[PEN-L:1728] Re: prison privatization

1998-12-19 Thread valis

I had posted [PEN-L 1545] without any particular intention of getting
a response from Eric Schlosser, but thanks to Ms Bolick there may
be one, and perhaps he will address the list directly.  I hope that 
Ms Bolick will always be proud to be part of such a great publication.

  valis
   

 I have printed out your message and will forward it to Eric Schlosser
 via postal mail. 

 Best,

 Katie Bolick
 The Atlantic Monthly

   

On Dec 18 Jim Devine wrote in [PEN-L 1711]:

 Reading the excellent article in the December 1998 ATLANTIC MONTHLY about
 the prison-industrial complex (by Eric Schlosser) reminded me of the
 satirical article I posted to pen-l 4 or 5 years ago. Almost all of my
 satire seems to have come true.
 
 There's a discussion of for-profit prison corruption that is interesting.
 Privatizing a prison (making its managment profit-seeking, creating what
 Brad might call a "free marketplace of prisoners") doesn't end the need for
 the government to supervise them. (Mostly, it allows cost-cutting by
 bringing in non-union labor, cutting corners, etc., allowing the owners to
 pay their CEOs princely salaries.) Noticeable in Schlosser's story is that
 the kind of corruption changes.  If a privatized prison's management breaks
 the rules of the contract (or the laws), it creates the incentive to bribe
 the government regulators in one way or another (typically by hiring them
 as consultants). On the other hand, if a government-owned prison's
 management does this, they have fewer resources for such bribes. So we see
 "you scratch my back and I'll scratch yours" type corruption, which is
 common in all bureaucracies, allowing the persistance of problems. What's
 noticeable is that the privatized version leads to much greater income
 disparities. This parallels the situation in the US class system (which
 promotes income disparities) and the USSR class system (which had very
 limited disparities). 
 
 any thoughts?
 
 Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
 http://clawww.lmu.edu/Faculty/JDevine/jdevine.html
 








[PEN-L:1731] Class, race and gender in the early American Marxist movement

1998-12-19 Thread Louis Proyect

Dogmatic Marxism's hostility toward "non-class" demands has been around for
a very long time, judging from the evidence of Timothy Messer-Kruse's "The
Yankee International: 1848-1876." (U. of North Carolina, 1998) Furthermore,
you are left with the disturbing conclusion that this problem existed at
the very highest levels of the first Communist International, and included
Marx himself.

The people who launched a section of the Communist International in the USA
were veteran radicals, who had fought against slavery and for women's
rights for many years. They saw the emerging anti-capitalist struggles in
Europe, most especially the Paris Commune of 1871, as consistent with their
own. They saw revolutionary socialism as the best way to guarantee the
success of the broader democratic movement. What European Marxism would
think of them is an entirely different matter.

The names of some of the early recruits should give you an indication of
the political character of the new movement. Included were abolitionists
Horace Greely, Wendell Phillips and Charles Sumner. Feminist Victoria
Woodhull joined in and put her magazine "Woodhull and Claflin's Weekly" at
its disposal. The weekly not only included communications from Karl Marx,
but spiritualist musings from Woodhull. The native radical movement of the
1870s was a mixed bag. Socialism, anti-racism, feminism, pacifism and
spiritualism co-existed comfortably. The Europeans were anxious to purify
the movement of all these deviations from the very start. Unfortunately
they put anti-racism, feminism and spiritualism on an equal footing.

Victoria Woodhull was unquestionably the biggest irritant, since she
defended all these deviations while at the same time she spoke out
forcefully for free love, the biggest deviation imaginable in the Victorian
age:

"The sexual relation, must be rescued from this insidious form of slavery.
Women must rise from their position as ministers to the passions of men to
be their equals. Their entire system of education must be changed. They
must be trained to be like men, permanent and independent individualities,
and not their mere appendages or adjuncts, with them forming but one member
of society. They must be the companions of men from choice, never from
necessity."

Marx decided to put an end to all this nonsense and threw his weight behind
the German-American Frederic Sorge, who was assigned to clean house.
Against the Yankee swamp, Sorge would ram through a "scientific socialism"
that was true to the tenets of Marx and Engels. Furthermore, the
orientation of the American section would not be to women and blacks, but
only to the white workers and their embryonic trade unions. It seemed to
matter little that Sorge understood next to nothing about American
politics. His mastery of Marxist doctrine would produce the desired
results: "Fellow-workman," he proclaimed, "Keep our standard pure  our
ranks clean! Never mind the small number! No great work was ever begun by a
majority." With sectarian nonsense like this, it should surprise nobody
that Sorge's group remained small in number. What does surprise us is that
Sorge was Marx's hand-picked leader.

The Yankees and the German-American "orthodox Marxists" split and began to
carry out their respective orientations, which are instructive to compare.
Although the Sorge group was formally in favor of racial equality, their
actions often fell short of the verbal commitment. The simple explanation
for this is that they adapted to the prejudices of the white workers whom
they curried favor with.

Woodhull's group made no such concessions, as their political traditions
were rooted in the abolitionist movement. Indeed, when they called for a
mass demonstration in New York City to commemorate the martyrs of the Paris
Commune, the first rank in the parade went to a company of black soldiers
known as the Skidmore Guard. The demonstration passed by a quarter million
spectators and the sight of armed black men in the vanguard was
electrifying. Sorge's group complained that the demonstration was a
distraction from working-class struggles, whose participants would lose a
day's pay by participating. He called for a boycott.

Black militias were an important fixture of northern urban politics in this
period. When black men donned uniforms and marched in formation, they were
making a statement not only about their full rights as citizens, but their
determination to back these rights by any means necessary. The black
Eighty-Fifth Regiment in NYC was one of the more radical and
internationalist militias in the city. They had marched alongside Irish New
Yorkers in honor of Fenian heroes and gave their units names like the
"[Crispus] Attucks Guards" and "Free Soil Guards." This regiment decided to
name Tennessee Claflin, Victoria Woodhull's sister, their commander and
supplied her with a uniform. Woodhull had become the presidential candidate
of the Equal Rights Party in 1872 and her vice-presidential 

[PEN-L:1732] Re: Re: Re: Re: neoclassical econ.13945.61647.288450.515102@lisa.zopyra.comv04003a04b29f8800d37b@[136.152.90.200]v04003a04b29f33da9e82@[136.152.90.200]3.0.3.32.19981217134329.006a4eec@lmumail.lmu.eduv04003a0eb29e01c93904@[128.32.105.161]3.0.3.32.19981216160851.0069a724@lmumail.lmu.eduv04003a0db29dea5fb879@[128.32.105.161]3.0.3.32.19981216115914.006a5b38@lmumail.lmu.eduv04003a04b29db9ce5003@[128.32.105.161]3.0.1.32.19981216130547.00b20590@popserver.panix.comv04003a04b29d9eeb3190@[136.152.90.200]3.0.3.32.19981216092322.006b0f6c@lmumail.lmu.eduv04003a01b29d97f48e77@[136.152.90.200]3.0.1.32.19981216110156.00901b74@popserver.panix.com007d01be2900$0ea6bde0$2e0036ca@abcv04003a04b29f8800d37b@[136.152.90.200]3.0.3.32.19981218130633.006c423c@lmumail.lmu.edu 3.0.3.32.19981218152129.00703ccc@lmumail.lmu.edu

1998-12-19 Thread Mathew Forstater


--D8BB81645E32E6196DB1EBC3

Jim Devine wrote:

 since there are some basic contributions that
 neoclassical economics agrees to, such as how supply and demand operate in
 partial equilibrium. However, since there is no school of economics that
 does not believe in these verities


If I understand what you are saying, this is in fact not true at all.  Smith's
notion of natural and market price (held by all of the classical economists and
Marx as well) were not the same thing as the neoclassical notion of how supply
and demand operate in partial equilibrium.  The notion that supply and demand
forces determine prices is not the same as the notion that prices may deviate
from natural or normal prices due to excess supply or demand.  The latter notion
is perfectly consistent with a labor theory of value or Sraffian prices, which
are not the same as the neoclassical notion of how supply and demand operate in
partial equilibrium.  maybe I misunderstood what you were saying. If you were
saying only that many schools of economics recognize the *laws* of supply and
demand, as opposed to the *theory* of supply and demand, then that would be
closer to the truth (though not all subscribe to that even) but that is a very
insignificant similarity when compared with the differences in theories of value,
distribution, accumulation, output and employment, and technical change.

Mat

--D8BB81645E32E6196DB1EBC3

!DOCTYPE HTML PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD HTML 4.0 Transitional//EN"
HTML
Jim Devine wrote:
BLOCKQUOTE TYPE=CITE
PREsince there are some basic contributions that
neoclassical economics agrees to, such as how supply and demand operate in
partial equilibrium. However, since there is no school of economics that
does not believe in these verities/PRE
/BLOCKQUOTE

PBRIf I understand what you are saying, this is in fact not true at
all.nbsp; Smith's notion of natural and market price (held by all of the
classical economists and Marx as well) were not the same thing as the neoclassical
notion of how supply and demand operate in partial equilibrium.nbsp; The
notion that supply and demand forces determine prices is not the same as
the notion that prices may deviate from natural or normal prices due to
excess supply or demand.nbsp; The latter notion is perfectly consistent
with a labor theory of value or Sraffian prices, which are not the same
as the neoclassical notion of how supply and demand operate in partial
equilibrium.nbsp; maybe I misunderstood what you were saying. If you were
saying only that many schools of economics recognize the *laws* of supply
and demand, as opposed to the *theory* of supply and demand, then that
would be closer to the truth (though not all subscribe to that even) but
that is a very insignificant similarity when compared with the differences
in theories of value, distribution, accumulation, output and employment,
and technical change.
PMat/HTML

--D8BB81645E32E6196DB1EBC3--






[PEN-L:1735] Re: Class, race and gender in the early American Marxist movement

1998-12-19 Thread Doug Henwood

In the middle of a very fine piece, Louis Proyect unfortunately wrote:

The answer to dogmatic Marxism is not Judith Butler, as Doug Henwood seems
to think.

I do not think any such thing, nor have I said or written anything remotely
like that. Just because I think someone is intelligent and instructive
doesn't mean I think he or she has "the answer." A minor point: her
critique of "neoconservative Marxism," though rather misspecified (Alan
Sokal is *not* a Marxist), it still has a lot in common with the Proyect
critique of "dogmatic Marxism."

By the way, this will all be thrashed out in the lbo-talk seminar on
Butler's Psychic Life of Power, beginning on January 10.

Doug






[PEN-L:1737] Re: Re: Re: Re: Social Democracy and Utopia

1998-12-19 Thread Rosser Jr, John Barkley

Brad,
 Well, I've already granted that Scandinavian social 
democracies were more liberal democratic than Tito's 
Yugoslavia, which was a one-party state after all.  
However, despite Tito's despotism, it was clearly the most 
politically and civilly liberal of any of the "communist" 
states.
 This story about worker-managed firms not hiring is at 
least partly one of those theoretical results that (the 
1958 Benjamin Ward AER paper) that has become a standard 
poop line among most economists.  However it is not always 
true.  Again, I picked Slovenia precisely because up until 
the collapse of Yugoslavia it had an unemployment rate of 
less than 5%.  I also note that the same theoretical texts, 
as well as the studies by Pencavel of the northwest US 
plywood cooperatives, suggests that labor does not get laid 
off as much in downturns as in traditional firms.
Barkley Rosser
On Fri, 18 Dec 1998 16:30:55 -0800 Brad De Long 
[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 Brad,
  OK, for the umpteenth time I am going to point
 something out to you to which you have never responded.
  What about Slovenia and worker-managed market
 socialism?  Taking a look at where it started from in 1945,
 the record is pretty good and although not as liberal of a
 democracy as the Scandinavian social democracies, it was
 pretty free and easy, more so than other states ruled by a
 Communist Party (actually the League of Yugoslav Workers,
 to be technically precise).
  I must grant that Slovenia's virtues are only clearer
 since the collapse of Yugoslavia, and that the overall
 record there on a lot of grounds has been not as good,
 although your constant inclusion of Tito in your list of
 awful leaders looks pretty thin.  Things only went bad in
 Yugoslavia after old "last of the Hapsburgs" kicked the
 bucket.
 Barkley Rosser
 
 Milovan Djilas has... interesting views of Tito. A believer in political
 democracy Tito was not.
 
 There is the problem that successful worker-managed firms tend to want to
 not hire new workers (because it dilutes the value of their ownership
 share), so you have higher demand for a factory's products leading to a
 contraction in the factory's production. But I would love it if ESOPs
 became the chief means by which corporations raised capital. And I have
 always been profoundly depressed that both co-determination and
 worker-managed firms have not managed to expand faster...
 
 
 Brad DeLong
 

-- 
Rosser Jr, John Barkley
[EMAIL PROTECTED]






[PEN-L:1740] Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: neoclassical econ.

1998-12-19 Thread Jim Devine

--=_243102602==_.ALT

I wrote: 


 since there are some basic contributions that
 neoclassical economics agrees to, such as how supply and demand operate in
 partial equilibrium. However, since there is no school of economics that
 does not believe in these verities 


Matt writes:If I understand what you are saying, this is in fact not true at
all.  Smith's notion of natural and market price (held by all of the classical
economists and Marx as well) were not the same thing as the neoclassical notion
of how supply and demand operate in partial equilibrium.

I don't think we disagree with each other on this. For Smith and the Classicals
(sounds like a rock group, no?), supply and demand determined fluctuations
about "natural" prices (Marx's prices of production). The neoclassicals accept
the fluctuations but not the centers of gravity.

... If you were saying only that many schools of economics recognize the
*laws* of supply and demand, as opposed to the *theory* of supply and demand,
then that would be closer to the truth (though not all subscribe to that even)
but that is a very insignificant similarity when compared with the differences
in theories of value, distribution, accumulation, output and employment, and
technical change. 

I was only talking about the narrowest sense of "supply and demand."

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
http://clawww.lmu.edu/Faculty/JDevine/JDevine.html

--=_243102602==_.ALT

html
I wrote: br
preblockquote type=cite citeblockquote type=cite citesince there
are some basic contributions that
neoclassical economics agrees to, such as how supply and demand operate
in
partial equilibrium. However, since there is no school of economics 
that
does not believe in these verities/pre
/blockquote/blockquote
Matt writes:gt;If I understand what you are saying, this is in fact not
true at all.nbsp; Smith's notion of natural and market price (held by
all of the classical economists and Marx as well) were not the same thing
as the neoclassical notion of how supply and demand operate in partial
equilibrium.lt;br
br
I don't think we disagree with each other on this. For Smith and the
Classicals (sounds like a rock group, no?), supply and demand determined
fluctuations about quot;naturalquot; prices (Marx's prices of
production). The neoclassicals accept the fluctuations but not the
centers of gravity.br
br
gt;... If you were saying only that many schools of economics recognize
the *laws* of supply and demand, as opposed to the *theory* of supply and
demand, then that would be closer to the truth (though not all subscribe
to that even) but that is a very insignificant similarity when compared
with the differences in theories of value, distribution, accumulation,
output and employment, and technical change. lt;br
br
I was only talking about the narrowest sense of quot;supply and
demand.quot;br
br
divJim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] amp;
a href="http://clawww.lmu.edu/Faculty/JDevine/JDevine.html" 
EUDORA=AUTOURLhttp://clawww.lmu.edu/Faculty/JDevine/JDevine.html/a/div
/html

--=_243102602==_.ALT--






[PEN-L:1741] Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Social Democracy and Utopia

1998-12-19 Thread Jim Devine

I would add that worker-owned firms don't require an external reserve army
of labor in order to motivate people to work under conditions of workplace
authoritarianism, the way capitalist firms do. 

Barkley writes: 
 This story about worker-managed firms not hiring is at 
least partly one of those theoretical results that (the 
1958 Benjamin Ward AER paper) that has become a standard 
poop line among most economists.  However it is not always 
true.  Again, I picked Slovenia precisely because up until 
the collapse of Yugoslavia it had an unemployment rate of 
less than 5%.  I also note that the same theoretical texts, 
as well as the studies by Pencavel of the northwest US 
plywood cooperatives, suggests that labor does not get laid 
off as much in downturns as in traditional firms.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
http://clawww.lmu.edu/Faculty/JDevine/JDevine.html






[PEN-L:1743] Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: neoclassical econ.

1998-12-19 Thread Jim Devine

It was I, not Mirowski, as the one who put the parenthetical remark
"utilitarianism" by point 4 of his list. I was using the word very broadly,
as defined in point 4 itself. But thanks for the very informative
discussion of utilitarianism.

Ken Hanly writes: 
COMMENT: This is an interesting and helpful list  of important features of 
neoclasical 
economics, but I strongly disagree with Mirowski's statement that 
neoclassical economics 
is utilitarian. In historical terms, it is true that economic theory had
close 
connections with utilitarianism, as in James Mill, Bentham, and Jevons, but 
modern 
neo-classical economics shares little with utilitarianism except the term 
"utility" . 
In economics the term no longer connotes a theory of value or ethical theory 
as it does 
in utilitarianism.
   Here are just a few differences:
   * Utilitarianism always has a definite theory of value. For example 
classical utilitarianism held the view that the good=pleasure. Economics has 
no theory of 
value, although it does use a principle that implicitly makes a value 
judgment ==the 
Pareto Principle-=-and certain parts of welfare economics seem to involve 
further value 
judgments. The beauty of the system is supposed to be that it does not 
depend upon 
solving the problem of what is really good; only preferences are counted but 
hey are not 
evaluated as good or bad.
   * Utilitarianism has a definite theory of obligation. You ought to maximize 
the 
general happiness. Preferences can be measured in terms of whether they 
maximize 
happpiness or not. You can make interpersonal comparisons of utility. In 
economics you 
can't . The neo-classical economist can't tell you what policies would make 
for the 
greatest happiness of the greatest number, just which would be 
Pareto-efficient. Even the 
most dyed-in-the-wool neo-classical welfare economist would admit that 
analysis must be 
supplemented by value and political considerations. Of course I suppose if 
you  act 
contrary to what anlaysis would indicate you commit the cardinal sin of being 
inefficient.
   * Of course there are other types of utilitarian. G.E. Moore was a 
utilitarian 
who rejected the hedonistic theory of value of Bentham. Moore is just as far 
from the 
neo-classicals though. He held that the good was an objective, simple, 
non-natural 
property that some things have, not identical with pleausure, being 
preferred, desired, 
or whatever. It is indefinable, just like the empirical property "yellow", 
something he 
often compared it with; but it differs from "yellow" in being non-natural. 
Why" Well take 
any definition of "good" in terms of a natural property and ask of anything 
that has that 
property whether it is good. The question is not "empty" or "tautologous" as 
is the 
question "Are bachelors unmarried males". This shows that the concept of 
good is not 
identical to the property you have used to define it. For example you can ask 
significantly: This is pleasant but is it good? Therefore "good" does not
mean 
"pleasant". I am sure neo-classicals do not talk about this sort of thing 
and would 
wonder what was going on. But if you are a utilitarian you need a theory of 
value. Of 
course neo-classicals aren't. It is an insult to utilitarians to put them in 
the same 
camp with people who seem to be lacking even the most primitive 
understanding of value 
theory. By the  way Frank Knight, one of Milton Friedman
's profs. and a neo-classical of sorts himself, is an exception to what I 
have said 
above. He has an excellent article on the value shortcomings of 
neo-classical analysis. 
He also has an article that discusses Moore at some length. I can't remember 
the title 
for sure but I think it was ESSAYS ON ECONOMICS, it is edited by Milton 
Friedman in any 
event. I'll look it up if no one knows it offhand.) (END COMMENT)


 CHeers, Ken Hanly




 
 n case anyone was wondering what I mean be neoclassical, here's a
 definition, which follows Phil Mirowski:
 
 1. employs mathematical modeling rather than institutional analysis or
 historical evidence as its main tool for understanding the world
(formalism);
 
 2. claims to be "scientific" in a positivist or Cartesian way, in imitation
 of idealized natural science (positivism);
 
 3. utilizes constrained maximization, equilibrium, and comparative statics
 as its main analytical pillars (equilibrium economics);
 
 4. emphasizes individual utility-maximization (consistent goal-seeking) as
 the determinant of human behavior (utilitarianism);
 
 5. always seeks out microfoundations, i.e., solely individual explanations
 of aggregate phenomena (reductionism, methodological individualism); and
 finally,
 
 6. leaves many of the most important variables, such as tastes and
 technology, as exogenously determined by nature or other forces outside of
 the economist's concern (naturalism).
 
 To Mirowski's list, I would add a final tenet, hopefully as a friendly
 

[PEN-L:1744] Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Social Democracy and Utopia

1998-12-19 Thread Doug Henwood

Jim Devine wrote:

I would add that worker-owned firms don't require an external reserve army
of labor in order to motivate people to work under conditions of workplace
authoritarianism, the way capitalist firms do.

No, but they have an incentive not to hire, to avoid diluting profits,
don't they?

Doug






[PEN-L:1747] Re: Re: Re: Re: prison privatization

1998-12-19 Thread Brad De Long

Bentham's panopticon was based on designs actually used by his brother for
workers in shipyards.

Michael Perelman

Very depressing that it was actually put into effect. Do you have a
reference?...

Brad DeLong






[PEN-L:1748] Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: prison privatization

1998-12-19 Thread michael perelman

Brad asked for this reference:

  Ashworth, William R. 1994. "The Calculating Eye: Baily, Herschel, Babbage
and the Business of Astronomy." British Journal of the History of Science,
27, pp. 409-41.
   435: "Samuel Bentham ... employed the same principles of labour
management that the business astronomers later applied to the mental
management of knowledge production." Bentham, Samuel. 1828. Naval Essays, or
Essays on the Management of Public Concerns as Exemplified in the Naval
Department, Considered as a Branch of the Business of Warfare (London): p.
36.435: "In his division of dockyard labour he disregarded the
"artificial, but common classification of works according to trades or
handicrafts," said his wife and biographer, since, "it stood particularly in
the way when the object was the contrivance of a good system of machinery.
He therefore began by classing the several operations requisite and when
these had been classed, he next proceeded to the contrivance of machines by
which they might be performed, and that, independently of the need for skill
or manual dexterity in the workmen"."
   435: Samuel planned a manufacturing site in Kricheff, Russia, "so
contrived as that the whole of the operations carried on in it should be
under observation from its centre." Bentham, Maria S. [Samuel's widow]].
1862. The Life of Brigadier-General Sir Samuel Bentham, p. 83.436:
Jeremy used the panopticon idea as "a mill for grinding rogues honest and
idle men industrious." John Bowring. 1843. The Works of Jeremy Bentham
(Edinburgh): x, p. 226. quoted in Cooper, Carolyn C. 1984. "The Portsmouth
System of Manufacture." Technology and Culture, 2, pp. 182-226, p. 193.
438: "No longer needed were the steady and dexterous hand, judgment, and
timing that a turner, a joiner, or a carpenter, as well as a traditional
blockmaster, took years of practice to achieve.  That skill was, for most
operations, "built into" the machines." Cooper, Carolyn C. 1984. "The
Portsmouth System of Manufacture." Technology and Culture, 2, pp. 182-226,
p. 193.440: "This is an utilitarian age.  No man is now allowed any
credit for indulging in idle speculations and closet fancies." Review of
'Letters addressed to H. R. H. the Grand Duke of Saxe-Coburg and Gotha, on
the theory of probabilities as applied to the moral and political sciences,
by M. A. Quetelet, Astronomer Royal of Belgium, London (1849)." The
Assurance Magazine and the Institute of Actuaries (1851): 1, p. 362.441:
He concludes: "To reduce risk required a foundation of trust and confidence
through the establishment of sound public accounts and the reconstitution of
a trustworthy character.  The commercial and scientific arena had to be
cleansed of irresponsible adventurers to enable 'real' growth in knowledge
and financial capital."##






[PEN-L:1751] Michael Quinn article

1998-12-19 Thread Ken Hanly

I should perhaps have mentioned that Michael Quinn is an Associate 
Research Fellow at the Bentham Project, University College London. He is 
editing Bentham's writings on Poor Relief. The article is in the Bentham 
Newsletter for 1997. There is another article on Bentham's project to 
freeze peas if anyone is interested!
  Cheers, Ken Hanly






Re: [PEN-L:1736] Stampeding bison?199812171533.BAA06772@elf.brisnet.org.au 4.0.1.19981219130529.0101b960@popserver.panix.com

1998-12-19 Thread Peter Dorman

More on the changing ecology of the great plains: the chapter on cattle
and meat-packing in Cronon's NATURE'S METROPOLIS.

Peter Dorman

Louis Proyect wrote:
 
 Today's NY Times has an article titled "People Can't Agree on What's
 Natural and What's Not," by Timothy Egan that repeats an often-heard
 accusation against the American Indian, namely that they were just as
 "wasteful" of natural resources as the Europeans. Egan writes:
 
 "A hundred years ago, after the Americans had wiped out most of the
 bounteous bison of the West and removed the native people who had lived on
 those animals, there came a great die-out of domestic cattle. A long,
 bitter winter left cowboys without cows, and the Indians saying, 'Told you
 so.' It was, many people still believe, nature's blow against the attempt
 to erase much of the native West.
 
 "But what about the Great Plains tribes, who used to start big grass fires
 to drive bison off a cliff? By some estimates, up to 90 percent of a herd
 was wasted. It may have been natural or simply crafty and wasteful, no
 different from Roman excess."
 
 Well, what about those Great Plains tribes? If you look at the chapter on
 "The Prairie-Plains" in Alice Kehoe's "North American Indians: A
 Comprehensive Account," you will find reference to bison being corralled,
 not being stampeded off cliffs. John C. Ewers was Senior Ethnologist at the
 Smithsonian Institution and an expert on Plains Indians. In his "The
 Blackfeet: Raiders of the Northwestern Plains," there is an account from an
 elder named Old Weasel Tail of how the Blackfoot hunted bison prior to the
 introduction of the horse into their society:
 
 "Near the edge of timber and toward the bottom of a downhill slope the
 Indians built a corral of wooden posts set upright in the ground to a
 height of about seven feet. They connected the posts by crosspoles tied in
 place with rawhide ropes. Around three sides of the corral they laid stakes
 over the lowest crosspoles. Their butt ends were firmly braced in the
 ground outside the corral. These stakes projected about three feet or more
 inside the corral at an angle, so that their sharpened ends were about the
 height of a buffalo's body. If the buffalo tried to break through the
 corral, after they had been driven into it, they would be impaled on these
 stakes. From the open side of the corral the fence of poles extended in two
 wings outward and up the hill. These lines were further extended by piles
 of cut willows in the shape of conical lodges about half the height of a
 man, tied together at their tops. These brush piles were spaced at
 intervals of several feet. On the hill just above the corral opening a
 number of poles were placed on the ground crosswise of the slope and
 parallel to each other. The buffalo had to cross these poles to enter the
 corral. The poles were covered with manure and water, which froze and
 became slippery so that once the buffalo were in the corral they couldn't
 escape by climbing back up the hill.
 
 "Before the drive began a beaver bundle owner removed the sacred buffalo
 stones from his bundle and prayed. He sang a song, 'Give me one buffalo or
 more. Help me to fall the buffalo.'
 
 "Then men of the camp [probably swift-footed, long-winded young fellows]
 were sent out to get behind a herd of buffalo and drive it toward the
 corral. Another man stood at the top of the hill and gave a signal to the
 women and children, who were hiding behind the brush piles, that the
 buffalo were coming. As the animals passed them on their way down the slope
 the women and children ran out of their hiding places.
 
 "Once inside the corral the buffalo were killed by men and boys stationed
 around the outside of the stout fence. Then the camp chief went into the
 corral to take charge of the butchering and the division of the meat. While
 butchering, the people ate buffalo liver, kidneys, and slices of brisket
 raw. Two young men took choice pieces of liver, kidneys, liver, brisket,
 tripe, and manifold to the beaver bundle owner  who had remained in his
 lodge during the slaughter, but whose power had brought success in the
 hunt. Each man who killed a buffalo was given its hide and ribs. The
 slaughtered animals were cut into quarters which were divided among the
 families in the camp. Each family, whether it was large or small, received
 an equal share."
 
 In other words, the bison hunt was not a wanton destruction of wildlife,
 but a calculated effort to supply the basic needs of the village.
 Furthermore, NOT A SINGLE piece of the bison went to waste. The other thing
 to understand is that the great risks were involved. If a hunt was not
 successful, people might starve. The bison might detect the scent of the
 hunter or an unusual sound might frighten them away. Blackfoot tales
 include numerous references to repeated failures to get the animal into the
 corral. There are none that recount driving them off a cliff, which I have
 a feeling is 

[PEN-L:1755] Re: Re: Re: Incorrect Model of Language in TRACTATUS ( Was RE ADNAUSEAM_367C5870.7042@mb.sympatico.ca13948.28799.457331.977517@lisa.zopyra.com367C985E.5C36@mb.sympatico.ca 13948.32430.947319.799784@lisa.zopyra.com

1998-12-19 Thread Ken Hanly

William S. Lear wrote:
The innate structures are structures not derived from experience 
and provide us a source of knowledge of linguistic structures. Surely 
this makes them what traditionally was called innate ideas. Those 
traditional rationalist philosophers, such as Descartes, also held that 
there existed innate ideas that were a source of knowledge. While you are 
correct that CHomsky doesn't typically use the term "innate ideas" 
neither does he deny that the innate structures of the mind are such. The 
very title "Cartesian Linguistics" is an explicit recognition of his 
being in the Cartesian tradition. Does Chomsky every deny that his  
innate structures of the mind are innate ideas? Commentators certainly 
take them as such. I am not aware of his objecting to this. Of course the 
whole concept of innate ideas is anathema to most psychologists and they 
will claim there is no evidence that such exist. The concept of innate 
ideas is quite unpopular in the area of pyschology. Holding radical and 
unpopular views has never phased Chomsky.( Of course these views are not 
at all unpopular among many linguistic theorists.) It is because members 
of other species lack the innate ideas associated with universal grammar 
that they do not have the language competence of most humans. Of course 
there are people out there training apes named after Chomsky who believe 
otherwise.
   CHeers, Ken Hanly
 
 On Sat, December 19, 1998 at 22:25:34 (-0800) Ken Hanly writes:
 In his CARTESIAN LINGUISTICS among other places. ...
 
 I'm familiar with most of Chomsky's work.  I was not sure that he
 expressed the belief that there were "innate ideas".  Rather, I have
 always heard "innate structures" (of the mind) or some such.
 
 Bill






[PEN-L:1752] Re: Re: Incorrect Model of Language in TRACTATUS ( Was RE ADNAUSEAM_

1998-12-19 Thread William S. Lear

On Sat, December 19, 1998 at 17:52:48 (-0800) Ken Hanly writes:
Ajit Sinha wrote:
...
   While Wittgenstein is no behaviorist he would no doubt reject
the Chomskian view that there are innate ideas. ...

Could you tell me where Chomsky expresses his "view that there are
innate ideas"?


Bill






[PEN-L:1750] Michael Quinn on the Poor Panopticon and Benthams Charitable projects.

1998-12-19 Thread Ken Hanly

This is a multi-part message in MIME format.

--6557BC62CE6

This is a rather long article, so those of you who are not interested
in it should hit the delete button. On the other hand if you want to know 
how to reprogramme impoverished street kids so that they can support 
themselves and eventually go out and provide surplus value for capital 
just as other decent workers do, Bentham has the recipe.
  Cheers, Ken Hanly

--6557BC62CE6

BASE HREF=3D"file:///C|/NETSCAPE/DIALER/QUINN2.HTM"

1=BE=00=00=00=AB=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=E4+=01=00Y=02k=02k=02k=02k=02k=02=00=
=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=
=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=
=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00l=02=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=
=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00=00HTML
HEAD
TITLETHE BENTHAM NEWSLETTER/TITLE/HEADBODY
BGCOLOR=3D"FF"H2The Fallacy of Non-Interference: The Poor
Panopticon and Equality of Opportunity./H2

PH2Michael Quinn/H2

PIn the long and continuing debate concerning Bentham's status
as a `liberal', the closely related projects of the Panopticon
Penitentiary and the National Charity Company have consistently
been advanced as the conclusive evidence of Bentham's underlying
authoritarianism.SUP1/SUP This fact is unsurprising: for in
relation to both projects Bentham not only explicitly writes in
terms of control, of imposing on persons behaviours and, by
repetition thereof, ultimately character traits, which they do
not wish to acquire, albeit in the alleged interests of those
persons, as well as those of society at large, but appears to
revel in the exercise of `plastic power' in a manner which is
repellent, and does appear to trample on human dignity.  Janet
Semple recognised as much in her study of the
Panopticon.SUP2/SUP  However, she was able to produce a
dispassionate assessment of that ambiguous institution, and to
mount a sophisticated defence of Panopticism, which rested
ultimately on the recognition that, quite simply, a prison is
either a mechanism of control or it is nothing.

PWith reference to the poor law writings, Bentham's explicit
design of using the assemblage of management rules devised for
the Poor Panopticon, and in particular the Inspection
Architecture Principle, to the end of creating thrifty, sober,
and, above all, industrious citizens, looks even more ominous for
any interpretation which seeks to present his intentions as
facilitative, as empowering rather than disempowering, since the
poor had committed no crime, and there would seem to be no
parallel case for their control and rehabilitation.

PBentham does appear to glory in the scope which detention in
a Poor Panopticon gives its governor to break down and recast
entire personalities.  He can plausibly be presented as
anticipating Skinner's box, and filling it with, to use his own
expression, `that part of the national livestock which has no
feathers to it and walks on two legs',SUP3/SUP instead of
rats.  Ought we not then to suspect that, in Bahmueller's words,
`if the truth were known, we would soon suspect that it was not
only the indigent that Bentham wanted to control, but Ius/I
too, Iall/I of us.  That is, we might suspect that Panopticon
was a version of Benthamite society writ small.'SUP4/SUP
Indeed, is Bahmueller further correct to view the emerging
apprentices of the Poor Panopticon, liberated after an entire
lifetime of indoctrination, as the stormtroopers of a Benthamic
blitzkrieg, as `foot soldiers in a surreptitious guerilla war he
hoped to wage against the entrenched mores of an unutilitarian
society'?SUP5/SUP  When Bentham describes his poor house as
a `utopia', is the correct implication that drawn by both
Bahmueller and Himmelfarb, that he believes that everyone would
be much better off for a course in utilitarian
conditioning?SUP6/SUPPThe revisionist response to these indictments i=
s to call in
evidence Bentham's mature constitutional theory, a theory that
is rather less concerned with the insidious exercise of unseen
power than with the supervision, control, and limitation of
power, precisely by means of the exposure of its every exercise
to the evaluation and censure of those over whom it is
exercised.SUP7/SUP  The `existential realisation of
philosophic radicalism'SUP8/SUP is indeed panoptic in a
sense, it does indeed aim at transparency, but the behaviours
which are to be made transparent are those of the holders and
exercisers of coercive power, and the all-seeing eye is that of
the public, the collectivity of individuals to whose welfare that
power presents a standing threat.

PWhat is the explanation of the undeniable tension between
these two Benthams?  The explanation does not lie in the
development of Bentham's thought, for the contrast between the
self-definition of interests on the one hand, and the necessity
of intervention deliberately to form and order the 

[PEN-L:1749] Foucault on the Panopticon

1998-12-19 Thread Ken Hanly

This is a multi-part message in MIME format.

--3F40D9C32E2

The enclosed short file by Foucault shows the significance of the role of 
 warden observation in the design of the panopticon as mentioned by Jim 
Devine. I understood that the public too were allowed to view the 
proceedings. The Poor Panopticons were separate institutions but based 
upon the same architectural principles.
   Cheers, Ken Hanly

--3F40D9C32E2

BASE HREF="file:///C|/NETSCAPE/DIALER/PANOPWHN.HTM"

HTML



HEAD



TITLEUnverifiability of Surveillance in the Panopticon/TITLE



META NAME="GENERATOR" CONTENT="Internet Assistant for Microsoft Word 2.0z"

/HEAD

BODY BGCOLOR="#ff" TEXT="#00" LINK="#008000" VLINK="#808080"



P

Michel Foucault describes the workings of Jeremy Bentham's panopticon,

an architectural design which permits a centralized supervisor

to monitor all of an institution's inmates.  The ultimate goal,

Foucault explains, is for the inmate to internalize the mechanism

of surveillance which the building establishes.

BLOCKQUOTE

[I]t is at once too much and too little that the prisoner should

be constantly observed by an inspector:  too little, for what

matters is that he knows himself to be observed; too much, because

he has no need in fact of being so.  In view of this, Bentham

laid down the principle that power should be visible and unverifiable.

Visible:  the inmate will constantly have before his eyes the

tall outline of the central tower from which he is spied upon.

 Unverifiable:  the inmate must never know whether he is being

looked at at any one moment; but he must be sure that he may always

be so.  (A HREF="bibliog.html#f" Foucault 201/A)BR



/BLOCKQUOTE



P

CENTER[A HREF="top.html"top/A] . [A HREF="index.html"index/A] . [back] . 
[next]

BR

/CENTER

/BODY



/HTML


--3F40D9C32E2--







[PEN-L:1746] Re: Re: Re: prison privatization

1998-12-19 Thread Ken Hanly

Jim Devine wrote:
 
 Ken Hanly writes:
 (begin comment) I haven't read the article. Does it mention Bentham's
 panopticon and Benthams plans to reform prisons ?
 
 no, there is little historical background prior to 1964 or so (except for a
 short sketch of the 19th century US pro-penitentiary movement and
 Toqueville's comments on it). It's almost all about the growth of both the
 public and private prison industry.
 
  He planned the prison
 building so that the public could come in and watch to see that the
 prisoner's weren't slacking, and also that the prisoners were not being
 abused by the wardens.
 
 I guess I was mistaken. I thought that the Panopticon was about minimizing
 the effort of the guards: being in the center of a circle of cells, the
 guards can watch them all simultaneously.
 

COMMENT: I haven't the material at hand but there seems no contradiction 
between what you say and I say, both may be accomodated within the plan.
It seems to me that pubic viewing was from an upper level that looked out 
over the main floor of the prison but I stand to be corrected on this.

Bentham's 'reform' proposals also would solve the problem of the
 homeless and the unemployed . He argued that indigents and all those
 without visible means of support probably lived through illegal
 activitiy. How else could they meet their needs? These people should be
 rounded up and put in the panopticons where they would perform useful
 labor, have a roof over their heads, clothing and food, and eventually
 save enough from their wages to be let go.
This would seem to be the next logical step for prison reform in
 the twentieth century. There are all these street people and the homeless
 who are under-exploited in the system.
 
 Schlosser argues that the prison system is already overcrowded, so that
 this program would be ridiculous.
COMMENT: I meant the program to be ridiculous but not for the reason 
that the prison system is overcrowded. THe solution to overcrowding is to 
build more and more prisons. Indeed these reforms would be intended to 
generate a growth industry . I am sure those investing in the 
Prison-Industrial complex would find nothing ridiculous about that. The 
proposals  are ridiculous in their cavalier disregard for human rights 
and their exploitation of those most disadvantaged in society. However, 
it seems
this is no longer regarded as ridiculous. It is difficult to write satire 
on the prison system.  Why don't you repost your satire? I don't recall 
seeing it.

Cheers, Ken Hanly






[PEN-L:1745] Re: Re: Incorrect Model of Language in TRACTATUS ( Was RE ADNAUSEAM_

1998-12-19 Thread Ken Hanly

Ajit Sinha wrote:
The story I have heard is that the picture theory of meaning was 
suggested to Wittgenstein by the manner in which an auto-accident was 
modeled by counters in a courtroom so that judge and jury could see 
exactly how one car collided with another. This is repeated as an example 
under the entry "picture theory of meaning" in THE OXFORD COMPANION TO 
PHILOSOPHY. I think I have seen the same story in J. Urmson's 
INTRODUCTION TO PHILOSOPHICAL ANALYSIS (I think that is the title). I 
recall little of Saussure. It seems to me he thought that the elements 
of spoken language were to be understood only within the linguistic 
system, and this certainly contradicts the view of proper names that 
authors such as Russell and Wittgenstein had at the time of the 
Tractatus. In the Investigations his approach in general  is closer to 
the Saussure's thought. 
Wittgenstein seems to be rather critical of the Sapir-Whorf hypothesis in 
the INVESTIGATIONS but sometimes he is interpreted as partially 
supporting it. As I recall he has a passage that goes somewhat as 
follows. (I haven't THE INVESTIGATIONS) at hand.
In Russian ( some language) the English statement that the sky is 
blue would be translated by an active present tense verb. The English 
equivalent would roughly be "it blues". He asks himself something like 
this: "Do the Russians then see the blue sky differently? " If the 
Sapir-Whorf hypothesis were true they would, perception would be 
determined by language forms. Wittgenstein suggests that this difference 
alone is not sufficient to conclude this. WHat you could conclude is that 
there will be a contrast possible in English that is not possible in
Russian. An English writer might write "The sky blues." THis would have a 
certain effect through the contrast with the ordinary "is blue". 
Translating this into Russian would lose the effect since there is no 
contrast there since there is no simple predication equivalent to "is 
blue" only the active present tense verb. (My apologies to any Russians 
if I have the wrong language!)
The Investigations is often thought of as in some ways akin to 
behaviorism since Wittgenstein denies that terms referring to inner 
events are to be understood by attending to a private referent. e.g. the 
term "pain" means the private inner event that only I experience. Terms 
referring to inner events require what he calls external criteria of 
their application. Taking terms such as "pain" as meaning these private 
events leads to the problem of other minds and if correct would make
communication with others impossible. Gilbert Ryle's CONCEPT OF MIND is a 
classic refutation of Cartesian dualism and the idea of the self as some 
non-material substance, thoughts as non-material, non-extended etc. Ryle 
gives credit to WIttgenstein as the source of his approach. However, one 
of the reasons WIttgenstein wanted to get the Investigations published 
was to show people what he really thought! Even so, the Investigations do 
have many passages that would support Ryle's approach. However others 
are wholly contradictory to Ryle and any sort of behaviorism. He says at 
one point: Are you saying that there is no difference between pain and 
pain behavior? He answers that of course there is. This is hardly what a 
hard-line metaphysical behaviorist would say--although it is consistent 
with methodological behaviorism such as that of Skinner- as contrasted 
with Watson.
While Wittgenstein is no behaviorist he would no doubt reject
the Chomskian view that there are innate ideas. By the way Norman Malcolm
's Memoir on WIttgenstein is an interesting contrast to Von Wright's. The 
latter is much more objective, while Malcolm is an unabashed disciple. 
Malcolm himself is an  eminent philosopher and well worth reading. An 
interesting short readable work is "Dreaming" or perhaps it is "On 
Dreaming". He seems to think that there is a great difference between 
dreams and nightmares--i.e. where you actually wake up scared shitless 
etc. He has no sympathy with those who define dreaming in terms of 
periods of REM sleep etc. Many psychologists would probably like to burn 
the book!
Cheers, Ken Hanly

PS THe person interviewed on the CBC newsmagazine was Edward Peck. He 
was ambassador to Iraq during the early seventies. The family resemblance 
to Edward Said mislead me. All Edwards are not alike. 
 
 At 18:37 14/12/98 -0800, Ken Hanly wrote:
 P.P.S. (post post script) Wittgenstein himself noted his pupils tended to
 defer to his genius. He was such an intense, sincere person that students
 were simply overwhelmed and as a result were neither critical of him nor
 capable of independent thought while under his sway. Wittgenstein always
 admired G.E.Moore who didn't have a clue what Wittgenstein was talking
 about very often, but would tell Wittgenstein so. He sat in his classes
 with a puzzled look on his face, not the look of adoration he saw 

[PEN-L:1742] Re: Re: Re: prison privatization

1998-12-19 Thread michael perelman

Bentham's panopticon was based on designs actually used by his brother for
workers in shipyards.

Michael Perelman






[PEN-L:1739] Re: Re: prison privatization

1998-12-19 Thread Jim Devine

Ken Hanly writes: 
(begin comment) I haven't read the article. Does it mention Bentham's 
panopticon and Benthams plans to reform prisons ?

no, there is little historical background prior to 1964 or so (except for a
short sketch of the 19th century US pro-penitentiary movement and
Toqueville's comments on it). It's almost all about the growth of both the
public and private prison industry.

 He planned the prison 
building so that the public could come in and watch to see that the 
prisoner's weren't slacking, and also that the prisoners were not being 
abused by the wardens. 

I guess I was mistaken. I thought that the Panopticon was about minimizing
the effort of the guards: being in the center of a circle of cells, the
guards can watch them all simultaneously.

   Bentham's 'reform' proposals also would solve the problem of the 
homeless and the unemployed . He argued that indigents and all those 
without visible means of support probably lived through illegal 
activitiy. How else could they meet their needs? These people should be 
rounded up and put in the panopticons where they would perform useful 
labor, have a roof over their heads, clothing and food, and eventually 
save enough from their wages to be let go.
   This would seem to be the next logical step for prison reform in 
the twentieth century. There are all these street people and the homeless 
who are under-exploited in the system. 

Schlosser argues that the prison system is already overcrowded, so that
this program would be ridiculous.


Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
http://clawww.lmu.edu/Faculty/JDevine/JDevine.html






[PEN-L:1738] Re: Social Democracy and Utopia

1998-12-19 Thread Brad De Long

It's certainly the case that worker-managed firms don't lay off their
members in downturns (very much). But--at least the last time I talked to
Laura Tyson about this--she did say that it really seemed true that
worker-managed firms had a very difficult time expanding in response to
increased demand. But I don't know nearly as much about this as I should...


Brad DeLong






[PEN-L:1736] Stampeding bison?199812171533.BAA06772@elf.brisnet.org.au

1998-12-19 Thread Louis Proyect

Today's NY Times has an article titled "People Can't Agree on What's
Natural and What's Not," by Timothy Egan that repeats an often-heard
accusation against the American Indian, namely that they were just as
"wasteful" of natural resources as the Europeans. Egan writes:

"A hundred years ago, after the Americans had wiped out most of the
bounteous bison of the West and removed the native people who had lived on
those animals, there came a great die-out of domestic cattle. A long,
bitter winter left cowboys without cows, and the Indians saying, 'Told you
so.' It was, many people still believe, nature's blow against the attempt
to erase much of the native West. 

"But what about the Great Plains tribes, who used to start big grass fires
to drive bison off a cliff? By some estimates, up to 90 percent of a herd
was wasted. It may have been natural or simply crafty and wasteful, no
different from Roman excess."

Well, what about those Great Plains tribes? If you look at the chapter on
"The Prairie-Plains" in Alice Kehoe's "North American Indians: A
Comprehensive Account," you will find reference to bison being corralled,
not being stampeded off cliffs. John C. Ewers was Senior Ethnologist at the
Smithsonian Institution and an expert on Plains Indians. In his "The
Blackfeet: Raiders of the Northwestern Plains," there is an account from an
elder named Old Weasel Tail of how the Blackfoot hunted bison prior to the
introduction of the horse into their society:

"Near the edge of timber and toward the bottom of a downhill slope the
Indians built a corral of wooden posts set upright in the ground to a
height of about seven feet. They connected the posts by crosspoles tied in
place with rawhide ropes. Around three sides of the corral they laid stakes
over the lowest crosspoles. Their butt ends were firmly braced in the
ground outside the corral. These stakes projected about three feet or more
inside the corral at an angle, so that their sharpened ends were about the
height of a buffalo's body. If the buffalo tried to break through the
corral, after they had been driven into it, they would be impaled on these
stakes. From the open side of the corral the fence of poles extended in two
wings outward and up the hill. These lines were further extended by piles
of cut willows in the shape of conical lodges about half the height of a
man, tied together at their tops. These brush piles were spaced at
intervals of several feet. On the hill just above the corral opening a
number of poles were placed on the ground crosswise of the slope and
parallel to each other. The buffalo had to cross these poles to enter the
corral. The poles were covered with manure and water, which froze and
became slippery so that once the buffalo were in the corral they couldn't
escape by climbing back up the hill.

"Before the drive began a beaver bundle owner removed the sacred buffalo
stones from his bundle and prayed. He sang a song, 'Give me one buffalo or
more. Help me to fall the buffalo.'

"Then men of the camp [probably swift-footed, long-winded young fellows]
were sent out to get behind a herd of buffalo and drive it toward the
corral. Another man stood at the top of the hill and gave a signal to the
women and children, who were hiding behind the brush piles, that the
buffalo were coming. As the animals passed them on their way down the slope
the women and children ran out of their hiding places.

"Once inside the corral the buffalo were killed by men and boys stationed
around the outside of the stout fence. Then the camp chief went into the
corral to take charge of the butchering and the division of the meat. While
butchering, the people ate buffalo liver, kidneys, and slices of brisket
raw. Two young men took choice pieces of liver, kidneys, liver, brisket,
tripe, and manifold to the beaver bundle owner  who had remained in his
lodge during the slaughter, but whose power had brought success in the
hunt. Each man who killed a buffalo was given its hide and ribs. The
slaughtered animals were cut into quarters which were divided among the
families in the camp. Each family, whether it was large or small, received
an equal share."

In other words, the bison hunt was not a wanton destruction of wildlife,
but a calculated effort to supply the basic needs of the village.
Furthermore, NOT A SINGLE piece of the bison went to waste. The other thing
to understand is that the great risks were involved. If a hunt was not
successful, people might starve. The bison might detect the scent of the
hunter or an unusual sound might frighten them away. Blackfoot tales
include numerous references to repeated failures to get the animal into the
corral. There are none that recount driving them off a cliff, which I have
a feeling is a projection of our own wasteful practices on indigenous society.

This NY Times article, which is actually a discussion of a book written by
a British social theorist who wants to apologize for European control over
the world and the 

[PEN-L:1733] Re: prison privatization

1998-12-19 Thread Ken Hanly

Jim Devine wrote:
(begin comment) I haven't read the article. Does it mention Bentham's 
panopticon and Benthams plans to reform prisons ? He planned the prison 
building so that the public could come in and watch to see that the 
prisoner's weren't slacking, and also that the prisoners were not being 
abused by the wardens. This is a refreshing contrast with modern day 
prisons that prefer to hide what goes on in prisons from public view.
 The prisons were privatised and to be managed by Bentham for his profit. 
Bentham spent a lot of money pushing his plan to no avail. His failure to 
impress authorities probably hastened the development of Bentham's 
democratic sympathies and caused him to push for the extension of the 
franchise. He no doubt thought that the public would elect people more 
intelligent and thus sympathetic to his reforms. Eventually parliament 
compensated him for money he had spent. 
Bentham's 'reform' proposals also would solve the problem of the 
homeless and the unemployed . He argued that indigents and all those 
without visible means of support probably lived through illegal 
activitiy. How else could they meet their needs? These people should be 
rounded up and put in the panopticons where they would perform useful 
labor, have a roof over their heads, clothing and food, and eventually 
save enough from their wages to be let go.
This would seem to be the next logical step for prison reform in 
the twentieth century. There are all these street people and the homeless 
who are under-exploited in the system. Bentham's proposal would rectify 
this and also lead to the greatest happiness of the greatest number!
Some people might complain that the rights of the homeless are violated 
by these proposals. This objection could be met by recriminalizing 
vagrancy. This would add some expense to the system but if we find that
the public is willing to pay this extra amount for the satisfaction of 
knowing that all those in panopticon have been found guilty of crimes 
this should be in accord with the principles of welfare economics.
(end comment)
Cheers, Ken Hanly 
 Reading the excellent article in the December 1998 ATLANTIC MONTHLY about
 the prison-industrial complex (by Eric Schlosser) reminded me of the
 satirical article I posted to pen-l 4 or 5 years ago. Almost all of my
 satire seems to have come true.
 
 There's a discussion of for-profit prison corruption that is interesting.
 Privatizing a prison (making its managment profit-seeking, creating what
 Brad might call a "free marketplace of prisoners") doesn't end the need for
 the government to supervise them. (Mostly, it allows cost-cutting by
 bringing in non-union labor, cutting corners, etc., allowing the owners to
 pay their CEOs princely salaries.) Noticeable in Schlosser's story is that
 the kind of corruption changes.  If a privatized prison's management breaks
 the rules of the contract (or the laws), it creates the incentive to bribe
 the government regulators in one way or another (typically by hiring them
 as consultants). On the other hand, if a government-owned prison's
 management does this, they have fewer resources for such bribes. So we see
 "you scratch my back and I'll scratch yours" type corruption, which is
 common in all bureaucracies, allowing the persistance of problems. What's
 noticeable is that the privatized version leads to much greater income
 disparities. This parallels the situation in the US class system (which
 promotes income disparities) and the USSR class system (which had very
 limited disparities).
 
 any thoughts?
 
 Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
 http://clawww.lmu.edu/Faculty/JDevine/jdevine.html






[PEN-L:1734] Re: Walrasian versus Austrian (Hayekian) Neoclassical Economics

1998-12-19 Thread Mathew Forstater

Yes, I think there are very significant differences and that in some
formulations Austrian economics should not even be called neoclassical
probably.  Some, because there are some big differences within Austrian
economics itself. Lots of people unfortunately miss the differences between
Austrian and neoclassical because the two arrive at similar conclusions on
certain issues, e.g. pro-market, anti-state intervention, but they arrive at
those conclusions very differently. The Austrian route is a greater
theoretical accomplishment in my view because while neoclassical economics
arrives at its concusions often because of very unrealistic assumptions, the
Austrians vigorously reject assumptions like perfect information, perfect
competition, etc., yet they still argue that markets lead to "spontaneous
order." It's much harder to derive spontaneous market order with radical
uncertainty than with perfect information.  I think the Austrian conclusion
has problems, but it is certainly a bold project.  And the Austrian critiques
of neoclassical economics have much in common with some radical critiques,
while the Austrian methodological critiques also present a challenge to some
radical theories that depart from neoclassical economics on substance but not
on methodology.

Mat

Ken Hanly wrote:

 Aren't there significant differences between neoclassicals who
 stress Walras and the Pareto optimality (efficiency) of ideal markets
 versus the Austrian neo-classicals?






[PEN-L:1730] RE: Re: Re: Re: Re: Social Democracy and Utopia

1998-12-19 Thread Max Sawicky


 . . . 
 There is the problem that successful worker-managed firms tend to want to
 not hire new workers . . .

This is well-taken, but you have to admit that on the
scale of grand systemic problems, it does not rank too
high.  The state can essay macro and micro remedies
for this.  We're a long way from the waste that
follows from commandist planning, laissez-faire,
or muddling liberalism.

muddling along,

mbs






[PEN-L:1729] The bombing of Iraq

1998-12-19 Thread Frank Durgin



   
   WSWS : News  Analysis : Middle East : Iraq

   The bombing of Iraq

   A shameful chapter in American
   history

   By Martin McLaughlin and David North
   19 December 1998

   Those who are responsible for the bombing of Iraq are
   writing a shameful chapter in American history.
   Hundreds of Iraqi men, women and children have
   already been killed or maimed by American bombs and
   cruise missiles. The death toll from the air war will
   mount far higher. Even the Pentagon had predicted more
   than 10,000 would be killed in an onslaught of only
   medium intensity, let alone in the full-scale attack
which
   was unleashed on December 16.

   Putting aside for a moment the reactionary aims being
   pursued by the Clinton Administration, the massive
   disparity between the resources of the United States and
   those of Iraq endows a nightmarish and criminal
   character to the actions taken by the Pentagon. What is
   unfolding today in the Middle East resembles not so
   much a war as a state-sanctioned execution. But in this
   case, the victim is not an individual, strapped
helplessly
   to a gurney, but rather the unarmed population of a
   defenseless country.

   The White House, the Pentagon, the Congress, and, of
   course, the media sing hymns of praise to "our heroic
   men and women in the Persian Gulf." In reality, every
   American should feel deeply ashamed of what these
   "heroes" are being ordered to do in the name of the
United
   States. "Heroism," at a minimum, involves a serious
   element of risk and danger. "Heroes" are not those who
   are willing to kill, but who are prepared to die. On the
   basis of this definition, the people of Baghdad are far
   more deserving of respect and admiration than those who
   are tormenting them from the relative safety of their
   high-tech murder machines.

   There is nothing particularly courageous about placing
   one's finger on a button to launch a cruise missile,
while
   floating on a naval vessel in the Persian Gulf or flying
a
   B-52 bomber 1,000 miles from Baghdad.

   In 1991 American soldiers in the Persian Gulf War had a
   lower death rate than their counterparts who stayed
   home. More died of traffic accidents than from Iraqi
   weapons. During the last seven years, the risks facing
   American military personnel have been even further
   reduced. US weaponry has been upgraded and Iraq's
   defenses have been virtually destroyed. Moreover,
   American pilots are guided to their targets by
intelligence
   provided by UN weapons inspectors and spy satellites
   which have scoured the Iraqi landscape continuously for
   the past eight years.

   As for the commanders who are in charge of this sordid
   operation, history will judge them in much the same way
   as it does the scoundrels who supervised the genocidal
   slaughter of the Indians in the 1870s and 1880s. This
   much is certain: 50 years from now no one will be
   making films like Patton, The Longest Day or Saving Pvt.
   Ryan about their exploits.

   One need not agree with the politics of such World War
   II-era commanders as Eisenhower, Bradley, Patton, and
   Nimitz to acknowledge that they, at least, led their
armies
   against an enemy fully capable of firing back. Today's
   generals are nothing more than bureaucrats of mass
   slaughter, working their way up the Pentagon hierarchy,
   spending a term at the top issuing orders to destroy
   helpless populations, then retiring to well-paid
positions
   on corporate boards or as "consultants" to the TV
   networks covering the next American blitzkrieg.

   The horrors of World War II evoked searing images that
   profoundly influenced the political consciences of
several
   generations. Next to those produced by the opening of
the