Is there anyone here interested in explaining economic growth in terms of
knowledge as per Debra Amidon's recent book The Innovation Highway?

Happy to form a readers club if there are any co-believers? Publicly we are
starting an European Union debate on this around here
http://www.knowledgeboard.com/cgi-bin/item.cgi?id=98621&d=1&h=417&f=56&datef
ormat=%o%20%B%20%Y

chris macrae [EMAIL PROTECTED]
----- Original Message -----
From: "Alypius Skinner" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
To: <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
Sent: 11 December 2002 20:40 PM
Subject: Fw: New theory explains economic growth in terms of evolutionary
biology


>
>
> > New theory explains economic growth in terms of evolutionary biology
> >
> > The struggle for survival that characterized most of human existence
> > stimulated a process of natural selection that conferred an evolutionary
> > advantage on humans who had a higher genetic predisposition for a
careful
> > rearing of the next generation. This evolutionary change permitted the
> > Industrial Revolution to trigger a change from an epoch of stagnation to
> an age
> > of sustained economic growth, according to the first theory that
> integrates the
> > fields of evolutionary biology and economic growth. This research by
Brown
> > University economist Oded Galor and Omer Moav from the Hebrew University
> is the
> > lead article in the current Quarterly Journal of Economics.
> >
> >
>
> --------------------------------------------------------------------------
> >
> >       PROVIDENCE, R.I. - It took an evolutionary leap in the human
species
> to
> > help trigger the change from centuries of economic stagnation to a state
> of
> > sustained economic growth, according to the first theory that integrates
> > evolutionary biology and economics.
> >
> >       "Until now, economic growth theory did not have implications for
> > evolutionary biology, and evolutionary biology did not have implications
> for
> > economic growth," said lead theorist Oded Galor, professor of economics
at
> > Brown University.
> >
> >       This new theory, the first of its kind ever proposed in the
> economics
> > literature, appears as the lead article in the current Quarterly Journal
> of
> > Economics. It is co-authored by Omer Moav of the Hebrew University of
> > Jerusalem.
> >
> >       "The struggle for survival that had characterized most of human
> existence
> > stimulated a process of natural selection and generated an evolutionary
> > advantage to human traits that were complementary to the growth process,
> > triggering the takeoff from an epoch of stagnation to sustained economic
> > growth," the authors wrote in their study.
> >
> >       The evolution of the human brain in the transition to Homo sapiens
> > "increased the evolutionarily optimal investment in offspring's
quality,"
> said
> > Galor. "This was due to the complementary relationship between brain
> capacity
> > and the return to investment in human capital."
> >
> >       The process gave an evolutionary advantage to people who had
higher
> > valuation toward offspring's quality, Galor said. "The subsequently
> increased
> > prevalence of this genetic trait in the population ultimately permitted
> the
> > Industrial Revolution to trigger a transition to a state of sustained
> economic
> > growth."
> >
> >       The critical natural selection that occurred prior to the
Industrial
> > Revolution involved the fundamental tradeoff between child-caring and
> > child-rearing. The "epoch of stagnation" gave an evolutionary advantage
to
> a
> > higher-quality smaller family rather than to lower-quality larger
> families,
> > Galor said.
> >
> >       "Valuation of quality, through better nourishment and education
for
> > children, fed back into technological progress. And as technology
> advanced, it
> > fed back into more education. Human capital took off. This leap in
> evolution
> > came to dominate the population as a whole, and centuries of economic
> > stagnation ended."
> >
> >       The authors attribute acceleration in this evolutionary process to
> the
> > emergence of the nuclear family that fostered intergenerational links.
> Prior to
> > the agricultural revolution, 10,000 years ago, people lived among
> > hunter-gatherer tribes that tended to share resources more equally.
> >
> >       "During this hunter-gatherer period, the absence of direct
> > intergenerational links between parental resources and investment in
their
> > offspring delayed the evolutionary advantage of a preference for
> high-quality
> > children," said the authors.
> >
> >       In fact, according to the theory, a switch back to a quantity
> emphasis
> > began to take place in the 20th century.
> >
> >       "During the transition from stagnation to growth, once the
economic
> > environment improved sufficiently, the evolutionary pressure weakened
and
> the
> > significance of quality for survival declined," said Galor. The inherent
> > advantage in reproduction of people who highly value a large number of
> children
> > gradually dominated and their fertility rates ultimately overtook the
> fertility
> > rates of people who value high-quality children, he said.
> >
> >       "Oded Galor's tendency to ask big, important questions, to be
> tackled in
> > ambitious and technically sophisticated models have earned him a
> well-deserved
> > reputation as one of the most ingenious and interesting growth-theorists
> of our
> > age," said Joel Mokyr, professor of economics and history, Northwestern
> > University. Mokyr is a leading expert on the history of technological
> progress
> > and the Industrial Revolution.
> >
> >       "Galor and Moav have opened a new and potentially very fruitful
vein
> of
> > thinking about the history of economies in the very long run," said
Mokyr.
> > "This pioneering paper is a breakthrough in its use of population
dynamics
> in
> > long-term historical change and in applying Darwinian logic to the
history
> of
> > mankind."
> >
> >       The predictions of the proposed theory are consistent with the
time
> path
> > of population, technology and income since the emergence of Homo
sapiens,
> said
> > Galor.
> >
> >       "Once biologists identify the genes that control fertility
behavior,
> the
> > predictions of the theory in the context of the evolution of the human
> species
> > could be tested as well, comparing genetic valuation for quality in
> > hunter-gatherer tribes to those in societies that have experienced the
> > Neolithic revolution," Galor said.
> >
> >       According to the authors, earlier episodes of technological
progress
> did
> > not generate a "takeoff" because the necessary human evolutionary change
> had
> > not yet completed its course.
> >
> >       "The population did respond to higher return to education and
> investment
> > in human capital, but not aggressively enough to generate an
acceleration
> in
> > the rate of technological progress and sustained economic growth," said
> Galor.
> >
> >       The theory generates an alternative intriguing prediction, he
said.
> >
> >       "It suggests that during the epoch of stagnation, men who were
from
> a
> > physiological viewpoint moderately fertile (men with a moderate sperm
> count),
> > and who were therefore induced by nature to invest more in the quality
of
> their
> > offspring had an evolutionary advantage over highly fertile
individuals,"
> Galor
> > said. This would suggest that sperm count has declined in the last
> thousands of
> > years, he said.
> >
> >       The National Science Foundation supported Galor's research.
> >
> > http://www.brown.edu/Administration/News_Bureau/2002-03/02-040.html
> >
> >
> >
> >
>
>
>
>
>


Reply via email to