[EM] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
Hi guys, I'm still here, still pondering, but now I have another question.
I've been thinking about score voting, approval voting, and plurality (FPTP)
voting, and I have a concern.

 

Say we have a situation where we have three candidates, say Gore, Nader, and
Bush. Say we have a voter, Abe whose greatest concern is that Bush NOT win.
His second priority is that Nader win over Gore - but this priority is a
distant second. He *really* doesn't want Bush to win. He would prefer Nader
over Gore, but he *hates* Bush.

 

Let's also say that Abe is intelligent, and he is committed to using his
vote to maximize his happiness - in other words, rather than vote sincerely
and cause his preferences harm, he will always vote strategically where it
is to his benefit to do so.

 

If Score Voting was in place, and he were to vote sincerely, Abe probably
would vote something like 'Gore:75, Nader: 100, Bush: 0'. However, he's no
fool, and he knows that while it is theoretically possibly that Nader
*might* win, Gore is his best chance to stopping Bush, and that withholding
score from Gore might (if all Nader supporters did it) result in Gore not
getting enough of a score, therefor Bush could win.

 

So strategically speaking, Abe reasons that although he supports a less
likely candidate more, he strategically should score the front-runner Gore
at full strength, so long as keeping Bush out is the greatest need - and so
long as Nader's win is unlikely.

 

So, as far as *I* can see, this converts Score Voting into Approval voting.
The only people who would bother to vote sincerely are:

1)  Those who truly prefer Gore highest and Bush lowest (or vice versa),
because there's no strategic downside.

2)  People who would rather feel more sincere about their vote than
feel good about the outcome of their vote.

3)  People who aren't intelligent to realize that by voting sincerely
they may be helping elect their least preferred candidate.

 

And say what you want about intelligence being a bar to entry, you can bet
that the smart people behind ALL candidates will make sure that everyone
gets the message, so we can largely ignore #3.  Most people I imagine would
be pragmatic enough to worry more about the end result and less about
sincere vs. strategic, so we ignore #2. And #1 people are going to vote the
same way anways, so they may as well use Approval voting.

 

OK, so let's throw out Score Voting and use Approval voting. Gore v Nader V
Bush.  Abe (who hates Bush but prefers Nader) gives an approval vote to
Nader, his top-most preference, but knowing that withholding approval from
Gore could elect Bush (and not wanting to play the spoiler) he also gives an
approval vote to Gore. Since Gore in this example is far and away receiving
much more support than Nader, Gore now beats Bush.

 

Let's call the party that put Nader on the ballot the Green party, and that
they continue to field candidates in further elections that use the Approval
voting system.  Abe notices the following pattern: when the Green party
fields a candidate that doesn't even have a glimmer of hope winning the
election (like the Gore/Nader/Bush one) that people that support the Green
party candidate also approve the Democrat candidate as a bulwark against the
Republican. And since in those elections the Green party never really had a
hope of winning, the Green approval vote is ultimately irrelevant - those
elections would have proceeded no differently than if the Green supporters
had simply voted Democrat.

 

But much worse yet, Abe notices that in *some* election, the Green party
actually gets a chunk of people thinking that Green could actually win. And
emboldened by their hopes, many Green supporters decide to go for it,
approve of the Green candidate, but *not* the Democrat one. Result: in
elections where more voters think more favorably towards Green's chances,
their least preferred choice (the Republican) tends to win more!

 

This are my two thoughts:

 

a)  Intelligent use of Score Voting becomes Approval Voting, and the
harm in unwise use of Score voting means that Approval Voting is superior to
(and simpler than) Score voting pragmatically.

b)  Approval Voting tends to result in irrelevant approval votes being
given to weak candidates - which is pointless, or slightly stronger (but
still losing) candidates can once again present a spoiler effect where a
person's least preferred choice is elected because they cast their approval
only toward their most preferred choice, who was nowhere near supported
enough to stop their least preferred choice.

 

Am I substantially wrong about any of this? Ultimately, in real and
practical terms, it seems that done intelligently, Score Voting devolves
into Approval Voting, and Approval Voting devolves into Plurality Voting.

 

How is this not so?

 

If it *is* so, then as much as I abhor Plurality Voting, I must now likewise
abhor Score and Approval Voting.  But that shoves me back at 

[EM] Question about the Plurality Criterion

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
As I have had it explained to me, the Plurality Criterion is: If there are
two candidates X and Y so that X has more first place votes than Y has any
place votes, then Y shouldn't win.

 

Which I think means that if X has, for example, 100 votes, then B would have
to appear on less than 100 ballots and still *win* for this criterion to be
failed, yes?

 

I cannot imagine a (halfway desirable) voting system that would fail the
Plurality Criterion - can anyone tell me the simplest one that would? Apart
from a lame one like least votes win, I mean?

 

-Benn Grant

eFix Computer Consulting

 mailto:b...@4efix.com b...@4efix.com

603.283.6601

 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] Why Random by itself doesn't cut it.

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
 (if all Nader supporters did it) result in Gore not
 getting enough of a score, therefor Bush could win.



 So strategically speaking, Abe reasons that although he supports a less
 likely candidate more, he strategically should score the front-runner Gore
 at full strength, so long as keeping Bush out is the greatest need - and so
 long as Nader's win is unlikely.



 So, as far as *I* can see, this converts Score Voting into Approval voting.
 The only people who would bother to vote sincerely are:

 1)  Those who truly prefer Gore highest and Bush lowest (or vice
 versa),
 because there's no strategic downside.

 2)  People who would rather feel more sincere about their vote than
 feel good about the outcome of their vote.

 3)  People who aren't intelligent to realize that by voting sincerely
 they may be helping elect their least preferred candidate.



 And say what you want about intelligence being a bar to entry, you can bet
 that the smart people behind ALL candidates will make sure that everyone
 gets the message, so we can largely ignore #3.  Most people I imagine would
 be pragmatic enough to worry more about the end result and less about
 sincere vs. strategic, so we ignore #2. And #1 people are going to vote the
 same way anways, so they may as well use Approval voting.



 OK, so let's throw out Score Voting and use Approval voting. Gore v Nader V
 Bush.  Abe (who hates Bush but prefers Nader) gives an approval vote to
 Nader, his top-most preference, but knowing that withholding approval from
 Gore could elect Bush (and not wanting to play the spoiler) he also gives
 an
 approval vote to Gore. Since Gore in this example is far and away receiving
 much more support than Nader, Gore now beats Bush.



 Let's call the party that put Nader on the ballot the Green party, and that
 they continue to field candidates in further elections that use the
 Approval
 voting system.  Abe notices the following pattern: when the Green party
 fields a candidate that doesn't even have a glimmer of hope winning the
 election (like the Gore/Nader/Bush one) that people that support the Green
 party candidate also approve the Democrat candidate as a bulwark against
 the
 Republican. And since in those elections the Green party never really had a
 hope of winning, the Green approval vote is ultimately irrelevant - those
 elections would have proceeded no differently than if the Green supporters
 had simply voted Democrat.



 But much worse yet, Abe notices that in *some* election, the Green party
 actually gets a chunk of people thinking that Green could actually win. And
 emboldened by their hopes, many Green supporters decide to go for it,
 approve of the Green candidate, but *not* the Democrat one. Result: in
 elections where more voters think more favorably towards Green's chances,
 their least preferred choice (the Republican) tends to win more!



 This are my two thoughts:



 a)  Intelligent use of Score Voting becomes Approval Voting, and the
 harm in unwise use of Score voting means that Approval Voting is superior
 to
 (and simpler than) Score voting pragmatically.

 b)  Approval Voting tends to result in irrelevant approval votes being
 given to weak candidates - which is pointless, or slightly stronger (but
 still losing) candidates can once again present a spoiler effect where a
 person's least preferred choice is elected because they cast their approval
 only toward their most preferred choice, who was nowhere near supported
 enough to stop their least preferred choice.



 Am I substantially wrong about any of this? Ultimately, in real and
 practical terms, it seems that done intelligently, Score Voting devolves
 into Approval Voting, and Approval Voting devolves into Plurality Voting.



 How is this not so?



 If it *is* so, then as much as I abhor Plurality Voting, I must now
 likewise
 abhor Score and Approval Voting.  But that shoves me back at the Bucklin,
 IRV, and other system that have one of my least favorite flaws - that
 ranking X higher than Y can cause Y to beat X. :(



 It's days like these that I feel that there *is* no way to elect people
 that
 is fair and right. :(



 -Benn Grant

 eFix Computer Consulting

  mailto:b...@4efix.com b...@4efix.com

 603.283.6601



 -- next part --
 An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
 URL: 
 http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/attachments/20130624/7644697a/attachment-0001.htm
 

 --

 Message: 3
 Date: Mon, 24 Jun 2013 10:10:36 -0400
 From: Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com
 To: 'EM' election-methods@lists.electorama.com,
 electionscie...@googlegroups.com
 Subject: [EM] Question about the Plurality Criterion
 Message-ID: 01af01ce70e4$9a68fff0$cf3affd0$@4efix.com
 Content-Type: text/plain; charset=us-ascii

 As I have had it explained to me, the Plurality Criterion is: If there are
 two candidates X and Y so that X has more first place votes

[EM] random eg w. improved version of IRV3.

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
I took Warren's example and ignored all of the voter information except the
top 3 choices, tallied up (with Excel) the number of votes each got so that
A, B and E were identified as the finalists.  I then sorted each of the
votes into one of ten categories based on preferences between the three
finalists and then summed up the number in each category.  Only two voters
didn't have one of the three finalists in their top three.  I added
together the three categories for each of the three finalists, where they
were the top preference among the finalists.  The totals were: A: 11, B:
14, E:10.  This eliminated E so that 3 votes were transferred from E to
each of the two candidates, which made B beat A, 17 to 14.   But let's say
E demanded a recount and instead we considered the outcome if we eliminated
A instead.  Then B would beat E, 20 to 12.

So B wins, almost with a majority, which isn't bad with 7 a-priori
competitive candidates, an assumption that is not realistic for real-world
important single-winner
elections.  And, 43% of the vote information was used, the lower rankings
were not important and so their non-usage is not important and would be
robustly not important if the number of competitive candidates tended to be
relatively low for a variety of real world economic(cost of campaigning,
building name recognition), psychological reasons(short-cuts used by
rationally ignorant voters with opportunity costs to the time spent on
politics).

dlw

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
To ignore the simple upgrade to IRV that I have proffered
and defended at length on this list-serve,
 when you argue against IRV?
dlw

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
I am not sure who is ignoring your upgrade, but I am curious - can you
remind me how your voting system works again?

 

-Benn Grant

eFix Computer Consulting

 mailto:b...@4efix.com b...@4efix.com

603.283.6601

 

From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com
[mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On Behalf Of David L
Wetzell
Sent: Monday, June 24, 2013 11:09 AM
To: EM
Subject: [EM] Is it professional?

 

To ignore the simple upgrade to IRV that I have proffered
and defended at length on this list-serve,

 when you argue against IRV?  


dlw


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
To: Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com


Most IRV in real world limits the rankings to 3 candidates per voter.
In my approach, I treat the rankings as approval votes in the first round
and tally up the number of times each candidate gets ranked to determine
3 finalists.There are 10 ways to rank 3 finalists so I sort the votes into
these 10 categories, tally them up and use the info to have an instant
runoff vote among the 3 finalists.

Ben, this is the approach that I said gave the same result for all of the
cases you brought up in your initial email to the list, which illustrated
why you thought IRV was flawed.
dlw

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #8922] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:08 AM, Stephen Unger un...@cs.columbia.eduwrote:

 Regarding the plurality criterion:

  The Plurality Criterion is: If there are two candidates X and Y so
  that X has more first place votes than Y has any place votes, then Y
  shouldn't win.

 It is NOT worthy of  respect.
  Consider the following 2-candidate SV election.

 #votes  C1  C2
 51   9   8
 49   0   9

 C1 should win according to the Plurality Criterion, but obviously C2
 is the people's choice. One of the advantages of SV is that it
 properly handles cases like this.

 Steve


OK, SV=Score Voting, right?  Score voting doesn't have places, does it, as
it is not a ranked based system? I agree with you that in the above
election C2 should win, of course - although some would not.

I dunno, maybe I don't under this, or maybe the Plurality is better defined
without referring to first place or any place.

I guess that's my next question: is the Plurality relevant to non ranked
systems? Is the Criterion used by experts (like you guys) to refer to C2
winning about as failing the Plurality Criterion? Or is it only about
things like Bucklin and IRV?

-Thanks.

-Benn Grant

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
So if I understand you:

You have a single election. You permit people to rank up to 3 candidates,
no more.  You eliminate form consideration all but the top 3 people who
were ranked, regardless of what rank they got. Then, with only those three
left, you proceed to process them with standard IRV to find the winner.

Is that a correct summation of you system, do I understand it right?


On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:19 AM, David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.comwrote:

 To: Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com


 Most IRV in real world limits the rankings to 3 candidates per voter.
 In my approach, I treat the rankings as approval votes in the first round
 and tally up the number of times each candidate gets ranked to determine
 3 finalists.There are 10 ways to rank 3 finalists so I sort the votes into
 these 10 categories, tally them up and use the info to have an instant
 runoff vote among the 3 finalists.

 Ben, this is the approach that I said gave the same result for all of the
 cases you brought up in your initial email to the list, which illustrated
 why you thought IRV was flawed.
 dlw



 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #8922] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:08 AM, Stephen Unger un...@cs.columbia.eduwrote:

 One point overlooked here is that any new party has to go thru an
 incubation period during which it has virtually no chance of
 winning. Voting for such a party helps strengthen it, and makes it
 more likely that others will support it next time around. At some
 point it may become a contender, and then it might actually start
 winning elections. If you cast votes (approve or give high scores to)
 only for parties that might win the current election, then we will be
 stuck forever with the existing 2-party scam.


It doesn't seem like you are saying I am wrong about that, you just seem
unhappy that I am right?

And under Score/Approval/Plurality voting systems, there would be three
phases a party might go through:

A) unpopular enough not to be a spoiler
B) popular enough to be a spoiler, but not popular enough to win
C) popular enough to win often (25% of the time, for example.)

On your way to C, you are going to have a LOT of B, and you may never make
it to C, especially if people get burned voting for the emerging party by
getting their least preferred candidate.

The only way to build a strong new party in reality, as far as I can see,
is to have a voting system that does not penalize you into getting your
least favored choice by voting for your most favored one.

Voters may have many different philosophies, and the voting system
 should accommodate as many as possible.


I don't know that I agree with either side of this.  Voters ultimately, by
and large and by definition, I think, want the best outcome possible.  If
Nader isn't a real possibility, then a non-conservation wants Gore FAR
ahead of Bush.  Most non-conservative are intelligent enough to see that
Gore and Bush are equally bad from their point of view.  And most would
rate the election of Bush far more a likely than the election of Nader, and
even if it was a coind toss among all three (Gore/Nader/Bush) most would
rightly view stopping Bush as more critical than helping Nader beat Gore.

 It is easily possible that, in the same SV election, voters A and B

 both score 3 candidates, C1, C2, C3,  as 9, 0, 0, respectively for
 different reasons. A might consider C2 and C3 both to be terrible,
 while B might consider C2 to be perhaps a 4 or 5, but chooses 0
 because of concern that C2 might defeat C1. A third voter with views
 similar to C2's might score the  candidates as 9, 5, 0. All are
 perfectly legitimate actions. Since we cannot distinguish between
 pairs such as A and B, it is not appropriate to try to alter the
 voting system so as to prevent voters from acting strategically. (I
 think it would be a good idea to urge voters to cast SV votes that
 accurately correspond to their appraisals, and candidates might do
 well to so advise their supporters.)


Again, is it *theoretically possible that Nader voters might prefer Bush
to Gore, but in the real world, progressive tend to see democrats as far
superior to republicans, and libertarians tend to see republicans as far
superior to democrats.  Ignoring that seems like a bad idea.

 Efforts to change the voting system to nullify or prevent strategic

 voting lead to systems that restrict the voter's options. E.g,
 median-based score voting, in effect, restricts the extent to which a
 voter can support a candidate.


First of all, is efforts to ... nullify or prevent strategic voting the
same meaning as efforts to make sincere voting produce similar choices to
strategic voting.?

Second of all, it seems to me that the less divergence there is between
strategic and sincere voting, the more beneficial qualities the voting
system has, such as:
-we can worry less about the spoiler effect, which promotes more than just
2 parties
-we can worry less that people are accidentally voting against their
interests
-we can have fewer debates about whether people have an obligation to vote
strategically or sincerely

This would seem to be a good thing.

But ultimately, I don't think you answered my central questions (and pardon
me if you did and I just don't see it):


   - Intelligent use of Score Voting becomes Approval Voting, and the harm
   in unwise use of Score voting means that Approval Voting is superior to
   (and simpler than) Score voting pragmatically.

   - Approval Voting tends to result in irrelevant approval votes being given
   to weak candidates – which is pointless, or slightly stronger (but still
   losing) candidates can once again present a spoiler effect where a person’s
   least preferred choice is elected because they cast their approval only
   toward their most preferred choice, who was nowhere near supported enough
   to stop their least preferred choice.


  Am I substantially wrong about any of this? Ultimately, in real
and practical
terms, it seems that done intelligently, Score Voting devolves into
Approval Voting, and Approval Voting devolves into Plurality Voting.

Thanks.


Re: [EM] [CES #8924] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
Most non-conservative are intelligent enough to see that Gore and Bush are
equally bad from their point of view.

 

was supposed to be

 

Most non-conservative are intelligent enough to see that Gore and Bush are
NOT equally bad from their point of view.

 

My typing sucks and always has.  You lucky bastards get to try to read what
I write. ;)

 

-Benn Grant

eFix Computer Consulting

 mailto:b...@4efix.com b...@4efix.com

603.283.6601

 

From: electionscie...@googlegroups.com
[mailto:electionscie...@googlegroups.com] On Behalf Of Benjamin Grant
Sent: Monday, June 24, 2013 11:40 AM
To: electionsciencefoundation
Cc: EM
Subject: Re: [CES #8924] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically
substantially different from Plurality?

 

On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:08 AM, Stephen Unger un...@cs.columbia.edu
mailto:un...@cs.columbia.edu  wrote:

One point overlooked here is that any new party has to go thru an
incubation period during which it has virtually no chance of
winning. Voting for such a party helps strengthen it, and makes it
more likely that others will support it next time around. At some
point it may become a contender, and then it might actually start
winning elections. If you cast votes (approve or give high scores to)
only for parties that might win the current election, then we will be
stuck forever with the existing 2-party scam.

 

It doesn't seem like you are saying I am wrong about that, you just seem
unhappy that I am right?

 

And under Score/Approval/Plurality voting systems, there would be three
phases a party might go through:

 

A) unpopular enough not to be a spoiler

B) popular enough to be a spoiler, but not popular enough to win

C) popular enough to win often (25% of the time, for example.)

 

On your way to C, you are going to have a LOT of B, and you may never make
it to C, especially if people get burned voting for the emerging party by
getting their least preferred candidate.

 

The only way to build a strong new party in reality, as far as I can see, is
to have a voting system that does not penalize you into getting your least
favored choice by voting for your most favored one.

 

Voters may have many different philosophies, and the voting system
should accommodate as many as possible. 

 

I don't know that I agree with either side of this.  Voters ultimately, by
and large and by definition, I think, want the best outcome possible.  If
Nader isn't a real possibility, then a non-conservation wants Gore FAR ahead
of Bush.  Most non-conservative are intelligent enough to see that Gore and
Bush are equally bad from their point of view.  And most would rate the
election of Bush far more a likely than the election of Nader, and even if
it was a coind toss among all three (Gore/Nader/Bush) most would rightly
view stopping Bush as more critical than helping Nader beat Gore.

 

 It is easily possible that, in the same SV election, voters A and B

both score 3 candidates, C1, C2, C3,  as 9, 0, 0, respectively for
different reasons. A might consider C2 and C3 both to be terrible,
while B might consider C2 to be perhaps a 4 or 5, but chooses 0
because of concern that C2 might defeat C1. A third voter with views
similar to C2's might score the  candidates as 9, 5, 0. All are
perfectly legitimate actions. Since we cannot distinguish between
pairs such as A and B, it is not appropriate to try to alter the
voting system so as to prevent voters from acting strategically. (I
think it would be a good idea to urge voters to cast SV votes that
accurately correspond to their appraisals, and candidates might do
well to so advise their supporters.)

 

Again, is it *theoretically possible that Nader voters might prefer Bush to
Gore, but in the real world, progressive tend to see democrats as far
superior to republicans, and libertarians tend to see republicans as far
superior to democrats.  Ignoring that seems like a bad idea.

 

 Efforts to change the voting system to nullify or prevent strategic

voting lead to systems that restrict the voter's options. E.g,
median-based score voting, in effect, restricts the extent to which a
voter can support a candidate.

 

First of all, is efforts to ... nullify or prevent strategic voting the
same meaning as efforts to make sincere voting produce similar choices to
strategic voting.?

 

Second of all, it seems to me that the less divergence there is between
strategic and sincere voting, the more beneficial qualities the voting
system has, such as:

-we can worry less about the spoiler effect, which promotes more than just 2
parties

-we can worry less that people are accidentally voting against their
interests

-we can have fewer debates about whether people have an obligation to vote
strategically or sincerely

 

This would seem to be a good thing.

 

But ultimately, I don't think you answered my central questions (and pardon
me if you did and I just don't see it):

 

* Intelligent use of Score Voting becomes Approval Voting, and 

Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread James Gilmour
 David L WetzellSent: Monday, June 24, 2013 4:19 PM

 Most IRV in real world limits the rankings to 3 candidates per voter.  

In real world?  Evidence please  -  on a WORLD basis..

I have never encountered such limits in any IRV election.  But then, I don't 
live in the USA.

Some 3-only limits are imposed because of the limitations of the out-of-date 
equipment used to tally paper ballots.

James Gilmour
Edinburgh, Scotland




---
avast! Antivirus: Outbound message clean.
Virus Database (VPS): 130624-1, 24/06/2013
Tested on: 24/06/2013 17:17:08
avast! - copyright (c) 1988-2013 AVAST Software.
http://www.avast.com




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
I limit the collection of ranking info to up to 3 rankings per voter, which
is useful for practical purposes, and then treat the up to 3 rankings per
voter as approval votes to determine which three of the umpteen candidates
proceed.  I then process those three with the standard IRV to find the
winner.

dlw

dlw


On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 10:24 AM, Benjamin Grant panjakr...@gmail.comwrote:

 So if I understand you:

 You have a single election. You permit people to rank up to 3 candidates,
 no more.  You eliminate form consideration all but the top 3 people who
 were ranked, regardless of what rank they got. Then, with only those three
 left, you proceed to process them with standard IRV to find the winner.

 Is that a correct summation of you system, do I understand it right?


 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:19 AM, David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.comwrote:

 To: Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com


 Most IRV in real world limits the rankings to 3 candidates per voter.
 In my approach, I treat the rankings as approval votes in the first round
 and tally up the number of times each candidate gets ranked to
 determine 3 finalists.There are 10 ways to rank 3 finalists so I sort the
 votes into these 10 categories, tally them up and use the info to have an
 instant runoff vote among the 3 finalists.

 Ben, this is the approach that I said gave the same result for all of the
 cases you brought up in your initial email to the list, which illustrated
 why you thought IRV was flawed.
 dlw



 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list
 info




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
Isn't that what I said?  If not, where did I get it wrong?

 

-Benn Grant

eFix Computer Consulting

 mailto:b...@4efix.com b...@4efix.com

603.283.6601

 

From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com
[mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On Behalf Of David L
Wetzell
Sent: Monday, June 24, 2013 12:20 PM
To: Benjamin Grant
Cc: EM
Subject: Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

 

I limit the collection of ranking info to up to 3 rankings per voter, which
is useful for practical purposes, and then treat the up to 3 rankings per
voter as approval votes to determine which three of the umpteen candidates
proceed.  I then process those three with the standard IRV to find the
winner.  

 

dlw




dlw

 

On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 10:24 AM, Benjamin Grant panjakr...@gmail.com
mailto:panjakr...@gmail.com  wrote:

So if I understand you:

 

You have a single election. You permit people to rank up to 3 candidates, no
more.  You eliminate form consideration all but the top 3 people who were
ranked, regardless of what rank they got. Then, with only those three left,
you proceed to process them with standard IRV to find the winner.

 

Is that a correct summation of you system, do I understand it right?

 

On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:19 AM, David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.com
mailto:wetze...@gmail.com  wrote:

To: Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com mailto:b...@4efix.com 

 

Most IRV in real world limits the rankings to 3 candidates per voter.  
In my approach, I treat the rankings as approval votes in the first round 

and tally up the number of times each candidate gets ranked to determine 3
finalists.There are 10 ways to rank 3 finalists so I sort the votes into
these 10 categories, tally them up and use the info to have an instant
runoff vote among the 3 finalists.


Ben, this is the approach that I said gave the same result for all of the
cases you brought up in your initial email to the list, which illustrated
why you thought IRV was flawed.

dlw




 

 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

 

 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] re James Gilmour

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
Jame Gilmour: In real world?  Evidence please  -  on a WORLD basis..

dlw: I mistyped, I know things are done differently in different places.
 In the US, it's common to have up to 3 rankings.  It's not a serious
limitation for most single-winner political elections.  Once again, it
depends on the number of competitive candidates and in the worse case, it
might lead to some strategic voting, but less so than o.w. wd be the case.

dlw

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #8922] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi,


(Benjamin wrote:)

On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:08 AM, Stephen Unger un...@cs.columbia.edu wrote:

Regarding the plurality criterion:

 The Plurality Criterion is: If there are two candidates X and Y so
 that X has more first place votes than Y has any place votes, then Y
 shouldn't win.

It is NOT worthy of  respect.
 Consider the following 2-candidate SV election.

#votes  C1  C2
51       9   8
49       0   9

C1 should win according to the Plurality Criterion, but obviously C2
is the people's choice. One of the advantages of SV is that it
properly handles cases like this.


Woodall (the inventor of the criterion) used a model in which all 
methods are rank methods (and optionally have the concept of truncation). If 
you want to use the criteria in other 
environments you just have to be consistent about how you extend it.

I would interpret 0 ratings as truncation and translate the above scenario to 
say:
51: C1C2
49: C2 (C1 has no votes)


So it is no violation of Plurality to elect C2, only a violation of Majority 
Favorite.

But you can change the scenario so that Plurality would be failed:

51: C1 rated 5, C2 unrated

49: C2 rated 10, C1 unrated


OK, SV=Score Voting, right?  Score voting doesn't have places, does it, as it 
is not a ranked based system? I agree with you that in the above election C2 
should win, of course - although some would not.

I dunno, maybe I don't under this, or maybe the Plurality is better defined 
without referring to first place or any place.

I guess that's my next question: is the Plurality relevant to non ranked 
systems? Is the Criterion used by experts (like you guys) to refer to C2 
winning about as failing the Plurality Criterion? Or is it only about things 
like Bucklin and IRV?


Kevin

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
Ben: You eliminate form consideration all but the top 3 people who were
ranked, regardless of what rank they got.

dlw: This was unclear about how the top 3 were chosen.

dlw


On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:27 AM, Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com wrote:

 Isn’t that what I said?  If not, where did I get it wrong?

 ** **

 -Benn Grant

 eFix Computer Consulting

 b...@4efix.com

 603.283.6601

 ** **

 *From:* election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com [mailto:
 election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] *On Behalf Of *David L
 Wetzell
 *Sent:* Monday, June 24, 2013 12:20 PM
 *To:* Benjamin Grant
 *Cc:* EM
 *Subject:* Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

 ** **

 I limit the collection of ranking info to up to 3 rankings per voter,
 which is useful for practical purposes, and then treat the up to 3 rankings
 per voter as approval votes to determine which three of the umpteen
 candidates proceed.  I then process those three with the standard IRV to
 find the winner.  

 ** **

 dlw


 

 dlw

 ** **

 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 10:24 AM, Benjamin Grant panjakr...@gmail.com
 wrote:

 So if I understand you:

 ** **

 You have a single election. You permit people to rank up to 3 candidates,
 no more.  You eliminate form consideration all but the top 3 people who
 were ranked, regardless of what rank they got. Then, with only those three
 left, you proceed to process them with standard IRV to find the winner.***
 *

 ** **

 Is that a correct summation of you system, do I understand it right?

 ** **

 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:19 AM, David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.com
 wrote:

 To: Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com

 ** **

 Most IRV in real world limits the rankings to 3 candidates per voter.
 In my approach, I treat the rankings as approval votes in the first round
 

 and tally up the number of times each candidate gets ranked to determine
 3 finalists.There are 10 ways to rank 3 finalists so I sort the votes into
 these 10 categories, tally them up and use the info to have an instant
 runoff vote among the 3 finalists.


 Ben, this is the approach that I said gave the same result for all of the
 cases you brought up in your initial email to the list, which illustrated
 why you thought IRV was flawed.

 dlw


 

 ** **

 ** **

 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info
 

 ** **

 ** **


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
Let me try again, because I want to make sure I get what you are trying to
communicate.

1) People vote from the pool of all candidate, for their top 3, ranked.
 For example, Candidate 1: 1st place, Candidate 2, 3rd place, C3, no place,
C4, no place, C5, 2nd place, and the rest of the cnadidates, no place.

2) Each candidate who got ANY rank place (of the three) gets a +1 point
per ballot they got ranked on. We know throw out all but the candidates
with the top three point scores.

3) Now, we use the ballots to conduct an IRV style algorithm with the three
remaining candidates and determine the winner.

If I *now* got that right, it seems to me that if there are, for example,
ten candidates, and if I choose three and NONE of the three I chose make it
to the final three, then my ballot is irrelevant in choosing which of the
final 3 I preferred.  Therefor there would be a STRONG strategic reason to
make SURE that at least one of the three I rank would be favored to make it
to the final IRV round - which diverges from the possible sincere vote.

-Benn Grant.


On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 12:31 PM, David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.comwrote:

 Ben: You eliminate form consideration all but the top 3 people who were
 ranked, regardless of what rank they got.

 dlw: This was unclear about how the top 3 were chosen.

 dlw


 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:27 AM, Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com wrote:

 Isn’t that what I said?  If not, where did I get it wrong?

 ** **

 -Benn Grant

 eFix Computer Consulting

 b...@4efix.com

 603.283.6601

 ** **

 *From:* election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com [mailto:
 election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] *On Behalf Of *David L
 Wetzell
 *Sent:* Monday, June 24, 2013 12:20 PM
 *To:* Benjamin Grant
 *Cc:* EM
 *Subject:* Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

 ** **

 I limit the collection of ranking info to up to 3 rankings per voter,
 which is useful for practical purposes, and then treat the up to 3 rankings
 per voter as approval votes to determine which three of the umpteen
 candidates proceed.  I then process those three with the standard IRV to
 find the winner.  

 ** **

 dlw


 

 dlw

 ** **

 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 10:24 AM, Benjamin Grant panjakr...@gmail.com
 wrote:

 So if I understand you:

 ** **

 You have a single election. You permit people to rank up to 3 candidates,
 no more.  You eliminate form consideration all but the top 3 people who
 were ranked, regardless of what rank they got. Then, with only those three
 left, you proceed to process them with standard IRV to find the winner.**
 **

 ** **

 Is that a correct summation of you system, do I understand it right?

 ** **

 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:19 AM, David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.com
 wrote:

 To: Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com

 ** **

 Most IRV in real world limits the rankings to 3 candidates per voter.
 In my approach, I treat the rankings as approval votes in the first round
 

 and tally up the number of times each candidate gets ranked to
 determine 3 finalists.There are 10 ways to rank 3 finalists so I sort the
 votes into these 10 categories, tally them up and use the info to have an
 instant runoff vote among the 3 finalists.


 Ben, this is the approach that I said gave the same result for all of the
 cases you brought up in your initial email to the list, which illustrated
 why you thought IRV was flawed.

 dlw


 

 ** **

 ** **

 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list
 info

 ** **

 ** **




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #8922] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 12:28 PM, Kevin Venzke step...@yahoo.fr wrote:

 But you can change the scenario so that Plurality would be failed:

 51: C1 rated 5, C2 unrated

 49: C2 rated 10, C1 unrated

 Kevin


A little confused again.  What voting system are we using above? Lost track
of that.

-Benn Grant

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #8922] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Kevin Venzke


Hi Benn,


 De : Benjamin Grant panjakr...@gmail.com
À : Kevin Venzke step...@yahoo.fr 
Cc : em election-meth...@electorama.com 
Envoyé le : Lundi 24 juin 2013 11h45
Objet : Re: [EM] [CES #8922] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically 
substantially different from Plurality?
 

On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 12:28 PM, Kevin Venzke step...@yahoo.fr wrote:

But you can change the scenario so that Plurality would be failed:

51: C1 rated 5, C2 unrated

49: C2 rated 10, C1 unrated

Kevin


A little confused again.  What voting system are we using above? Lost track of 
that.


My assumption was that we were talking about Range, with blank ratings counting 
as zero.

Kevin


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
Hi Ben, 1)  they get to vote or rank up to 3 candidates.  If someone only
wants one candidate to win they need not rank others or if they only had
time to learn about two or three and only really liked one or two of those
candidates then they could rank one or two of them.

2 and 3 are right.

Yes, if your top 3 were not among the top 3 for everyone then your vote
would count in the first stage, not the final stage.  And yes that could
lead to some strategic voting, but there'd be less of such.   And this
would not be a common phenomenon if the top 3 are genuinely more
competitive candidates.  In Warren's example, only 2/37 votes didn't have
one of the top 3 candidates among their top three candidates.  That's
basically 5.4% and that was with a system where all seven candidates had a
priori equal chances of being the final winner, not a realistic assumption.
dlw

dlw


On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:42 AM, Benjamin Grant panjakr...@gmail.comwrote:

 Let me try again, because I want to make sure I get what you are trying to
 communicate.

 1) People vote from the pool of all candidate, for their top 3, ranked.
  For example, Candidate 1: 1st place, Candidate 2, 3rd place, C3, no place,
 C4, no place, C5, 2nd place, and the rest of the cnadidates, no place.

 2) Each candidate who got ANY rank place (of the three) gets a +1 point
 per ballot they got ranked on. We know throw out all but the candidates
 with the top three point scores.

 3) Now, we use the ballots to conduct an IRV style algorithm with the
 three remaining candidates and determine the winner.

 If I *now* got that right, it seems to me that if there are, for example,
 ten candidates, and if I choose three and NONE of the three I chose make it
 to the final three, then my ballot is irrelevant in choosing which of the
 final 3 I preferred.  Therefor there would be a STRONG strategic reason to
 make SURE that at least one of the three I rank would be favored to make it
 to the final IRV round - which diverges from the possible sincere vote.

 -Benn Grant.


 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 12:31 PM, David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.comwrote:

 Ben: You eliminate form consideration all but the top 3 people who were
 ranked, regardless of what rank they got.

 dlw: This was unclear about how the top 3 were chosen.

 dlw


 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:27 AM, Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com wrote:

 Isn’t that what I said?  If not, where did I get it wrong?

 ** **

 -Benn Grant

 eFix Computer Consulting

 b...@4efix.com

 603.283.6601

 ** **

 *From:* election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com [mailto:
 election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] *On Behalf Of *David L
 Wetzell
 *Sent:* Monday, June 24, 2013 12:20 PM
 *To:* Benjamin Grant
 *Cc:* EM
 *Subject:* Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

 ** **

 I limit the collection of ranking info to up to 3 rankings per voter,
 which is useful for practical purposes, and then treat the up to 3 rankings
 per voter as approval votes to determine which three of the umpteen
 candidates proceed.  I then process those three with the standard IRV to
 find the winner.  

 ** **

 dlw


 

 dlw

 ** **

 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 10:24 AM, Benjamin Grant panjakr...@gmail.com
 wrote:

 So if I understand you:

 ** **

 You have a single election. You permit people to rank up to 3
 candidates, no more.  You eliminate form consideration all but the top 3
 people who were ranked, regardless of what rank they got. Then, with only
 those three left, you proceed to process them with standard IRV to find the
 winner.

 ** **

 Is that a correct summation of you system, do I understand it right?

 ** **

 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:19 AM, David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.com
 wrote:

 To: Benjamin Grant b...@4efix.com

 ** **

 Most IRV in real world limits the rankings to 3 candidates per voter.
 In my approach, I treat the rankings as approval votes in the first
 round 

 and tally up the number of times each candidate gets ranked to
 determine 3 finalists.There are 10 ways to rank 3 finalists so I sort the
 votes into these 10 categories, tally them up and use the info to have an
 instant runoff vote among the 3 finalists.


 Ben, this is the approach that I said gave the same result for all of
 the cases you brought up in your initial email to the list, which
 illustrated why you thought IRV was flawed.

 dlw


 

 ** **

 ** **

 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list
 info

 ** **

 ** **





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #8922] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 12:50 PM, Kevin Venzke step...@yahoo.fr wrote:


 But you can change the scenario so that Plurality would be failed:
 
 51: C1 rated 5, C2 unrated
 
 49: C2 rated 10, C1 unrated
 
 Kevin
 
 
 A little confused again.  What voting system are we using above? Lost
 track of that.


 My assumption was that we were talking about Range, with blank ratings
 counting as zero.

 Kevin


If we are talking about Range and counting blank rating as zero, then this:

51: C1 rated 5, C2 unrated
49: C2 rated 10, C1 unrated

is really no different than this:

51: C1 rated 5, C2 rated 0
49: C2 rated 10, C1 rated 0

And I think, since plurality says If there are two candidates X and Y
so that X has more first place votes than Y has any place votes, then
Y shouldn't win, then X and Y have the same number of any place votes,
i.e., Range voting can NEVER fail plurality. Again, I can't imagine a
decent system that would.

Now if there was some functional difference between a 0 rating and no
rating at all, we could examine that, I think.  For example, I have hear
some people talking about averages, what if a lack of rating *was*
functionally different from a 0 rating?  What if the score each candidate
gets isn't the *sum* of all their ratings (with unratings = 0) but the
average of all their ratings, with a non-rating not counting against them?

Let me work this through here. According to the sum approach, C1 gets 5 *
51 = 255 and C2 gets 10 * 49 = 490, C2 wins.

If we are looking for the average, then C! obviously has an average of 5
among the 51 people who gave him a rating, while C2 obviously has an
average of 10. C2 wins.

It's interesting to note that whether or not you use sum or average both of
the first example above turn out the same way.

In any case, with a Range/Score system that permits people to have a
functionally different from zero no rating option, I still have an issue
concluding the the Plurality criterion was failed.  Did C1 have more first
place votes than C2? I don't think so. Therefor Plurality is not violated,
is it? Because in order for Plurality to be violated, the one candidate
would have to get more first place votes that another has ANY place votes,
and still lose. As far as I can see here, C2 had more first place votes
that C1.  Is there a way to get C1 to win while C2 has more first place
votes than C1 has ANY place votes? I cannot imagine that in this
circumstance.

Can you?

What am I missing?  Or have I screwed up somewhere?

-Benn

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Kathy Dopp
Please forward to the appropriate list for me.  Thank you.

From: electionscie...@googlegroups.com

 [mailto:electionscie...@googlegroups.com] On Behalf Of Benjamin Grant
 Sent: Monday, June 24, 2013 11:40 AM
 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:08 AM, Stephen Unger un...@cs.columbia.edu
 mailto:un...@cs.columbia.edu  wrote:

   If you cast votes (approve or give high scores to)
 only for parties that might win the current election, then we will be
 stuck forever with the existing 2-party scam.


Yes. But the point of approval or score voting is voters do not have to do
that in order to keep their least favorite from winning.



 And under Score/Approval/Plurality voting systems, there would be three
 phases a party might go through:


 A) unpopular enough not to be a spoiler

 B) popular enough to be a spoiler, but not popular enough to win

 C) popular enough to win often (25% of the time, for example.)


Those options apply to plurality and IRV, not to approval or score voting
where a voter's 2nd choice vote cannot cause his least favorite to win.



 On your way to C, you are going to have a LOT of B, and you may never make
 it to C, especially if people get burned voting for the emerging party by
 getting their least preferred candidate.

 Speaking re. plurality or IRV still.


 The only way to build a strong new party in reality, as far as I can see,
 is
 to have a voting system that does not penalize you into getting your least
 favored choice by voting for your most favored one.


Yes.  Agreed.




 Second of all, it seems to me that the less divergence there is between
 strategic and sincere voting, the more beneficial qualities the voting
 system has, such as:

 -we can worry less about the spoiler effect, which promotes more than just
 2
 parties

 -we can worry less that people are accidentally voting against their
 interests

 -we can have fewer debates about whether people have an obligation to vote
 strategically or sincerely



 This would seem to be a good thing.


Ideally, but practically we may have to continue to vote for all candidates
other than our least favorates.


 * Intelligent use of Score Voting becomes Approval Voting, and the
 harm in unwise use of Score voting means that Approval Voting is superior
 to
 (and simpler than) Score voting pragmatically.


I agree.



 * Approval Voting tends to result in irrelevant approval votes
 being
 given to weak candidates - which is pointless, or slightly stronger (but
 still losing) candidates can once again present a spoiler effect where a
 person's least preferred choice is elected because they cast their approval
 only toward their most preferred choice, who was nowhere near supported
 enough to stop their least preferred choice.


First, why should anyone care if some votes turn out to be irrelevant
according to your definition?  Second, if someone uses approval voting like
plurality  byvoting for their true favorite without  also voting for their
most likely favorite candidate to win, then they are accepting that they
might spoil the chances of their other favorite(s).  Neither of these
arguments is a logically coherent reason for favoring plurality over
approval voting.



   Am I substantially wrong about any of this? Ultimately, in real and
 practical terms, it seems that done intelligently, Score Voting devolves
 into Approval Voting, and Approval Voting devolves into Plurality Voting.


There is no logically coherent reason for approval voting to devolve into
plurality IMO.

Kathy

Fundamentals of Verifiable Elections
http://kathydopp.com/wordpress/?p=174

View some of my research on my SSRN Author page:
http://ssrn.com/author=1451051

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] Question about the Plurality Criterion

2013-06-24 Thread Chris Benham
Ben,
 
MinMax(Margins) fails the Plurality criterion. It elects the candidate with the 
weakest pairwise loss as measured by the  difference between the two 
candidates' vote tallies.

An alternative definition is that it elects the candidate who needs the fewest 
number of extra bullet-votes to be able to pairwise-beat all the other 
candidates.
 
3:A
5:BA
6:C

CB 6-5,  BA 5-3,  AC 8-6.
 
That method elects B, but the Plurality criterion says that B can't win because 
of C. 

Given that if the B voters had truncated the winner would have been C, this is 
also a failure of the Later-no-Help criterion.
 
The method meets the Condorcet criterion and Mono-add-Top. It has been promoted 
here by Juho Laatu.
 
Chris Benham

 
 
 
Ben grant wrote (24 June 2013):
 
As I have had it explained to me, the Plurality Criterion is: If there are two 
candidates X and Y so that X has more first place votes than Y has any place 
votes, then Y shouldn't win.

Which I think means that if X has, for example, 100 votes, then B would have to 
appear on less than 100 ballots and still *win* for this criterion to be 
failed, yes?

I cannot imagine a (halfway desirable) voting system that would fail the 
Plurality Criterion - can anyone tell me the simplest one that would? Apart 
from a lame one like least votes win, I mean?
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #8922] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi Benn,



 De : Benjamin Grant panjakr...@gmail.com
À : Kevin Venzke step...@yahoo.fr 
Cc : em election-meth...@electorama.com 
Envoyé le : Lundi 24 juin 2013 12h11
Objet : Re: [EM] [CES #8922] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically 
substantially different from Plurality?

On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 12:50 PM, Kevin Venzke step...@yahoo.fr wrote:


But you can change the scenario so that Plurality would be failed:

51: C1 rated 5, C2 unrated
49: C2 rated 10, C1 unrated

Kevin


A little confused again.  What voting system are we using above? Lost track 
of that.


My assumption was that we were talking about Range, with blank ratings 
counting as zero.

Kevin



If we are talking about Range and counting blank rating as zero, then this:


51: C1 rated 5, C2 unrated
49: C2 rated 10, C1 unrated

is really no different than this:


51: C1 rated 5, C2 rated 0
49: C2 rated 10, C1 rated 0

And I think, since plurality says If there are
two candidates X and Y so that X has more first place votes than Y has any 
place 

votes, then Y shouldn't win, then X and Y have the same number of any place 
votes, 

i.e., Range voting can NEVER fail plurality. Again, I can't imagine a decent 
system 

that would.

Woodall's framework involves a concept of voters explicitly acknowledging 
candidates on their ballots, and Plurality is based on this. It doesn't really 
matter whether being unrated or being rated 0 are treated the same by the 
method. Personally I think a 0 rating is about the same as not being 
acknowledged as having any value, but if instead we say that an explicit 0 
rating counts as the acknowledgment, then Plurality failures can be avoided as 
long as the voters put 0s instead of leaving candidates unranked.

Now if there was some functional difference between a 0 rating and no rating 
at all, 

we could examine that, I think.

The functional difference for Plurality relates to the input, not the result. 
Consider why this criterion should be of any interest in the first place. You 
seem to agree that it is not good to fail it.

In any case, with a Range/Score system that permits people to have a 
functionally 

different from zero no rating option, I still have an issue concluding the 
the 

Plurality criterion was failed.  Did C1 have more first place votes than C2? 
I 

don't think so.
...

What am I missing?  Or have I screwed up somewhere?


What first place votes means in the rank context is strictly ranked above 
all of the other candidates. Plurality is originally defined for rank methods. 
If you want to apply criteria for rank methods to some other kind of method, 
you have to explain how you can interpret the latter as a rank method. For 
ratings ballots I think it's easiest to say that you just extract the relative 
rankings from the ratings.

Kevin


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 1:28 PM, Kathy Dopp kathy.d...@gmail.com wrote:

 Please forward to the appropriate list for me.  Thank you.

 From: electionscie...@googlegroups.com

 [mailto:electionscie...@googlegroups.com] On Behalf Of Benjamin Grant
 Sent: Monday, June 24, 2013 11:40 AM
 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 11:08 AM, Stephen Unger un...@cs.columbia.edu
 mailto:un...@cs.columbia.edu  wrote:

   If you cast votes (approve or give high scores to)
 only for parties that might win the current election, then we will be
 stuck forever with the existing 2-party scam.


 Yes. But the point of approval or score voting is voters do not have to do
 that in order to keep their least favorite from winning.


I understand that is it's goal, but I seem to have pointed out that it
still does that.  Aparently, not well, though.


  And under Score/Approval/Plurality voting systems, there would be three

 phases a party might go through:


 A) unpopular enough not to be a spoiler

 B) popular enough to be a spoiler, but not popular enough to win

 C) popular enough to win often (25% of the time, for example.)


 Those options apply to plurality and IRV, not to approval or score voting
 where a voter's 2nd choice vote cannot cause his least favorite to win.


Except when it does? I know that the party line is that Approval and Score
Voting cannot cause your least favorite to winner, but that's untrue if
Nader being Abe's (our voter's) preference over Gore causes him to give
less than 100 to Gore - that *can* cause Bush to win.  The only way to be
sure that he has done everything to prevent Bush from winning (if that is
his highest priority in a Nader/Gore/Bush election) is to make sure to
score the person most likely to beat Bush as high as possible.  Therefore
he *must* strategically score Gore a 100, Therefore Score/Range voting
devolves into Approval voting.

So let's examine Approval voting, since that is what we are left with.  If
we do an Approval voting system with Gore/Nader/Bush, assuming that Abe's
first priority is to stop Bush and his next priority (a distant second,
considering how opposed he is to Bush) is to support Nader over Gore.

Well, now he cannot do that. He can support Nader *and* Gore, be he cannot
support Nader *over* Gore without risking a greater chance of a Bush
victory. And in our example (as in real life) Gore has much more support
than Nader.

This means that If he Approval votes for BOTH of them, it is unlikely that
his vote for Nader will accomplish anything.
If he votes for ONLY Nader, he has a better chance for Nader to beat Gore,
but a much worse chance for stopping a Bush victory.

And, this is the poison pill: Let's say that election after election people
see that more and more people are voting for Nader,although he is not
winning.  Thinking optimistically (as some people like to) that this might
be the year that Nader could take it all, they put all their money on Nader
- they vote Nader, but *not* Gore. The result? Gore's numbers drop, Nader's
numbers rise a little, but Bush still get's the most!

This seems almost worse than plurality, in a way, because at least with
plurality we all knew and admitted that we need to vote against the spoiler
effect, but Approval voting may actually suffer from it just as much while
not as obviously - meaning people may vote against there interests more by
not seeing that.

Make sense?


 On your way to C, you are going to have a LOT of B, and you may never make
 it to C, especially if people get burned voting for the emerging party by
 getting their least preferred candidate.

 Speaking re. plurality or IRV still.


Huh?



 The only way to build a strong new party in reality, as far as I can see,
 is
 to have a voting system that does not penalize you into getting your least
 favored choice by voting for your most favored one.


 Yes.  Agreed.


Good.


 Second of all, it seems to me that the less divergence there is between
 strategic and sincere voting, the more beneficial qualities the voting
 system has, such as:

 -we can worry less about the spoiler effect, which promotes more than
 just 2
 parties

 -we can worry less that people are accidentally voting against their
 interests

 -we can have fewer debates about whether people have an obligation to vote
 strategically or sincerely

 This would seem to be a good thing.


 Ideally, but practically we may have to continue to vote for all
 candidates other than our least favorates.


Again, huh? we may have to continue to vote for all candidates other than
our least favorates? When we we NOT vote for candidates other than our
least favorites? You seem to be suggesting that I want voters to vote for
their least favorite candidates?



 * Intelligent use of Score Voting becomes Approval Voting, and the
 harm in unwise use of Score voting means that Approval Voting is superior
 to
 (and simpler than) Score voting pragmatically.


 I agree.


OK, so at least we agree that Score Voting is 

Re: [EM] Question about the Plurality Criterion

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
Thanks for the note - squirreling this away for future study. :)

-Benn


On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 1:38 PM, Chris Benham cbenha...@yahoo.com.auwrote:

 Ben,

 MinMax(Margins) fails the Plurality criterion. It elects the candidate
 with the weakest pairwise loss as measured by the  difference between the
 two candidates' vote tallies.

 An alternative definition is that it elects the candidate who needs the
 fewest number of extra bullet-votes to be able to pairwise-beat all the
 other candidates.

 3:A
 5:BA
 6:C
 CB 6-5,  BA 5-3,  AC 8-6.

 That method elects B, but the Plurality criterion says that B can't win
 because of C.
 Given that if the B voters had truncated the winner would have been C,
 this is also a failure of the Later-no-Help criterion.

 The method meets the Condorcet criterion and Mono-add-Top. It has been
 promoted here by Juho Laatu.

 Chris Benham




 Ben grant wrote (24 June 2013):

 As I have had it explained to me, the Plurality Criterion is: If there
 are two candidates X and Y so that X has more first place votes than Y has
 any place votes, then Y shouldn't win.

 Which I think means that if X has, for example, 100 votes, then B would
 have to appear on less than 100 ballots and still *win* for this criterion
 to be failed, yes?

 I cannot imagine a (halfway desirable) voting system that would fail the
 Plurality Criterion - can anyone tell me the simplest one that would? Apart
 from a lame one like least votes win, I mean?




 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Chris Benham
Ben Grant wrote:
 
 - Approval Voting tends to result in irrelevant approval votes being given to 
weak candidates – which is pointless, or slightly stronger (but still losing) 
candidates can once again present a spoiler effect where a person’s
least preferred choice is elected because they cast their approval only toward 
their most preferred choice, who was nowhere near supported enough to stop 
their least preferred choice.

Am I substantially wrong about any of this? Ultimately, in real and practical 
terms, it seems that done intelligently, Score Voting devolves into Approval 
Voting, and Approval Voting devolves into Plurality Voting.
 
The idea is that some voters dislike feeling strategically pressured to vote 
their sincere favourites below equal-top. With voters never needing to vote 
their sincere favourites below equal-top, previous elections become a much 
better indicator of which candidates are really weak.
 
So I don't see compliance with the Favorite Betrayal Criterion as pointless.
 
Chris Benham
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Kathy Dopp
Bejamin,

I think we fundamentally agree about most things except for one statement
you made (I think you're seeing some disagreement where there is none),
which is why I'll only respond to this.

You said Since this isn't fixed, tell me what the benefit of Approval is
in the real world over Plurality?  I want to be CLEAR about this, so please
let me: I am not asking how the what supporters of Approval voting promise
will happen, nor what Approval voting's creators intentions are - I am ONLY
asking about pragmatic and real-world RESULTS.

Me:   E.g. If people see that the number of votes for Nader are virtually
equal to those for Gore, and investigation (undistorted polling) shows that
9 out of ten of those voters preferred Nader first, and the least favorite
candidate was more than 10% behind,  then in the next election
mathematically, only 5% of those voters have to switch to Nader for Nader
to win and still beat the least favorite.

I.e. People are influenced by perceived public opinion and as well since
your scenario was counterfactual, it may be less likely than  cases that
are possible where approval voting ends up making it possible for small
parties to grow large and beat currently large parties.

You have no basis for claiming your counterfactual is more likely to occur
than any other and yet you want to cut off clear opportunity for building
support for smaller parties based on it?  People, or at least some people
may be able to figure out how and when to use approval voting to boost
currently smaller parties.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 3:06 PM, Kathy Dopp kathy.d...@gmail.com wrote:

 Bejamin,

 I think we fundamentally agree about most things except for one statement
 you made (I think you're seeing some disagreement where there is none),
 which is why I'll only respond to this.

 You said Since this isn't fixed, tell me what the benefit of Approval is
 in the real world over Plurality?  I want to be CLEAR about this, so please
 let me: I am not asking how the what supporters of Approval voting promise
 will happen, nor what Approval voting's creators intentions are - I am ONLY
 asking about pragmatic and real-world RESULTS.

 Me:   E.g. If people see that the number of votes for Nader are virtually
 equal to those for Gore, and investigation (undistorted polling) shows that
 9 out of ten of those voters preferred Nader first, and the least favorite
 candidate was more than 10% behind,  then in the next election
 mathematically, only 5% of those voters have to switch to Nader for Nader
 to win and still beat the least favorite.


Yes, that is the best case scenario, and what we all hope would happen.
 What if the scenario I described happened instead?  It's actually
virtually guaranteed on the *way* to gettting to the scenario you painted.


 I.e. People are influenced by perceived public opinion and as well since
 your scenario was counterfactual, it may be less likely than  cases that
 are possible where approval voting ends up making it possible for small
 parties to grow large and beat currently large parties.

 You have no basis for claiming your counterfactual is more likely to occur
 than any other and yet you want to cut off clear opportunity for building
 support for smaller parties based on it?  People, or at least some people
 may be able to figure out how and when to use approval voting to boost
 currently smaller parties.


I have yet to see any demonstration of any counterfactuality, so at this
point I am not granting that claim. Unless I just plain don't understand
what you mean when you say counterfactual - which is quite possible.

In any case, among the things I seek in a voting system is a system where
one doesn't have to choose between stopping your least preferred candidate
and supporting your most preferred one. And so far as I can see, that will
happen realistically in Approval voting when a minority group gets too
optimistic.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] Warren needs to double check his work.

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
There should be a few more fewer ranks in the red in his example.
http://rangevoting.org/IrvIgnoreExample.html

Also, I don't think voters care that much if their deeper preferences
aren't consulted when their top prefs get elected or come in 2nd place and
so it seems contrived to make a big deal out of it.  This does get at why
little is lost when only 3 rankings are allowed with IRV, which then makes
it easier to use those rankings as approval votes for a first round that
reduces the number of candidates much more quickly.
dlw

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

On 06/24/2013 05:08 PM, David L Wetzell wrote:

To ignore the simple upgrade to IRV that I have proffered
and defended at length on this list-serve,
  when you argue against IRV?


Yes, for many reasons. Among them: because other simple upgrades give 
way greater bang for the buck.


Consider BTR-IRV: It's like IRV, except when eliminating, you don't 
remove the Plurality loser. Instead, you eliminate, of the two with 
worst Plurality results for that round, whoever is ranked below the 
other on the most ballots.


That's two sentences, and boom, Condorcet compliance (and thus 
resistance against Burlington scenarios).


I can hear the counter: But it's not IRV! It doesn't have momentum! 
But whatever force that counter has against BTR-IRV, it also has against 
your unproven hybrid.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Warren needs to double check his work.

2013-06-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

On 06/24/2013 09:33 PM, David L Wetzell wrote:

There should be a few more fewer ranks in the red in his example.
http://rangevoting.org/IrvIgnoreExample.html

Also, I don't think voters care that much if their deeper preferences
aren't consulted when their top prefs get elected or come in 2nd place
and so it seems contrived to make a big deal out of it.  This does get
at why little is lost when only 3 rankings are allowed with IRV, which
then makes it easier to use those rankings as approval votes for a first
round that reduces the number of candidates much more quickly.


One man might say: This does get at why little is lost when only 3 
rankings are allowed with IRV.
The other man might say: This does get at why full IRV is not much 
better than 3-candidate IRV.




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Question about the Plurality Criterion

2013-06-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

On 06/24/2013 04:10 PM, Benjamin Grant wrote:

As I have had it explained to me, the Plurality Criterion is: If there
are two candidates X and Y so that X has more first place votes than Y
has any place votes, then Y shouldn't win.

Which I think means that if X has, for example, 100 votes, then B would
have to appear on less than 100 ballots and still **win** for this
criterion to be failed, yes?

I cannot imagine a (halfway desirable) voting system that would fail the
Plurality Criterion – can anyone tell me the simplest one that would?
Apart from a lame one like “least votes win”, I mean?


That depends on what you put into a candidate not being ranked on the 
ballot. If you think that voters mean that all the candidates they rank 
are better than those they don't rank, then Plurality obviously makes 
sense. On the other hand, if not ranking a candidate simply means the 
voter has no opinion, then the Plurality criterion is no longer as obvious.


A very simple system that fails the Plurality criterion for this reason 
is mean (average) Range. In this system, you take the mean rating of 
each candidate, and greatest mean wins; but in this particular variant, 
if you don't rate candidate X, you don't change his mean in any way.


So you could have a candidate A that's ranked with a mean of 8.5 by 1 
million voters, and a candidate B that's ranked with a mean of 9 by 500 
000 voters (and otherwise not ranked). Say more than 500k of the ballots 
list A first. Then B is barred from winning by the Plurality criterion. 
Yet by the logic of mean Range, B should win because, according to that 
logic, the voters who didn't list B were just saying they didn't *know* 
what rating B should have and instead left the task of determining B's 
mean to the others who did rate B.


Now, pure mean Range has a problem in that candidates who are only known 
by a few fanatics could get an illegitimate win, so some sort of soft 
quorum (like IMDB does for its movies) is probably better. I just use 
mean Range as an example of a system that isn't obviously insane yet 
fails the Plurality criterion (or one particular way the Plurality 
criterion might be extended to rated ballots).



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Warren needs to double check his work.

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
Another might add, This is why the number of competitive candidates and
the extent of low-info voters matters in the comparison.

dlw


On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 3:31 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm 
km_el...@lavabit.com wrote:

 On 06/24/2013 09:33 PM, David L Wetzell wrote:

 There should be a few more fewer ranks in the red in his example.
 http://rangevoting.org/**IrvIgnoreExample.htmlhttp://rangevoting.org/IrvIgnoreExample.html

 Also, I don't think voters care that much if their deeper preferences
 aren't consulted when their top prefs get elected or come in 2nd place
 and so it seems contrived to make a big deal out of it.  This does get
 at why little is lost when only 3 rankings are allowed with IRV, which
 then makes it easier to use those rankings as approval votes for a first
 round that reduces the number of candidates much more quickly.


 One man might say: This does get at why little is lost when only 3
 rankings are allowed with IRV.
 The other man might say: This does get at why full IRV is not much better
 than 3-candidate IRV.




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
The short-cut in my hybrid has been used in some elections  and it had
potential to coopt the momentum of IRV, but I think that FairVote's upgrade
to top-two might take its place...

Now, The same might be true of BTR-IRV, the main draw-back is that seems to
work best with voters ranking the candidates.

I've been presuming that many voters won't want to do a lot of research and
rank all the candidates.  My suggestion doesn't require that to improve on
FPP.
And, the same can be said for the new upgrade FairVote is pushing for.
 Maybe with only 4 candidates, voters will take the time to look at all
four...

dlw

dlw


On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 3:28 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm 
km_el...@lavabit.com wrote:

 On 06/24/2013 05:08 PM, David L Wetzell wrote:

 To ignore the simple upgrade to IRV that I have proffered
 and defended at length on this list-serve,
   when you argue against IRV?


 Yes, for many reasons. Among them: because other simple upgrades give way
 greater bang for the buck.

 Consider BTR-IRV: It's like IRV, except when eliminating, you don't remove
 the Plurality loser. Instead, you eliminate, of the two with worst
 Plurality results for that round, whoever is ranked below the other on the
 most ballots.

 That's two sentences, and boom, Condorcet compliance (and thus resistance
 against Burlington scenarios).

 I can hear the counter: But it's not IRV! It doesn't have momentum! But
 whatever force that counter has against BTR-IRV, it also has against your
 unproven hybrid.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Question about the Plurality Criterion

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 4:45 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm 
km_el...@lavabit.com wrote:

 On 06/24/2013 04:10 PM, Benjamin Grant wrote:

 As I have had it explained to me, the Plurality Criterion is: If there
 are two candidates X and Y so that X has more first place votes than Y
 has any place votes, then Y shouldn't win.

 Which I think means that if X has, for example, 100 votes, then B would
 have to appear on less than 100 ballots and still **win** for this
 criterion to be failed, yes?

 I cannot imagine a (halfway desirable) voting system that would fail the
 Plurality Criterion – can anyone tell me the simplest one that would?
 Apart from a lame one like “least votes win”, I mean?


 That depends on what you put into a candidate not being ranked on the
 ballot. If you think that voters mean that all the candidates they rank are
 better than those they don't rank, then Plurality obviously makes sense. On
 the other hand, if not ranking a candidate simply means the voter has no
 opinion, then the Plurality criterion is no longer as obvious.


Yeah, I am starting to get that - that is a critical choice to make in
crafting and executing the system.


 A very simple system that fails the Plurality criterion for this reason is
 mean (average) Range. In this system, you take the mean rating of each
 candidate, and greatest mean wins; but in this particular variant, if you
 don't rate candidate X, you don't change his mean in any way.

 So you could have a candidate A that's ranked with a mean of 8.5 by 1
 million voters, and a candidate B that's ranked with a mean of 9 by 500 000
 voters (and otherwise not ranked). Say more than 500k of the ballots list A
 first. Then B is barred from winning by the Plurality criterion. Yet by the
 logic of mean Range, B should win because, according to that logic, the
 voters who didn't list B were just saying they didn't *know* what rating B
 should have and instead left the task of determining B's mean to the others
 who did rate B.

 Now, pure mean Range has a problem in that candidates who are only known
 by a few fanatics could get an illegitimate win, so some sort of soft
 quorum (like IMDB does for its movies) is probably better. I just use mean
 Range as an example of a system that isn't obviously insane yet fails the
 Plurality criterion (or one particular way the Plurality criterion might be
 extended to rated ballots).

 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Interesting - to wrap my brain around this going to have to create some
exmaple fake elections with these stats, will reply back once I have, could
be a day or more.

-Benn

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] All systems of voting are probably deeply flawed

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
Just a quick note to all, if I seem to be going after or down on whatever
system of voting you prefer, don't take it personally. It's not that I have
a better one in mind, it's just that I have a drive to truly know each
system top to bottom, no holds barred. And just because I find an aspect of
a system is abhorrent is not to say that I won't find another system even
more abhorrent.

 

It seems that every voting system I have check out thus far has what I would
certainly call deep flaws. Even if I remove some of the Criteria from the
list that I don't much care about - for example, if I understand it
correctly, it doesn't bother me if a well-supported compromise candidate
(ranked as 1 or 2 by 90%) is elected over a more narrowly supported first
place candidate that still got 51% of the vote.

 

But even if I remove from my personal consideration all the criteria that I
don't care about, there are plenty left that I do, and it sure is seeming
that no matter what, even the least bad system is going to have some (to me)
serious flaws.

 

So, again, if I am saying that your favorite voting system is horrible, that
doesn't mean I'm saying that it isn't inevitable.  Just that none of our
choices seem that wonderful. After all, sometimes the lesser of evils is the
best one can do - at least as a pragmatist, I must be open to that. :)

 

Thanks.

 

-Benn Grant

eFix Computer Consulting

 mailto:b...@4efix.com b...@4efix.com

603.283.6601

 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

On 06/24/2013 03:06 PM, Benjamin Grant wrote:

Hi guys, I’m still here, still pondering, but now I have another
question. I’ve been thinking about score voting, approval voting, and
plurality (FPTP) voting, and I have a concern.

Say we have a situation where we have three candidates, say Gore, Nader,
and Bush. Say we have a voter, Abe whose greatest concern is that Bush
NOT win. His second priority is that Nader win over Gore – but this
priority is a distant second. He *really* doesn’t want Bush to win. He
would prefer Nader over Gore, but he *hates* Bush.

Let’s also say that Abe is intelligent, and he is committed to using his
vote to maximize his happiness – in other words, rather than vote
sincerely and cause his preferences harm, he will always vote
strategically where it is to his benefit to do so.

If Score Voting was in place, and he were to vote sincerely, Abe
probably would vote something like ‘Gore:75, Nader: 100, Bush: 0’.
However, he’s no fool, and he knows that while it is theoretically
possibly that Nader *might* win, Gore is his best chance to stopping
Bush, and that withholding score from Gore might (if all Nader
supporters did it) result in Gore not getting enough of a score,
therefor Bush could win.

So strategically speaking, Abe reasons that although he supports a less
likely candidate more, he strategically should score the front-runner
Gore at full strength, so long as keeping Bush out is the greatest need
– and so long as Nader’s win is unlikely.

So, as far as *I* can see, this converts Score Voting into Approval
voting.


You're generally right. There are some very particular situations with 
incomplete information where it makes the most sense to use partial 
ballots, but those happen way too rarely to make a difference.


You can see this from the other end, too: say you're in an Approval 
election and want to vote 0-10-range style. You want to give X a rating 
of 4, but it's an Approval election. To do this, you generate a random 
number on 0...10. If it is lower or equal to the rating (in this case 
4), you approve of X, otherwise, you don't. If everybody did that, the 
Range and Approval results would give the same winner (with high 
probability). So in a real sense, Range is Approval with fractional 
votes permitted.


Also, Range could possibly give different results than Approval voting. 
Consider an election where 99% of the voters are strategic. The vote 
comes out to a tie between Nader and Gore, according to these 99%. Then 
the remaining 1%, voting sincerely, vote something like [Nader: 90%, 
Gore: 70%, Bush: 10%] (strategic would be [Nader: 100%, Gore: 100%, 
Bush: 0%]). Then those votes break the tie and Nader wins.
For reasons like this, a mix of strategic and honest voters give better 
results than just having strategic ones.



And say what you want about intelligence being a bar to entry, you can
bet that the smart people behind ALL candidates will make sure that
everyone gets the message, so we can largely ignore #3.  Most people I
imagine would be pragmatic enough to worry more about the end result and
less about sincere vs. strategic, so we ignore #2. And #1 people are
going to vote the same way anways, so they may as well use Approval voting.

OK, so let’s throw out Score Voting and use Approval voting. Gore v
Nader V Bush.  Abe (who hates Bush but prefers Nader) gives an approval
vote to Nader, his top-most preference, but knowing that withholding
approval from Gore could elect Bush (and not wanting to play the
spoiler) he also gives an approval vote to Gore. Since Gore in this
example is far and away receiving much more support than Nader, Gore now
beats Bush.

Let’s call the party that put Nader on the ballot the Green party, and
that they continue to field candidates in further elections that use the
Approval voting system.  Abe notices the following pattern: when the
Green party fields a candidate that doesn’t even have a glimmer of hope
winning the election (like the Gore/Nader/Bush one) that people that
support the Green party candidate also approve the Democrat candidate as
a bulwark against the Republican. And since in those elections the Green
party never really had a hope of winning, the Green approval vote is
ultimately irrelevant – those elections would have proceeded no
differently than if the Green supporters had simply voted Democrat.

But much worse yet, Abe notices that in *some* election, the Green party
actually gets a chunk of people thinking that Green could actually win.
And emboldened by their hopes, many Green supporters decide to go for
it, approve of the Green candidate, but *not* the Democrat one. Result:
in elections where more voters think more favorably towards Green’s
chances, their least preferred choice (the Republican) tends to win more!

This are my two thoughts:

a)Intelligent use of Score Voting becomes Approval Voting, and the harm
in unwise use of Score voting means that Approval Voting is superior to
(and simpler 

Re: [EM] Warren needs to double check his work.

2013-06-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

On 06/24/2013 11:22 PM, David L Wetzell wrote:

Another might add, This is why the number of competitive candidates and
the extent of low-info voters matters in the comparison.


Alright, then tell me what kind of evidence would change your mind as to 
whether the scarcity of competitive candidates is an artifact of 
Plurality or inherent to single-winner elections. (If no such evidence 
can exist, then there's no point in discussing.)


And furthermore, tell me why we shouldn't just use what you call 
multi-winner elections like runoffs and not have to take on faith that 
no single-winner method can produce diversity.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

On 06/24/2013 11:28 PM, David L Wetzell wrote:

The short-cut in my hybrid has been used in some elections  and it had
potential to coopt the momentum of IRV, but I think that FairVote's
upgrade to top-two might take its place...

Now, The same might be true of BTR-IRV, the main draw-back is that seems
to work best with voters ranking the candidates.


Consider these three scenarios.

Scenario 1: Voters don't rank now, but will rank when they see it's 
worth it. Here IRV will eventually crash but BTR-IRV is, well, better.


Scenario 2: Voters rank, contrary to your assumptions (but suggested by 
international evidence). Again, BTR-IRV does better.


Scenario 3: Voters don't rank and never will. BTR-IRV is here no worse 
than IRV.


Under what scenario does BTR-IRV *lose* against ordinary IRV?


I've been presuming that many voters won't want to do a lot of research
and rank all the candidates.


Yes, but to back up that presumption, you have to more or less assume 
that America is so special that the claim itself is impossible to disprove.



My suggestion doesn't require that to improve on FPP.


Plain IRV itself is enough to improve upon FPP. This is like saying 
that I don't have to run very quickly to outrun a turtle.



And, the same can be said for the new upgrade FairVote is pushing for.
  Maybe with only 4 candidates, voters will take the time to look at all
four...


That won't help when the correct candidate is center-squeezed out of the 
way. The only way to ensure there is no center squeeze is to limit the 
number of candidates to two - and then you have plain old runoff.




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 6:19 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm 
km_el...@lavabit.com wrote:

 Scenario 1: Voters don't rank now, but will rank when they see it's worth
 it. Here IRV will eventually crash but BTR-IRV is, well, better.

 Scenario 2: Voters rank, contrary to your assumptions (but suggested by
 international evidence). Again, BTR-IRV does better.

 Scenario 3: Voters don't rank and never will. BTR-IRV is here no worse
 than IRV.

 Under what scenario does BTR-IRV *lose* against ordinary IRV?


I am quite interested in the answer to this as well, as I imagine that
whatever the answer is is a defining advantage, should any exist.

-Benn

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Warren needs to double check his work.

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
KM:Alright, then tell me what kind of evidence would change your mind as to
whether the scarcity of competitive candidates is an artifact of Plurality
or inherent to single-winner elections. (If no such evidence can exist,
then there's no point in discussing.)

dlw:Let's switch to IRV + American forms of PR(in more local elections) and
watch the feedback loop.   We should be able to observe over time how the
dynamics of elections shift, as voter-prefs get better cultivated.  When
folks get habituated to the new system then it'd be easy to put multiple
alts to IRV on various ballots, using IRV to choose between them, and then
we'd see from various experiments  whether upgrading from IRV continues a
feedback loop in improving the quantity as well as quality of competitive
candidates on the ballot.

KM:And furthermore, tell me why we shouldn't just use what you call
multi-winner elections like runoffs and not have to take on faith that no
single-winner method can produce diversity.

dlw: We need both diversity and hierarchy.  This is why we need a mix of
election rules, some encouraging diversity/equality, others encouraging
hierarchy/order.  We need the latter because of the need for collective
action and coordination.

I classify multiple stage elections as hybrids between multi-winner and
single-winner elections.  I think they're costly but good systems.  If we
replaced all of our current fptp systems with a partisan primary in the US
with the FairVote upgrade on top two primary, it'd improve the system.  But
I'd rather not use one election rule for all elections.  I think it'd be
hard to get turnout up and fair in the first election, even with four
winners.

dlw

dlw


On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 5:10 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm 
km_el...@lavabit.com wrote:

 On 06/24/2013 11:22 PM, David L Wetzell wrote:

 Another might add, This is why the number of competitive candidates and
 the extent of low-info voters matters in the comparison.


 Alright, then tell me what kind of evidence would change your mind as to
 whether the scarcity of competitive candidates is an artifact of Plurality
 or inherent to single-winner elections. (If no such evidence can exist,
 then there's no point in discussing.)

 And furthermore, tell me why we shouldn't just use what you call
 multi-winner elections like runoffs and not have to take on faith that no
 single-winner method can produce diversity.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread David L Wetzell
It's a good argument.

1. What if candidates/parties are inherently fuzzy and rankings are
tenuous?  It can be done, I just don't put a lot of faith in them.

A. If I'm wrong and IRV proves defunct then IRV can be used to upgrade IRV.

B. If I'm right then the switch to an upgrade might make it harder to
switch away from FPTP/Top2 Primary and the return won't be higher.

2. At issue is how much better wd BTR-IRV be.  Maybe voters will rank and
there'll be GIGO.  Not for all of them, but for enough of them.  I'm not
saying voters can't learn, I'm saying voters will need to learn and there
still might be epistemic limits to their learning of how to vote.  It's not
like buying groceries every week, something relatively stable and done a
lot of times.

3. We get IRV quicker and the US system must hew to the true center sooner,
with the cultural wars wedge issues that have been poisoning our democracy
more effectively reframed by outsiders who may not be able to get elected
but would be able to get their ideas into the public square with a system
like IRV.

We needed a system like IRV over forty years ago.  There'll be more scope
for experimentation and voter-learning down the road, right now the gaming
of the fptp system has accumulated so much dysfunction and resistance to
reform that it's best to push forward with whatever will do the most good
the soonest possible and that seems to be a modified form of IRV.

dlw


On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 5:25 PM, Benjamin Grant panjakr...@gmail.comwrote:

 On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 6:19 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm 
 km_el...@lavabit.com wrote:

 Scenario 1: Voters don't rank now, but will rank when they see it's worth
 it. Here IRV will eventually crash but BTR-IRV is, well, better.

 Scenario 2: Voters rank, contrary to your assumptions (but suggested by
 international evidence). Again, BTR-IRV does better.

 Scenario 3: Voters don't rank and never will. BTR-IRV is here no worse
 than IRV.

 Under what scenario does BTR-IRV *lose* against ordinary IRV?


 I am quite interested in the answer to this as well, as I imagine that
 whatever the answer is is a defining advantage, should any exist.

 -Benn


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Benjamin Grant
On Mon, Jun 24, 2013 at 6:06 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm 
km_el...@lavabit.com wrote:

 On 06/24/2013 03:06 PM, Benjamin Grant wrote:

 So strategically speaking, Abe reasons that although he supports a less
 likely candidate more, he strategically should score the front-runner
 Gore at full strength, so long as keeping Bush out is the greatest need
 – and so long as Nader’s win is unlikely.

 So, as far as *I* can see, this converts Score Voting into Approval
 voting.


 You're generally right. There are some very particular situations with
 incomplete information where it makes the most sense to use partial
 ballots, but those happen way too rarely to make a difference.


Excellent, that makes me feel like I am not utterly in left field wondering
where everyone went.


 You can see this from the other end, too: say you're in an Approval
 election and want to vote 0-10-range style. You want to give X a rating of
 4, but it's an Approval election. To do this, you generate a random number
 on 0...10. If it is lower or equal to the rating (in this case 4), you
 approve of X, otherwise, you don't. If everybody did that, the Range and
 Approval results would give the same winner (with high probability). So in
 a real sense, Range is Approval with fractional votes permitted.

 Also, Range could possibly give different results than Approval voting.
 Consider an election where 99% of the voters are strategic. The vote comes
 out to a tie between Nader and Gore, according to these 99%. Then the
 remaining 1%, voting sincerely, vote something like [Nader: 90%, Gore: 70%,
 Bush: 10%] (strategic would be [Nader: 100%, Gore: 100%, Bush: 0%]). Then
 those votes break the tie and Nader wins.
 For reasons like this, a mix of strategic and honest voters give better
 results than just having strategic ones.


Of course, there are (in the circumstance where Gore is the better chance
to beat Bush than Nader) likely more Gore:100 Nader:0 Bush) votes than
Nader: 90 Gore:70 Bush 10 ones.

In fact, given that we *are* talking about an election with two strong
front running candidates and one spoiler weaker one, isn't it *far* more
likely that Gore is far in front of Nader and the only real unknown is if
Gore will beat Bush or not? Which leads right back to the entire scenario
of issues I began with.

The thing is, whenever we have more than two parties running, I think we
will always have weaker spoiler parties that cannot really win, but that
can, if the system allows or encourages people to vote against their best
interest, cause people to get a much lower ranked choice, possibly their
least preferred choice - this is my whole concern.

Am I substantially wrong about any of this? Ultimately, in real and
 practical terms, it seems that done intelligently, Score Voting devolves
 into Approval Voting, and Approval Voting devolves into Plurality Voting.

 How is this not so?


 I would much prefer a good ranked balloting system to Approval, but let me
 try to explain the other side as well.

 Your observation is right in that there's obvious tension between
 approving of only Nader (so Nader will win) and of both Nader and Gore (so
 Bush won't win). This is one of the reasons I dont like Approval all that
 much: I think it burdens the voter with having to convert an internal
 preference into an Approval-style ballot in what I call manual DSV. DSV
 is Designated Strategy Voting, a meta-system where one has a computer find
 out the optimal strategic vote for some given honest vote. The implication
 of having to engage in manual DSV is rather like having to do a
 mathematical task in your head before voting: we'd rather not and it makes
 the system more unwieldy.

 So there are really three stages to a prospective new party or candidate
 (like the Greens or Nader):

 1. the candidate is not competitive (e.g. fringe candidate).
 2. the candidate is competitive but either not strong enough to win, or
 there's been a miscalculation by the voters.
 3. the candidate has taken over the position that would belong to a
 competitor (e.g. Nader becomes the new Gore).

 I think Approval advocates argue that the relative share of approvals will
 inform the voters of where they are. So the progression goes something like:

 In stage one, everybody who approves of Nader also approves of Gore.
 In stage three, the tables are turned: everybody who approves of Gore also
 approves of Nader, but Nader still wins.

 Stage two and the transition to three is the tricky part. In rounds of
 repeated polling, the voters start off cautious (approving both Nader and
 Gore). Then they see that Nader has approval close to Gore's level, so some
 start approving of Nader alone. This then reinforces the perception that
 Nader is winning, so more voters approve of Nader alone. And so it goes
 until Nader is slightly ahead of Gore and wins.


Aha! But what if what is likely happens in stage two: People get ahead of
themselves and give their full support to Nader and 

Re: [EM] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically substantially different from Plurality?

2013-06-24 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi,


 De : Benjamin Grant
Cc : EM election-methods@lists.electorama.com 
Envoyé le : Lundi 24 juin 2013 17h53
Objet : Re: [EM] Score Voting and Approval Voting not practically 
substantially different from Plurality?
 

The only way to avoid this, I *think*, is with a system in which expressing a 
preference of A over B doesn't let C win - and such a system may well have 
worse flaws, possibly.

Right, you are here so close to IIA that you'd be stuck with random ballot or 
similar. FBC is sort of a next best. It's very close in spirit, only you're 
guaranteed to be able to vote A top and equal to B, but not necessarily 
strictly higher. Otherwise, we might create conflicting entitlements.

Kevin

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info