Memorial Service for Paul Marlor Sweezy (1910-2004)

A memorial service for Paul Sweezy will be held on Saturday, April 17, 3-6pm at Landmark on the Park, 160 Central Park West (at 76th Street). Please call (212) 691-2555 for further details.

by John Bellamy Foster

Referred to by The Wall Street Journal in 1972 as “the ‘dean’ of radical economists,” Paul M. Sweezy was, in the words of John Kenneth Galbraith, “the most noted American Marxist scholar” of the second half of the twentieth century.(1) Sweezy’s intellectual influence, which was global in its reach, lay chiefly in two areas: as a leading radical economist (and sociologist), and as the principal originator of a distinct North American brand of socialist thought in his position as co-founder and co-editor of Monthly Review magazine. Like both Marx and Schumpeter, to whose thought his work was closely related, Sweezy provided a historical analysis and crtique of capitalist economic development, encompassing a theory of the origins, development and eventual decline of the system.

Sweezy was born April 10, 1910 in New York. His father, Everett B. Sweezy was vice president of First National Bank of New York headed by George F. Baker, a close partner of J.P. Morgan and Company. His mother, Caroline (Wilson) Sweezy was in the first graduating class from Goucher College in Baltimore. He had two older brothers, Everett, born 1901, and Alan, born 1907. All three brothers went to Exeter and then to Harvard. In the early years, Paul followed in the footsteps of his brother Alan. Both Alan and Paul were editors of the Exonian and then later presidents of the Harvard Crimson. Both studied economics at the undergraduate and graduate levels at Harvard. Paul had all but completed his senior year at Harvard when his father died in 1931, interrupting his studies. Consequently, he did not graduate officially (magna cum laude) until the following year in 1932. In 1931-32, however, having already finished his undergraduate studies, he began graduate courses in economics at Harvard. It was at this time of intense study that his interests shifted decisively from journalism to economics.

In 1932 Sweezy left for England for a year’s study at the London School of Economics (during student breaks he also spent several months studying in Vienna). As a result of his experiences in Britain his life was to change considerably. Like many he had been shaken by the onset of the Great Depression. His father had lost the greater part of his fortune in the 1929 Crash, although enough remained to ensure a comfortable existence. In Britain Sweezy was awakened by the intellectual and political ferment of what was a turning point in world history. Not only did the depression deepen in this period but Hitler also came to power in Germany. His initial intention in attending the London School was to work with the conservative economist Friedrich Hayek. However, in the heated debates then taking place, particularly among younger scholars, Sweezy found himself increasingly attracted to Marxism. Key influences inducing this change in perspective were lectures he attended by Harold Laski at the London School and reading Leon Trotsky’s History of the Russian Revolution, which had just been translated into English. Sweezy was also affected by the rapid developments in economics in England in this period. It was at this time that he became acquainted with some of the younger, left-leaning Cambridge economists, including Joan Robinson.

In 1933 Sweezy returned to do graduate studies in economics at Harvard. He found the intellectual climate dramatically transformed. Marxism, which in his prior years at Harvard had played no part in his education, had by then become a topic of discussion in some of the larger universities. One big change was the arrival at Harvard of Joseph Schumpeter, one of the foremost economists of the twentieth century. A conservative economist, Schumpeter nonetheless had enormous respect for the economics of Karl Marx, even going so far—as Sweezy once put it—“to build a structure of thought which was to rival Marx. In other words he took Marx as a model in a way.”(2) Schumpeter had a small seminar of around a half dozen students in which Sweezy took part. Over the years the two became fast, even legendary friends, engaged in continual intellectual discussions and debates, in which other notable figures such as Oskar Lange and Wassily Leontiev and later Paul Samuelson also took part. Sweezy was for two years Schumpeter’s teaching assistant in his graduate course in economic theory.

During these years at Harvard Sweezy co-founded the journal Review of Economic Studies and published a series of important economic essays on issues of imperfect competition, the role of expectations in Keynesian analysis and economic stagnation. He was deeply affected by the revolution in economics introduced by John Maynard Keynes and incorporated aspects of Keynes’ analysis into his thought while remaining a Marxian critic.

In September 1936 Sweezy and Abba Lerner, a young economist at the London School of Economics, wrote a letter to the New Statesman and Nation responding an earlier article by Keynes on British foreign policy” in that publication. They argued that the failure of Britain to oppose the fascist powers in Ethiopia and Spain was a product of the class interest of the British ruling class, which, while opposed to fascism generally, put the defense of private property ahead of its national interests. Any other interpretation but the Marxist one, they argued, would leave analysts like Keynes himself in his article merely “surprised at the incredible stupidity that must be attributed to the British Foreign Office.” The two young economists ended their letter by indicating their “very highest admiration for Mr. Keynes’ work in our field. We think he has done more than any other writer in our time towards laying bare one of the deepest contradictions of the capitalist economy, the coexistence of willing hands and open mouths.” Keynes replied that the explanation for these shortcomings of British foreign policy was the “unqualified pacifism” of much of the British public. “Those who fail to observe it and interpret everything in terms of Capitalist and Communist theory are blind to their surroundings.”(3)

After John Maynard Keynes’ General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money was published in 1936 Sweezy became a very active participant in the Harvard discussions surrounding the Keynesian Revolution in economic theory. At the same time he married a young economist, Maxine Yaple. During this period he was working for various New Deal agencies. In 1937 he carried out an important study of “Interest Groups in the American Economy” for the National Resources Committee, which was published in 1939 as an appendix to the NRC’s well-known report, The Structure of the American Economy. In opposition to Berle and Means’ claim that a large number of U.S. firms were management controlled, Sweezy argued that it was possible to discern eight leading “interest groups” consisting of industrial and financial alliances. In the first group he listed the investment banking firm of J.P. Morgan and Co. and its alliance with the First National Bank, in which his father had worked. Sweezy also carried out research in this period for the Security and Exchange Commission on their study of monopoly in 1939 and for the Temporary National Economic Committee charged with analyzing the U.S. economy, particularly with respect to issues of competition and monopoly in 1940.

Sweezy’s first formal economic publication was “Professor Pigou’s Theory of Unemployment” published in the Journal of Political Economy in 1934. Over the course of the 1930s he wrote more than twenty-five articles and reviews on economic topics. Two of the papers that he authored in this period were to be of lasting importance for his work. The first was his article “Expectations and the Scope of Economics” in the Review of Economic Studies in June 1938. The second was his classic article, “Demand Under Conditions of Oligopoly,” in the Journal of Political Economy, August 1939. The earlier article reflected the Keynesian concern with expectations under conditions of economic disequilibrium and uncertainty. The second introduced the famous “kinked demand curve” theory of oligopolistic pricing, which explained why oligopolistic prices tend to go only one way—up. Both of these themes were to play a large role in the later theory of monopoly capital, as developed by Sweezy and Paul Baran. The kinked demand curve hypothesis originally developed out of Sweezy’s 1927 dissertation Monopoly and Competition in the English Coal Industry, 1550-1850, which won the David A. Wells prize and was published in the following year by Harvard University Press. Schumpeter was on Sweezy’s dissertation committee.

In 1938 Sweezy became an Instructor at Harvard. During these years he and his brother Alan helped in the founding of the Harvard Teacher’s Union, as a branch of the American Federation of Teachers. In addition to teaching the principles of economics and a course on corporations, he took over a course on the economics of socialism formerly taught by Edward Mason. It was in the process over a number of years of developing the lectures for this course that he wrote his seminal work The Theory of Capitalist Development: Principles of Marxian Political Economy (1942). He later explained that it had required an enormous struggle on his part to shift from the marginal utility analysis that he had learned through classic texts by figures like Harvard’s Frank Taussig, to Marx’s labor theory of value—a shift in thinking that could not be accomplished in a day or even a year, since these frameworks raised entirely different sets of questions. In drafting the manuscript for the The Theory of Capitalist Development he received help from the Japanese economist Shigeto Tsuru, who was then studying at Harvard and provided an appendix for the book on Marx’s reproduction schemes. This classic work is still used to teach Marxian economics to students in economics. More than simply a textbook it made a number of pioneering contributions, including: its emphasis on the qualitative (not simply quantitative) value problem in Marx’s treatment of the labor theory of value, its elaboration of the Bortkiewicz solution to the transformation problem; and its discussions of crisis theory and monopoly capitalism. It also provided in the introduction of the book what was to be an influential explanation of Marx’s method.

The most important conclusion of the The Theory of Capitalist Development had to do with the long-run stagnation of investment under capitalism arising from an in-built tendency in the system toward the overaccumulation of capital. “Stagnation of production, in the sense of less-than-capacity utilization of productive resources”--Sweezy was to write, evoking a theme that was to repeat itself again and again in his work,-- “is to be regarded as the normal state of affairs under capitalist conditions. If this view is adopted the whole crisis problem appears in a new light. Emphasis shifts from the question: ‘What brings on crisis and depression?’ to its opposite: ‘What brings on expansion?’” The Theory of Capitalist Development appeared in the same year as Schumpeter’s Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy and the two works can be seen as two sides of a complex debate on the future of capitalism and socialism. Schumpeter referred numerous times to Sweezy, and in particular to The Theory of Capitalist Development, in his History of Economic Analysis (1951), where he “strongly recommended” Sweezy’s book, “as an admirable presentation of Marx’s (and most of the neo-Marxists’) economic thought.”

full: http://www.monthlyreview.org/paulsweezy.htm

--

The Marxism list: www.marxmail.org

Reply via email to