Options actually
increase in value with an increase in the volatility of the underlying
stock.  An increase in volatility increases the chance that the option will
be "in the money" and hence profitable for insiders.

Why should outside public shareholders care about this difference?  Because
an increase in the volatility of the stock is something that corporate
insiders can manipulate by engaging in higher risk projects.  The insiders
can increase the value of their options by engaging in "all or nothing"
gambles.  After all, if the project is a success it might cause a huge
increase in the stock price, with a gain to outside shareholders as well.
The potential gain to insiders has been so huge in recent years that they
have been tempted to engage not only in high risk projects but in
manipulation of corporate earnings and other illegal activity that is, in
essence, theft from outside shareholders and looting of corporate assets, an
important public resource.

If the insider bet is a bust the options expire with no loss to the insider
while the outside shareholders will see a huge drop in the value of their
shares.  In fact, the insiders often walk away with luxurious golden
parachutes, no matter what the outcome of their speculative activities.
Dennis Kozlowski, the ousted CEO of Tyco, was set to earn $137,000 a year
for life as a consultant and lifelong use of the corporation's fleet of
airplanes!

In other cases insiders have walked away with millions of dollars even as
stock prices stagnate or decline, as they cash in on past options granted at
steep discounts to the current price.  Oracle CEO and Chairman Larry Ellison
cashed in $700 million of options that were nearly a decade old in 2001.
His sale came just in time, as Oracle stock plummeted from more than $34 per
share to around $13 per share weeks later when the Company told the public
that sales and profits were down.  The stock of Standard Microsystems
Corporation began the year 2001 at $20 a share and declined by almost fifty
percent at one point only to finish the year at slightly below $20.  Thus, a
net goose egg for outside shareholders, but CEO Steven Bilodeau received a
pay package worth more than $2.2 million including options and exercised
older options for another $2.5 million.  And, according to the AFL-CIO's
Executive Pay Watch, a fifty percent drop in the 2001 price of the stock of
Gap, the troubled clothing retailer, did not stop CEO and President Millard
Drexler from raking in more than $9 million in total compensation including
new stock options.

Thus, insiders' interests are not aligned with those of outside public
shareholders by stock options; they are, in fact placed at odds with each
other.  Despite this conflict, corporations can pretend that options are
given away for free, since they are not required to charge the cost of the
options as an expense item in company accounts.  At the very least, options
should be charged as a compensation expense to corporate income statements.
Even more reasonable would be to get rid of options altogether and force
insiders to hold restricted stock that they could only sell after leaving
the corporation.  This would put them much closer to the actual position of
outside public shareholders.   Public corporations should serve the public
interest and the managers of public corporations must be reminded of this.

*Stephen F. Diamond teaches securities law and corporate finance at the
Santa Clara University School of Law.

Stephen F. Diamond
School of Law
Santa Clara University
[EMAIL PROTECTED]

Reply via email to