Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-17 Thread robert bristow-johnson


okay, Abd ul, i once got suckered into responding to a big long thing  
you made in response to me.  you probably seen it, but the list  
hasn't because it exceeded some size limit.  so i'm gonna snip at the  
first place to respond and i'll ask that the next issue area get its  
separate email thread (we might even spawn new subject lines).  i  
just can't deal with size explosion to this degree.


On Jan 17, 2010, at 12:53 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


At 01:44 AM 1/15/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

but the problem with considering *more* than pure ranking (Range) is
that it requires too much information from the voter.  and the
problem with *less* (Approval or FPTP) is that it obtains too little
information from the voter.


There is a common error here, which is to assume that Range  
requires too much information from the voter.


well, it does force the voter to consider the questions oh, i hate  
this guy 28% more than i hate the other guy, so how do i rate each  
candidate in range?  the range rating values are a superset of the  
adjacent integer rankings from a ranked-order ballot like one for  
Condorcet, IRV, Borda.  in the ranked-order ballot, all the voter has  
to decide is who she would vote for in adjacent candidates: ABC.   
she doesn't have to decide how much more she likes B over C than how  
much A is over B.  one is a quick set of qualitative decisions.  the  
other makes it a quantitative issue, and that's when a lot of us get  
out our dartboard.  i don't think making threshold decision based on  
the precise sum of a bunch of noisy numbers (which is what Range is  
when we use our dartboards to score a candidate) does much other than  
to add the means of the noisy numbers and a sum of zero-mean random  
numbers which throws a little bit of dice into the mix before using  
the threshold comparison and determining the winner.


so it requires thinking that we wouldn't have to do otherwise.  if we  
don't feel like thinking that seriously, it becomes a big noisy  
threshold on the means of stable ranks.  that's sorta like Borda and  
does become the equivalent if people's evaluations of candidates  
sorta linear.



First of all, Approval is Range, simply the most basic Range method.


it's Range with 1-bit binary values.

So what you have is a contradiction: Range requires both too much  
and too little information. Surely it depends on the specific Range  
implementation.


yes it does.   of course the answer is (if i may appeal to an audio  
image) that what we *normally* mean when we say Range is were the  
sliders for each candidate are either continuous or have many  
discrete values (say 10 or 100).


a two-position slider is what we call a switch. requires one bit of  
information.  that's getting qualitatively different.  either you are  
at the minimum number of levels (or bits of information in the slider  
position) or you're not.


perhaps a 3-position slider can be Actively Disapprove, no opinion  
- neutral, and Actively Approve


perhaps a 4-position slider can be Actively Disapprove, no opinion  
- neutral, and Actively Approve and Hey, I really like this guy!


perhaps a 5-position slider can be This guy is crap, Actively  
Disapprove, no opinion - neutral, and Actively Approve and Hey,  
I really like this guy!


we can continue on like this with more discrete levels and all we'll  
get are gradations of the above.  it's all a matter of degree.


but the 2-position slider is a 1-bit piece of information:  
No,Yes, that's the minimum a voter has to judge.  that's  
qualitatively different.  here's why:  with the multi-level (3 or  
more), then order has to be considered with candidates that you  
approve or disapprove.


but the multi-level or continuous slider (3+) requires *more* than  
just ordering information (who is preferred to whom?), it requires  
*spacing* information.  like i hate candidate D worse than i hate C  
whom i dislike more than B whom i like less than A.  you have to  
decide that D is twice as badder than C than C is badder than B or  
some other value judgement.  what if you just don't feel like making  
such a precise judgement?  then you get your dartboard.




--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum) (Kathy Dopp)

2010-01-17 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 5:02 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:


robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 16, 2010, at 3:41 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:



Exactly as I tried to point out to you, you were either disallowing
voters to rank only two candidates or to rank all three.
no, it has nothing at all to do with allowing or disallowing the 
voters to

  I see I was
correct and you are disallowing voters to rank only two candidates and
have, as Abd ul also pointed out to you, left 3 choose 2 or 6 possible
choices out of your list.
because all unmarked candidates are tied for last place, when there 
is only one unmarked candidate, there is *no* consequential 
difference between leaving that candidate unmarked or marking that 
candidate last.


Is that true in IRV? Consider a vote of the sort:

A  B

where A and B are eliminated. Then this would be an empty vote, I 
think, and so be removed from the count, whereas if it had been


A  B  C

it would count as one point for C.


now lemme see, if there are three candidates, how are two of them 
eliminated before the IRV final round?


Ah, I see. The only way for that to happen is if both B and C tie for 
last, in which case A wins by default.


Thus it only matters if there are more than three candidates, i.e. when 
both ABC and AB votes are truncated.


think about it little bit, Kristofer, it *is* a useful fiction to leave 
the 2 bottom candidates (of 5) out of consideration (so one can get a 
grip of what happened in Burlington VT in 2009), but once you've done 
that (and you're considering only what happens between the remaining 3), 
the 9 numbers that are the only tallies you need to consider *any* 
counting scenario, IRV, Condorcet, Plurality of 1st choice, tallies for 
1st or 2nd choice (some people in Burlington have suggested that as the 
number to use to determine the weakest candidate to eliminate in an IRV 
round), whatever, are:



  1332  MKW
   767  MWK
   455  M
  2043  KMW
   371  KWM
   568  K
  1513  WMK
   495  WKM
  1289  W


with exactly those three candidates in consideration, what consequential 
difference would it make in IRV (or any other rule of tabulation) if the 
[1332  MKW] pile was split into two piles; [MKW] and [MK] that 
totaled 1332?  those 9 numbers could certainly be determined in 
individual precincts and meaningfully summed at City Hall or the 
campaign headquarters of either candidate.


I'm not sure if it would be equivalent in Borda, however. Some ways of 
extending Borda to incomplete (truncated) ballots suggest that you give 
the last candidate 1 point, the next to last 2, etc, so that for


A  B

B gets one point and A two, whereas for

A  B  C

A gets three.

It would also make a difference if the election method in question uses 
no opinion the way Warren's Range extension does: that no opinion is 
to provide no information at all (alters neither the numerator nor 
denominator of the average).


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-17 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

robert bristow-johnson wrote:

we can continue on like this with more discrete levels and all we'll get 
are gradations of the above.  it's all a matter of degree.


but the 2-position slider is a 1-bit piece of information: No,Yes, 
that's the minimum a voter has to judge.  that's qualitatively 
different.  here's why:  with the multi-level (3 or more), then order 
has to be considered with candidates that you approve or disapprove.


but the multi-level or continuous slider (3+) requires *more* than just 
ordering information (who is preferred to whom?), it requires *spacing* 
information.  like i hate candidate D worse than i hate C whom i 
dislike more than B whom i like less than A.  you have to decide that D 
is twice as badder than C than C is badder than B or some other value 
judgement.  what if you just don't feel like making such a precise 
judgement?  then you get your dartboard.


To me, it seems that the method becomes Approval-like when (number of 
graduations) is less than (number of candidates). When that is the case, 
you *have* to rate some candidates equal, unless you opt not to rate 
them at all.


That won't make much of a difference when the number of candidates is 
huge (100 or so), but then, rating 100 candidates would be a pain. I'd 
say it would be better to just have plain yes/no Approval for a first 
round, then pick the 5-10 most approved for a second round (using 
Range, Condorcet, whatever). Or use minmax approval or PAV or somesuch, 
as long as it homes in on the likely winners of a full vote.


I guess that if you (hypothetically speaking) like Range, you could 
argue that while there's a dartboard effect, the noise is unbiased and 
so will cancel itself out given enough voters: the voters may not hit 
exactly at the satisfaction point, but close enough.


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairer than IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

2010-01-17 Thread Kathy Dopp
Hi Chris,

I respond to your claims below.

On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 11:23 PM, Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au wrote:




 - Forwarded Message 
 From: Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au
 To: EM election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Sent: Fri, 15 January, 2010 4:21:31 AM
 Subject: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairer than IRV/STV 
 and lack most IRV/STV flaws

 Kathy Dopp wrote (11 Jan 2010):

 snip

 IRV/STV is fundamentally unfair because a large group of persons whose
 first choice loses, never has their 2nd choice counted, unlike some
 other voters. It's a highly inequitable method.

 snip

 Kathy Dopp wrote (13 Jan 2010):

 For those who need a system for substituting for a top-two runoff
 election, I devised two fair methods to suggest to her that do not
 have all the flaws of IRV/STV. (They both may've been devised by
 others before me. My goal was to create a fair method without
 IRV/STV's flaws which solve the problem of one person/one vote which
 is necessary to get a voting method approved by US courts.
 --

 I believe that these
 alternative systems (below) are also susceptible to the spoiler effect
 of a nonwinning candidate changing who wins the election, although I
 believe that there is a significant difference between the alternative
 methods below and plurality and IRV where a majority opposed candidate
 may win the election. In other words, I believe that the winner due to
 a spoiler in the alternative method below is more likely to be a majority
 favorite.


 If  majority opposed means having a majority-strength pairwise loss,
 then there is no decisive method that assures that no such candidate
 can win.

You could be right on that statement Chris. I wasn't thinking about
all the possibilities when I wrote the above.


 I'm not sure what Kathy means by a majority favorite. That phrase is
 usually taken to refer to a candidate that is strictly top-ranked by more
 than half the voters. The Majority Favorite criterion is met by IRV and
 Plurality among many others, but not by Borda or Range.

Sorry. I should use the phrase Condorcet winner for what I mean.



 Both methods below solve the problem of every voter having a vote of
 value one and, unlike IRV, treat all voters alike by counting all
 their choices

 So, here are two possible methods that are fairer than IRV/STV and
 which are monotonic (unlike IRV/STV):

 1. A rank choice ballot method:

 Any number of candidates may be running for office and any number
 allowed to be ranked on the ballot.

 Voter ranks one candidate vote =1

 Voter ranks two candidates, denominator is 1+2 = 3
 votes are worth 2/3 and 1/3 for first and second ranked candidates

 Voter ranks three candidates, denominator is 1+2+3=6
 votes are worth 3/6 and 2/6 and 1/6 for 1st, 2nd, and 3rd choice respectively

 Voter ranks four candidates, denominator is 1+2+3+4=10
 votes are worth 4/10, 3/10, 2/10, and 1/10 for 1st, 2nd, and 3rd and
 4th choice respectively

 ETC. Just follow the same pattern

 51: AB
 40: B
 09: CA


 A: (51 x 2/3 = 34) + (9 x 1/3 = 3) = 37.
 B: (40 x 1 = 40) + (51 x 1/3 = 17) = 57
 C: (9 x 2/3) = 6.

 Kathy's proposed point score method here elects B in violation of
 Majority Favourite.

Yes. But also notice that B is also a majority favorite in that 91
voters out of 100 prefer B over C and 40/100 prefer B strongly enough
to bullet vote, so the vast majority of voters should be happy with
this result, unlike with IRV where a majority may think that the
elected candidate is the worst choice, as happened in Burlington, VT
mayoral election.


 Also of course if the  A supporters had not ranked B then A would
 have won, a big violation of Later-no-Harm.

Later-no-harm is a very bad feature of IRV that prevents IRV from
finding majority-favorite compromise candidates and tends to elect
extreme right or extreme left candidates. In any negotiation, it is
necessary to reveal the 2nd choices of all parties early on, not hide
2nd choices entirely of some voters and never consider them at all
like IRV does to most voters in many elections.



 2. A point system where a total number of points per voter per contest
 may be allocated by the voter to any of the candidates running for
 office:

 Two candidates running for office, give all voters 2+1=3 votes to
 cast.  They may cast all three votes for one candidate or split the
 votes any way between the two.

 Three candidates running for office, give all voters 3+2+1=6 votes to
 cast. They may cast all six votes for one candidate or split the votes
 any way they like between the three.

 Four candidates running for office, give all voters 4+3+2+1=10 votes
 to cast. They may cast all ten votes for one candidate or split the
 votes any way they like between the four.

 Five candidates running for office, give all voters 5+4+3+2+1=15 votes
 to cast. They may cast all 15 votes for one candidate or split the
 votes any way they like.

 This 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-17 Thread Kathy Dopp
For the record, I like approval voting and think it would be among the
best, if not the best, first step as an alternative voting method to
plurality.  However, I also think Condorcet is OK as long as voters
are not required to rank all choices, to alleviate the point Abd ul
mentions below somewhat.  Really, the only methods I would object to
are the fundamentally unfair ones like IRV/STV that treat voters'
votes differentially and thus produce very undesirable election
results and remove the rights of some voters to fully participate.
Approval, if courts OK it, is by far the simplest to count, audit,
explain to voters, etc. and is probably the best first step.  Using
IRV/STV as a first step may turn off people to alternative electoral
methods for a very long time after they realize how deeply they've
been misled on how it works, its effects, etc.

I am now going to, for the most part, soon drop out of participation
in this list again for the Spring semester at college.

Kathy

On Sun, Jan 17, 2010 at 12:53 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
a...@lomaxdesign.com wrote:
 At 01:44 AM 1/15/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

 but the problem with considering *more* than pure ranking (Range) is
 that it requires too much information from the voter.  and the
 problem with *less* (Approval or FPTP) is that it obtains too little
 information from the voter.

 There is a common error here, which is to assume that Range requires too
 much information from the voter. First of all, Approval is Range, simply the
 most basic Range method. So what you have is a contradiction: Range
 requires both too much and too little information. Surely it depends on the
 specific Range implementation.

 But there is a more fundamental error: that of requirement. Voters may
 vote in Approval, and Range, as they would vote in Plurality, if they want,
 and for most voters, this is a simple and powerful strategy. If they favor a
 frontrunner, and if there are only two frontrunners (the normal situation!),
 whatever else they would do would be moot for election purposes. But they
 could cast votes to show support, which has other salutary effects. That, in
 fact, is why Warren Smith calls Range an incubator for minor parties. It
 allows them to show their natural support, neither more nor less.

 The only issue about voting strategy arises in a real three-way race,
 which is not common. Most voters, however, would be reasonably served by a
 very simple strategy. Vote first for your favorite candidate, no strategy
 necessary or even useful. Then consider the frontrunners, however many there
 are, it's the set of candidates that you think have a prayer of winning, and
 vote for your favorite of them. (in Approval, that's it, in Range, it means
 vote max or maybe just short of max). Is your favorite one of the
 frontrunners?.

 Vote minimum rating (i.e., in Approval, don't vote at all for) the worst
 candidate, with no strategic considerations at all. Vote similarly for the
 worst frontrunner: minimum rating or just a tad higher if the system allows
 it.

 And then where do you vote for the rest of the candidates, the ones in the
 middle? Well, pay attention first to any remaining frontrunners. (In most
 elections, there aren't any left, but we are now talking about a situation
 where there are three or more, and we should remember that this is rare.) My
 own conclusion from study of the game theory involved is that possible
 expected improvement from seriously optimizing Range votes is small at best
 over simply voting sincere ratings, and as long as preference order isn't
 reversed, it's all likely to average out. At worst, from clear exaggeration
 in order to gain some strategic advantage, it's possible to cast a vote that
 will leave behind serious regret once you know the outcome.

 When you have ranked the frontrunners where it seems right, then fill in any
 remaining candidates you want to rate. If it gets crowded, equal rank a
 candidate being added with the one already ranked.

 Rating equals ranking with the option of equal ranking.

 Equal preference strength expression (i.e., if one spreads the candidates
 through the rating space evenly) is Borda count. If you don't like that, if
 it seems to be off, then fix it. Spread some ratings apart, which
 necessarily compresses some. Don't hesitate to equal rank if you have any
 difficulty deciding which of two candidates are better. The fact that you
 have difficulty is a clear indication that you don't have a strong
 preference!

 I would not spend a lot of time actually doing the ranking/rating. The hard
 part is learning enough about the candidates to have a foundation for
 opinions. So if I don't have enough information to do that, I don't have
 strong preferences! and so voting is easy, if I simply express that. I can
 spread my vote over the full range if I think that my intuition might be
 valuable (it can be! -- but it may also be vulnerable to media
 manipulation). My choice. Range 

[EM] IRV vs Plurality ( Kristofer Munsterhjelm )

2010-01-17 Thread Chris Benham
Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote (17 Jan 2010):

To me, it seems that the method becomes Approval-like when (number of 
graduations) is less than (number of candidates). When that is the case, 
you *have* to rate some candidates equal, unless you opt not to rate 
them at all.

That won't make much of a difference when the number of candidates is 
huge (100 or so), but then, rating 100 candidates would be a pain. I'd 
say it would be better to just have plain yes/no Approval for a first 
round, then pick the 5-10 most approved for a second round (using 
Range, Condorcet, whatever). Or use minmax approval or PAV or somesuch, 
as long as it homes in on the likely winners of a full vote.

Simply using plain Approval to reduce the field to the top x point scorers
who then compete in the final round seems unsatifactory to me because
of the  Rich Party incentive (clone problem) for parties to field x 
candidates;
and because of the tempting Push-over (turkey raising) strategy incentive.

Chris Benham


  
__
See what's on at the movies in your area. Find out now: 
http://au.movies.yahoo.com/session-times/


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-17 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 03:01 AM 1/17/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 17, 2010, at 12:53 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


There is a common error here, which is to assume that Range
requires too much information from the voter.


well, it does force the voter to consider the questions oh, i hate
this guy 28% more than i hate the other guy, so how do i rate each
candidate in range?  the range rating values are a superset of the
adjacent integer rankings from a ranked-order ballot like one for
Condorcet, IRV, Borda.


Part of the problem is the way in which Range has been presented. It 
isn't really rating candidates, though that can be part of the 
process. It's *voting.*


The simplest way to describe Range, and to think about it, is that it 
is Approval Voting with fractional votes allowed. Not required.


There is a whole debate among students of Range about using average 
vote rather than sum of votes. The difference is that with sum of 
votes, we have a traditional Approval voting system, which always 
uses sum of votes. Not average vote. (Average vote is meaningless, 
really, unless the ballot asks for Yes or No or Approve/Disapprove 
for each candidate). Average vote doesn't consider majority at all. 
Naturally, I support sum of votes, and though average vote is 
interesting (in terms of understanding the future of a candidate), it 
isn't *voting*, which in it's basic form, is seeking for a majority 
of voters to vote for a candidate for the candidate to win. Is voting 
1/100 vote for a candidate voting for a candidate?


I would try to make ballot instructions make it clear that the voter 
is casting fractional votes, and probably shouldn't vote for a 
candidate at all if the voter isn't willing to support the candidate 
against others. That makes the decision much easier.



  in the ranked-order ballot, all the voter has
to decide is who she would vote for in adjacent candidates: ABC.
she doesn't have to decide how much more she likes B over C than how
much A is over B.  one is a quick set of qualitative decisions.  the
other makes it a quantitative issue, and that's when a lot of us get
out our dartboard.


Sure. But you don't have to make those quantitative decisions if you 
don't want to. It's optional, and, in fact, I prefer that voters not 
cast fractional votes unless they are easy for them to decide.



  i don't think making threshold decision based on
the precise sum of a bunch of noisy numbers (which is what Range is
when we use our dartboards to score a candidate) does much other than
to add the means of the noisy numbers and a sum of zero-mean random
numbers which throws a little bit of dice into the mix before using
the threshold comparison and determining the winner.


The numbers can be noisy, but surely you know that adding certain 
kinds of noise can improve the accuracy of a feedback system! They 
aren't actually noise, they are noisy. The averages provide 
information, and the very fact of the existence of fractional votes 
-- even just one! -- improves the utility of the system, that's been shown.




so it requires thinking that we wouldn't have to do otherwise.  if we
don't feel like thinking that seriously, it becomes a big noisy
threshold on the means of stable ranks.  that's sorta like Borda and
does become the equivalent if people's evaluations of candidates
sorta linear.


First of all, Approval is Range, simply the most basic Range method.


it's Range with 1-bit binary values.


Yup. Range 1, I call it, which means that there are two possible 
votes, generally with one being the default. Approval voting is 
Plurality voting, with the *option* of voting for more than one. Most 
voters, under normal conditions in the U.S., don't need to do it!



So what you have is a contradiction: Range requires both too much
and too little information. Surely it depends on the specific Range
implementation.


yes it does.   of course the answer is (if i may appeal to an audio
image) that what we *normally* mean when we say Range is were the
sliders for each candidate are either continuous or have many
discrete values (say 10 or 100).


Only Smith considers a continuous slider, and I prefer, simply, to 
consider that what separates Range from Approval is the ability to 
cast fractional votes. Freedom from the voter. Sure: if you have 
freedom you have more choices and, gosh, you might even be tempted to *think*!


Tell me, do you want voters to think or do you think of voting 
systems as a device that extracts information from voters without 
them thinking about it? And making actual decisions?



a two-position slider is what we call a switch. requires one bit of
information.  that's getting qualitatively different.  either you are
at the minimum number of levels (or bits of information in the slider
position) or you're not.


And all the switches are off by default. So, don't want to do much work?

First option: don't vote at all! Leave it to others who know more and 
care more. And this 

Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairer than IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

2010-01-17 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 08:38 AM 1/17/2010, Kathy Dopp wrote:


 Also of course if the  A supporters had not ranked B then A would
 have won, a big violation of Later-no-Harm.

Later-no-harm is a very bad feature of IRV that prevents IRV from
finding majority-favorite compromise candidates and tends to elect
extreme right or extreme left candidates. In any negotiation, it is
necessary to reveal the 2nd choices of all parties early on, not hide
2nd choices entirely of some voters and never consider them at all
like IRV does to most voters in many elections.


Chris is Australian, and is one of a rare breed: someone who actually 
understands STV and supports it for single-winner because of LNH 
satisfaction. Of course, LNH is a criterion disliked by many voting 
system experts, and it's based on a political concept which is, quite 
as you say, contrary to sensible negotiation process.


In rational process, people start by advocating their first 
preference, and will only disclose lower preferences if the 
preference strength of the favorite over the lower ones is low or zero.


Then, as they become aware of the first preferences of others, they 
will start to disclose lower preferences. The more eager they are to 
find consensus, the sooner they will do this. In Range, they *may* do 
it immediately, or they may conceal those preferences, it is their option.


My problem with straight Range voting is precisely because it 
too-quickly bypasses the normal strategy. And it will be less 
effective because of this.


However, Bucklin does imitate the rational process, and Range/Bucklin 
would do it even more accurately. The voter discloses to the method, 
as it were, as if the ballot becomes the voter's agent, true relative 
utilities. That becomes the optimum strategy! The system then slides 
down the voter's established utilities, starting out by bullet voting 
for the favorite or any equally rated candidates. Not finding a 
majority, it then clicks down the scale for all voters and checks 
again, and it keeps doing this until it finds a majority winner. If 
it's a deterministic election, it will go all the way down to the 
lowest non-zero rating. But I greatly prefer only setting a winner if 
a true majority approval is found, thus the method sticks with the 
tradition, a tradition which has centuries of experience behind it, 
and which is only abandoned in public elections in the name of 
efficiency over democracy.


There is a name for that choice. Fascism. But I'm not claiming that 
plurality is fascist, just that some aspects of some of the arguments 
for it are.


What I'd do with Range/Bucklin is to use it to discover if there is a 
majority winner with the Bucklin process. Then I'd count all the 
votes for all candidates. If sum of votes indicates a different 
winner, I'd hold a runoff. If not, that's it.


If there is no majority-approved winner, there is a runoff. I'll 
defer, for a moment, the question of candidate eliminations. 
Ultimately, I prefer no eliminations, or, at most, only ballot 
listing eliminations, write-ins still allowed. Or perhaps the 
candidates are listed on the second ballot with their Range ratings 
from the first election, so voters have that information handy and 
can make reasonable compromises right there. And the second election 
might be pure Bucklin (i.e., Approval/Bucklin).


And what happens if there is no majority in the runoff? In democratic 
organizations, they just keep at it until they get a majority. If 
there is a harm from the office not being filled, well, that's 
pressure to make a compromise. If the majority of people don't want 
to fill the office by finding a majority compromise, we have a loss 
of democracy, I call it the tyranny of the past. It was decided, 
that, in the future, decisions would be made with less than a 
majority. However, there is an option. If there is a question asked 
on the ballot, Shall this election be awarded to the candidate with 
the most votes, even if there is no majority, the majority will have 
determined on an election unconditionally if more voters vote yes on 
that question than vote no. But under current conditions, we wouldn't 
ask that question. We might be afraid of the answer we get.


Those who are in power fear that the power might evaporate, and often 
come to not trust the people. Systemic problem, I'm not blaming anyone.



Yes. *Any* system that guarantees the principle of
one-person/one-vote as some US judges insist on, has the feature
that it encourages bullet voting.


Actually, there are few decisions that insist on a narrow 
interpretation of one-person, one-vote. Minnesota is in an odd 
situation now, but I should really read the recent decision. Brown v. 
Smallwood was an anomaly, not confirmed anywhere else.


What is important is that, in the end, everyone gets equal voting 
power, without discrimination. Taking this principle to the end 
conclusions, though, plurality has some severe problems, so does IRV. 
Approval, in 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-17 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
Cutting to the chase, the fundamental error has been to assume that  
write-in or so-called inconsequential candidates can be batch- 
eliminated before having results from the whole election. No precinct  
knows what can be eliminated until it has the results from other  
precincts for the first round. Further a method must accomodate not  
just a most-common scenario but also all possible scenarios. Runoff  
voting in general encourages candidate counts to increase. Cf. San  
Francisco.


We are talking about the matrix size necessary to fully canvass an IRV  
election centrally from initial data provided by each precinct. That  
initial data might categorize all write-candidates into a single pile,  
but the risk is that if reports from other precincts indicate possible  
significance, it would be necessary to ask the precincts to tabulate  
the write-in pile. If you did this with so-called minor candidates,  
you'd see a lawsuit, which is less likely with write-ins. 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

2010-01-17 Thread Terry Bouricius
Kathy,

you wrotesnip
...unlike with IRV where a majority may think that the
elected candidate is the worst choice, as happened in Burlington, VT
mayoral election.
snip
That is incorrect for Burlington, (the IRV winner was the second
Condorcet-winner if the actual Condorcet-winner is removed, and favored
above the other three candidates.) And it is a fundamental fact that the
IRV winner can never be a candidate that the majority think is the worst
choice. IRV can never elect the Condorcet-loser. The ultimate winner must
be preferred above the other finalist in the last round of the tally.

It is PLURALITY voting, which you support, that often DOES elect the
Condorcet-loser, who a majority agree is the worst choice.

Terry Bouricius

- Original Message - 
From: Kathy Dopp kathy.d...@gmail.com
To: Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au; EM
election-methods@lists.electorama.com
Sent: Sunday, January 17, 2010 8:38 AM
Subject: Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are
fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws


Hi Chris,

I respond to your claims below.

On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 11:23 PM, Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au
wrote:




 - Forwarded Message 
 From: Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au
 To: EM election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Sent: Fri, 15 January, 2010 4:21:31 AM
 Subject: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairer than
 IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

 Kathy Dopp wrote (11 Jan 2010):

 snip

 IRV/STV is fundamentally unfair because a large group of persons whose
 first choice loses, never has their 2nd choice counted, unlike some
 other voters. It's a highly inequitable method.

 snip

 Kathy Dopp wrote (13 Jan 2010):

 For those who need a system for substituting for a top-two runoff
 election, I devised two fair methods to suggest to her that do not
 have all the flaws of IRV/STV. (They both may've been devised by
 others before me. My goal was to create a fair method without
 IRV/STV's flaws which solve the problem of one person/one vote which
 is necessary to get a voting method approved by US courts.
 --

 I believe that these
 alternative systems (below) are also susceptible to the spoiler effect
 of a nonwinning candidate changing who wins the election, although I
 believe that there is a significant difference between the alternative
 methods below and plurality and IRV where a majority opposed candidate
 may win the election. In other words, I believe that the winner due to
 a spoiler in the alternative method below is more likely to be a
 majority
 favorite.


 If majority opposed means having a majority-strength pairwise loss,
 then there is no decisive method that assures that no such candidate
 can win.

You could be right on that statement Chris. I wasn't thinking about
all the possibilities when I wrote the above.


 I'm not sure what Kathy means by a majority favorite. That phrase is
 usually taken to refer to a candidate that is strictly top-ranked by
 more
 than half the voters. The Majority Favorite criterion is met by IRV
 and
 Plurality among many others, but not by Borda or Range.

Sorry. I should use the phrase Condorcet winner for what I mean.



 Both methods below solve the problem of every voter having a vote of
 value one and, unlike IRV, treat all voters alike by counting all
 their choices

 So, here are two possible methods that are fairer than IRV/STV and
 which are monotonic (unlike IRV/STV):

 1. A rank choice ballot method:

 Any number of candidates may be running for office and any number
 allowed to be ranked on the ballot.

 Voter ranks one candidate vote =1

 Voter ranks two candidates, denominator is 1+2 = 3
 votes are worth 2/3 and 1/3 for first and second ranked candidates

 Voter ranks three candidates, denominator is 1+2+3=6
 votes are worth 3/6 and 2/6 and 1/6 for 1st, 2nd, and 3rd choice
 respectively

 Voter ranks four candidates, denominator is 1+2+3+4=10
 votes are worth 4/10, 3/10, 2/10, and 1/10 for 1st, 2nd, and 3rd and
 4th choice respectively

 ETC. Just follow the same pattern

 51: AB
 40: B
 09: CA


 A: (51 x 2/3 = 34) + (9 x 1/3 = 3) = 37.
 B: (40 x 1 = 40) + (51 x 1/3 = 17) = 57
 C: (9 x 2/3) = 6.

 Kathy's proposed point score method here elects B in violation of
 Majority Favourite.

Yes. But also notice that B is also a majority favorite in that 91
voters out of 100 prefer B over C and 40/100 prefer B strongly enough
to bullet vote, so the vast majority of voters should be happy with
this result, unlike with IRV where a majority may think that the
elected candidate is the worst choice, as happened in Burlington, VT
mayoral election.


 Also of course if the A supporters had not ranked B then A would
 have won, a big violation of Later-no-Harm.

Later-no-harm is a very bad feature of IRV that prevents IRV from
finding majority-favorite compromise candidates and tends to elect
extreme right or extreme left candidates. In any negotiation, 

Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

2010-01-17 Thread Kathy Dopp
On Sun, Jan 17, 2010 at 12:34 PM, Terry Bouricius
ter...@burlingtontelecom.net wrote:
 Kathy,

 you wrotesnip
 ...unlike with IRV where a majority may think that the
 elected candidate is the worst choice, as happened in Burlington, VT
 mayoral election.

To clarify, what I meant to say is that in Burlington, the IRV winner
was the worst choice of a majority of voters *out of the three
candidates who were viable*.  There are many other voting methods that
do not share that flaw with IRV/STV. In fact do any alternatives to
plurality share that IRV/STV flaw?

 snip
 That is incorrect for Burlington, (the IRV winner was the second
 Condorcet-winner if the actual Condorcet-winner is removed, and favored
 above the other three candidates.) And it is a fundamental fact that the
 IRV winner can never be a candidate that the majority think is the worst
 choice. IRV can never elect the Condorcet-loser. The ultimate winner must
 be preferred above the other finalist in the last round of the tally.

 It is PLURALITY voting, which you support, that often DOES elect the
 Condorcet-loser, who a majority agree is the worst choice.

You are distorting the facts again Terry.  If you want to know what I
support, ask or read my posts.  I clearly support plurality if the
choice is between IRV/STV and plurality because IRV/STV are *much
worse* than plurality in a variety of ways.  However, given the choice
between plurality and virtually any other alternative voting method
I've heard proposed on this list, I support the alternatives.

Please try to stop making personal attacks and distorting the facts
about people, whenever the facts on the issues are not on your side.
It's not pretty Terry.

Kathy


 Terry Bouricius

 - Original Message -
 From: Kathy Dopp kathy.d...@gmail.com
 To: Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au; EM
 election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Sent: Sunday, January 17, 2010 8:38 AM
 Subject: Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are
 fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws


 Hi Chris,

 I respond to your claims below.

 On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 11:23 PM, Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au
 wrote:




 - Forwarded Message 
 From: Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au
 To: EM election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Sent: Fri, 15 January, 2010 4:21:31 AM
 Subject: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairer than
 IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

 Kathy Dopp wrote (11 Jan 2010):

 snip

 IRV/STV is fundamentally unfair because a large group of persons whose
 first choice loses, never has their 2nd choice counted, unlike some
 other voters. It's a highly inequitable method.

 snip

 Kathy Dopp wrote (13 Jan 2010):

 For those who need a system for substituting for a top-two runoff
 election, I devised two fair methods to suggest to her that do not
 have all the flaws of IRV/STV. (They both may've been devised by
 others before me. My goal was to create a fair method without
 IRV/STV's flaws which solve the problem of one person/one vote which
 is necessary to get a voting method approved by US courts.
 --

 I believe that these
 alternative systems (below) are also susceptible to the spoiler effect
 of a nonwinning candidate changing who wins the election, although I
 believe that there is a significant difference between the alternative
 methods below and plurality and IRV where a majority opposed candidate
 may win the election. In other words, I believe that the winner due to
 a spoiler in the alternative method below is more likely to be a
 majority
 favorite.


 If majority opposed means having a majority-strength pairwise loss,
 then there is no decisive method that assures that no such candidate
 can win.

 You could be right on that statement Chris. I wasn't thinking about
 all the possibilities when I wrote the above.


 I'm not sure what Kathy means by a majority favorite. That phrase is
 usually taken to refer to a candidate that is strictly top-ranked by
 more
 than half the voters. The Majority Favorite criterion is met by IRV
 and
 Plurality among many others, but not by Borda or Range.

 Sorry. I should use the phrase Condorcet winner for what I mean.



 Both methods below solve the problem of every voter having a vote of
 value one and, unlike IRV, treat all voters alike by counting all
 their choices

 So, here are two possible methods that are fairer than IRV/STV and
 which are monotonic (unlike IRV/STV):

 1. A rank choice ballot method:

 Any number of candidates may be running for office and any number
 allowed to be ranked on the ballot.

 Voter ranks one candidate vote =1

 Voter ranks two candidates, denominator is 1+2 = 3
 votes are worth 2/3 and 1/3 for first and second ranked candidates

 Voter ranks three candidates, denominator is 1+2+3=6
 votes are worth 3/6 and 2/6 and 1/6 for 1st, 2nd, and 3rd choice
 respectively

 Voter ranks four candidates, denominator is 1+2+3+4=10
 votes are worth 

Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

2010-01-17 Thread Terry Bouricius
Kathy,

You still have it wrong. You wrote To clarify, what I meant to say is 
that in Burlington, the IRV winner
was the worst choice of a majority of voters *out of the three candidates 
who were viable*.

No, among the top three the IRV winner, Kiss, was not less preferred than 
Wright. Both Kiss and Montroll were preferred by more voters over Wright. 
Among the three candidates who were viable it was the first round 
plurality leader, Wright, who was the Condorcet-loser, not Kiss.

The real world choice in Burlington today is between plurality and IRV. 
You have stated, that in this case you prefer Plurality, which allows the 
Condorcet-loser to be declared the winner. I agree that there is a 
powerful intellectual case for a Condorcet solution, but that is not on 
the table (even though I helped Robert Bristow-Johnson try to get it into 
the hopper for consideration.) Condorcet, so far, has not been able to get 
any traction with folks in Burlington, or in any other jurisdiction in the 
world.

Condorcet advocates may want to focus their attention on Aspen, where the 
risk is that ranked ballots may be abandoned, if IRV is repealed. 
Promoting Condorcet as an alternate direction to go there seems to be a 
natural for advocates.

Terry Bouricius



- Original Message - 
From: Kathy Dopp kathy.d...@gmail.com
To: Terry Bouricius ter...@burlingtontelecom.net
Cc: election-methods@lists.electorama.com
Sent: Sunday, January 17, 2010 1:38 PM
Subject: Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are 
fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws


On Sun, Jan 17, 2010 at 12:34 PM, Terry Bouricius
ter...@burlingtontelecom.net wrote:
 Kathy,

 you wrotesnip
 ...unlike with IRV where a majority may think that the
 elected candidate is the worst choice, as happened in Burlington, VT
 mayoral election.

To clarify, what I meant to say is that in Burlington, the IRV winner
was the worst choice of a majority of voters *out of the three
candidates who were viable*.  There are many other voting methods that
do not share that flaw with IRV/STV. In fact do any alternatives to
plurality share that IRV/STV flaw?

 snip
 That is incorrect for Burlington, (the IRV winner was the second
 Condorcet-winner if the actual Condorcet-winner is removed, and favored
 above the other three candidates.) And it is a fundamental fact that the
 IRV winner can never be a candidate that the majority think is the 
 worst
 choice. IRV can never elect the Condorcet-loser. The ultimate winner 
 must
 be preferred above the other finalist in the last round of the tally.

 It is PLURALITY voting, which you support, that often DOES elect the
 Condorcet-loser, who a majority agree is the worst choice.

You are distorting the facts again Terry.  If you want to know what I
support, ask or read my posts.  I clearly support plurality if the
choice is between IRV/STV and plurality because IRV/STV are *much
worse* than plurality in a variety of ways.  However, given the choice
between plurality and virtually any other alternative voting method
I've heard proposed on this list, I support the alternatives.

Please try to stop making personal attacks and distorting the facts
about people, whenever the facts on the issues are not on your side.
It's not pretty Terry.

Kathy


 Terry Bouricius

 - Original Message -
 From: Kathy Dopp kathy.d...@gmail.com
 To: Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au; EM
 election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Sent: Sunday, January 17, 2010 8:38 AM
 Subject: Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are
 fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws


 Hi Chris,

 I respond to your claims below.

 On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 11:23 PM, Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au
 wrote:




 - Forwarded Message 
 From: Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.au
 To: EM election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Sent: Fri, 15 January, 2010 4:21:31 AM
 Subject: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairer than
 IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

 Kathy Dopp wrote (11 Jan 2010):

 snip

 IRV/STV is fundamentally unfair because a large group of persons whose
 first choice loses, never has their 2nd choice counted, unlike some
 other voters. It's a highly inequitable method.

 snip

 Kathy Dopp wrote (13 Jan 2010):

 For those who need a system for substituting for a top-two runoff
 election, I devised two fair methods to suggest to her that do not
 have all the flaws of IRV/STV. (They both may've been devised by
 others before me. My goal was to create a fair method without
 IRV/STV's flaws which solve the problem of one person/one vote which
 is necessary to get a voting method approved by US courts.
 --

 I believe that these
 alternative systems (below) are also susceptible to the spoiler effect
 of a nonwinning candidate changing who wins the election, although I
 believe that there is a significant difference between the alternative
 methods below and 

[EM] Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairer than IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

2010-01-17 Thread Chris Benham
Abd Lomax wrote (17 Jan 2010):

snip

Chris is Australian, and is one of a rare breed: someone who actually 
understands STV and supports it for single-winner because of LNH 
satisfaction. Of course, LNH is a criterion disliked by many voting 
system experts, and it's based on a political concept which is, quite 
as you say, contrary to sensible negotiation process.
 snip

I endorse IRV (Alternative Vote, with voters able to strictly rank from the top 
however 
many candidates they choose) as a good method, much better than Plurality or 
TTR,
and the best of the methods that are invulnerable to Burial and meet 
Later-no-Harm.

Some of us see elections as primarily a contest and not a negotiation process.

I endorse IRV because it has a maximal set of  (what I consider to be) 
desirable
criterion compliances:

Majority for Solid Coalitions (aka Mutual Majority)
Woodall's Plurality criterion
Mutual Dominant Third
Condorcet Loser 

Burial Invulnerability
Later-no-Harm
Later-no-Help

Mono-add-Top
Mono-add-Plump  (implied by mono-add-top)
Mono-append
Irrelevant Ballots

Clone-Winner
Clone-Loser  (together these two add up to Clone Independence)

As far as I can tell, the only real points of dissatisfaction with IRV in 
Australia are
(a) that in some jurisdictions the voter is not allowed to truncate (on pain of 
his/her
vote  being binned as invalid) and (b) that it isn't multi-winner PR so that 
minor
parties can be fairly represented.

I gather the Irish are also reasonably satisfied with it for the election of 
their President.

snip
I've really come to like Bucklin, because it allows voters to 
exercise full power for one candidate at the outset, then add, *if 
they choose to do so*, alternative approved candidates.
snip

The version of Bucklin Abd advocates (using ratings ballots with voters able to 
give
as many candidates they like the same rating and also able to skip slots) tends
to be strategically equivalent to Approval  but entices voters to play silly 
strategy
games sitting out rounds.

It would be better if 3-slot ballots are used, in which case it is the same 
thing as
(one of the versions of) Majority Choice Approval (MCA).

IMO the best method that meets  Favourite Betrayal (and also the best 3-slot 
ballot method)
is Strong Minimal Defence, Top Ratings:

*Voters fill out 3-slot ratings ballots, default rating is bottom-most
(indicating least preferred and not approved).

Interpreting top and middle rating as approval, disqualify all candidates
with an approval score lower than their maximum approval-opposition 
(MAO) score.
(X's  MAO score is the approval score of the most approved candidate on
ballots that don't approve X).

Elect the undisqualified candidate with the highest top-ratings score.*

Unlike MCA/Bucklin this fails Later-no-Help (as well as LNHarm) so the voters 
have a less
strong incentive to truncate.

Unlike MCA/Bucklin this meets Irrelevant Ballots. In MCA candidate X could be 
declared the
winner in the first round, and then it is found that a small number of voters 
had been wrongly
excluded and these new voters choose to openly bullet-vote for nobody (perhaps 
themselves
as write-ins) and then their additional ballots raise the majority threshold 
and trigger a second 
round in which X loses.

I can't take seriously any method that fails Irrelevant Ballots.

Compliance with Favourite Betrayal is incompatible with Condorcet. If you are 
looking for a 
relatively simple Condorcet method, I recommend Smith//Approval (ranking):

*Voters rank from the top candidates they approve. Equal-ranking is allowed. 
Interpreting being ranked above at least one other candidate as approval, elect 
the most 
approved member of the Smith set (the smallest non-empty set  S of candidates 
that pairwise
beat all the outside-S candidates).*


Chris Benham


  
__
See what's on at the movies in your area.. Find out now: 
http://au.movies.yahoo.com/session-times/


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

2010-01-17 Thread Terry Bouricius
Kathy,

You still are miss-stating the Burlington situation. Nearly every 
political scientist would say that Wright and Kiss were the two strongest 
candidates. Most political observers would agree that the term the two 
strongest candidates does not include the third place plurality 
candidate, Montroll, who you wish to include. Under election rules used in 
any government election in the world, whether a plurality election or a 
traditional runoff election, Montroll would lose as the third place 
candidate. The fact that IRV introduced ranked ballots allows us to see 
that his broader second-choice appeal made him the Condorcet-winner, but 
it is at least debatable as to whether the term strongest is the 
appropriate term to be applied to a candidate who could be in last place 
in a plurality situation. Though your term the two strongest candidates 
CAN be re-interpreted to mean what you want it to mean, I don't think you 
can make that statement without a caveat to explain that you mean 
something different than what any layperson would assume you mean.

Terry



- Original Message - 
From: Kathy Dopp kathy.d...@gmail.com
To: Terry Bouricius ter...@burlingtontelecom.net
Cc: election-methods@lists.electorama.com
Sent: Sunday, January 17, 2010 2:10 PM
Subject: Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are 
fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws


On Sun, Jan 17, 2010 at 1:54 PM, Terry Bouricius
ter...@burlingtontelecom.net wrote:
 Kathy,

 You still have it wrong. You wrote To clarify, what I meant to say is
 that in Burlington, the IRV winner
 was the worst choice of a majority of voters *out of the three 
 candidates
 who were viable*.

Yes. Sorry. Of the two strongest candidates then.

You're right.  Thanks for the correction.

Kathy


 No, among the top three the IRV winner, Kiss, was not less preferred 
 than
 Wright. Both Kiss and Montroll were preferred by more voters over 
 Wright.
 Among the three candidates who were viable it was the first round
 plurality leader, Wright, who was the Condorcet-loser, not Kiss.

 The real world choice in Burlington today is between plurality and IRV.
 You have stated, that in this case you prefer Plurality, which allows 
 the
 Condorcet-loser to be declared the winner. I agree that there is a
 powerful intellectual case for a Condorcet solution, but that is not on
 the table (even though I helped Robert Bristow-Johnson try to get it 
 into
 the hopper for consideration.) Condorcet, so far, has not been able to 
 get
 any traction with folks in Burlington, or in any other jurisdiction in 
 the
 world.

 Condorcet advocates may want to focus their attention on Aspen, where 
 the
 risk is that ranked ballots may be abandoned, if IRV is repealed.
 Promoting Condorcet as an alternate direction to go there seems to be a
 natural for advocates.

 Terry Bouricius



 - Original Message -
 From: Kathy Dopp kathy.d...@gmail.com
 To: Terry Bouricius ter...@burlingtontelecom.net
 Cc: election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Sent: Sunday, January 17, 2010 1:38 PM
 Subject: Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are
 fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws


 On Sun, Jan 17, 2010 at 12:34 PM, Terry Bouricius
 ter...@burlingtontelecom.net wrote:
 Kathy,

 you wrotesnip
 ...unlike with IRV where a majority may think that the
 elected candidate is the worst choice, as happened in Burlington, VT
 mayoral election.

 To clarify, what I meant to say is that in Burlington, the IRV winner
 was the worst choice of a majority of voters *out of the three
 candidates who were viable*. There are many other voting methods that
 do not share that flaw with IRV/STV. In fact do any alternatives to
 plurality share that IRV/STV flaw?

 snip
 That is incorrect for Burlington, (the IRV winner was the second
 Condorcet-winner if the actual Condorcet-winner is removed, and favored
 above the other three candidates.) And it is a fundamental fact that 
 the
 IRV winner can never be a candidate that the majority think is the
 worst
 choice. IRV can never elect the Condorcet-loser. The ultimate winner
 must
 be preferred above the other finalist in the last round of the tally.

 It is PLURALITY voting, which you support, that often DOES elect the
 Condorcet-loser, who a majority agree is the worst choice.

 You are distorting the facts again Terry. If you want to know what I
 support, ask or read my posts. I clearly support plurality if the
 choice is between IRV/STV and plurality because IRV/STV are *much
 worse* than plurality in a variety of ways. However, given the choice
 between plurality and virtually any other alternative voting method
 I've heard proposed on this list, I support the alternatives.

 Please try to stop making personal attacks and distorting the facts
 about people, whenever the facts on the issues are not on your side.
 It's not pretty Terry.

 Kathy


 Terry Bouricius

 - Original Message -
 From: Kathy Dopp 

Re: [EM] Fw: Two simple alternative voting methods that are fairerthan IRV/STV and lack most IRV/STV flaws

2010-01-17 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 17, 2010, at 3:53 PM, Terry Bouricius wrote:


 Nearly every political scientist would say that
Wright and Kiss were the two strongest candidates.


before or after the election?

before the election, i'm not sure that was true.  they might have  
said that Kiss and Montroll were the two strongest candidates


*after* the election, the political scientists/observers are  
reverberating the official election results determined by rules which  
are presently under debate.



Most political observers would agree that the term the two
strongest candidates does not include the third place plurality
candidate,


only because the election rules in effect do not put the 3rd place  
candidate (according to the rules) in the top two.  if the election  
rules were changed, then what would the political scientists or  
observers say?



Under election rules used in any government election in the world,
whether a plurality election or a traditional runoff election,
Montroll would lose as the third place candidate.


and i've pointed that out a few times.  and Montroll would not have  
been in the runoff.  and, it's possible that with reduced turnout,  
that the biggest loser (from the Condorcet POV) would have won  
subsequently pissing off 66% of the town.



The fact that IRV introduced ranked ballots allows us to see
that his broader second-choice appeal made him the Condorcet- 
winner, but

it is at least debatable as to whether the term strongest is the
appropriate term to be applied to a candidate who could be in last  
place

in a plurality situation.


yes, it's debatable and, since there are 3 different methods all  
lifting up different declared winners, it's subjective.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info