[PEN-L:10473] MAI Y2K

1999-08-30 Thread Michael Eisenscher



Date: Sat, 07 Aug 1999 12:33:31 -0700
Resent-from: Patrick Kerans [EMAIL PROTECTED]
From: Candice Mitchell - General Manager [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  (by way of Connie Fogal [EMAIL PROTECTED])
Subject: Y2KMAI

Hello Connie,

It was a pleasure chatting with you...Here are some interesting links that
definately point to a Global Free Trade Agreement  (MAI) being put in place
during Y2K disruptions.

This site is the Pentagon Think tankhave a look at who was and is involved
with the think-tank and the "M" curve.  When I first came across this site I
was blown away, so I called Dr. Thomas Barnett and had a lengthly conversation
with him regarding the info he was presenting.  I sent a copy of this site to
all the members of the House of Commons about 3 months ago
http://www.geocities.com/ResearchTriangle/Thinktank/6926/y2kproj.htmhttp:
//www.geocities.com/ResearchTriangle/Thinktank/6926/y2kproj.htm

This is the official World Bank Y2K web-site, talks about the vulnerabilty of
developing nations and Y2K
http://www.worldbank.org/y2k/pages/english/elinks.htmhttp://www.worldbank
..org/y2k/pages/english/elinks.htm

The site below is interesting because it is based in Washington DC and the
Head
of the Advisory Committee is Sen. Robert Bennett who is also the head of
the US
Senate Committee on the Year 2000
http://www.y2kcenter.org/http://www.y2kcenter.org/

This is the CIA map of the world and the Y2K risks
http://www.msnbc.com/modules/Y2KInternational/map_nestframe.asphttp://www
..msnbc.com/modules/Y2KInternational/map_nestframe.asp

The United Nations Working Group, also discusses the vulnerability of
developing nations.
http://www.un.org/members/y2k/y2k2nd/http://www.un.org/members/y2k/y2k2nd/

This is the state of California info site the matrix pretty well describes
what kind of disruptions may happen
http://www.oes.ca.gov/oeshomep.nsfhttp://www.oes.ca.gov/oeshomep.nsf

This statement is from the December 1998 Auditors General Report on the Year
2000.

20.117 Embedded systems and devices are emerging as a significant concern.
Numbering in the billions, they perform a vast range of duties serving many
domains such as science, engineering, manufacturing and health care. Experts
have estimated that only a small percentage of these micro processors are
date-sensitive. Even so, an estimated 20 million to 250 million could fail
as a
result of the millennium bug.
http://www.oag-bvg.gc.ca/domino/reports.nsf/html/9820ce.htmlhttp://www.oa
g-bvg.gc.ca/domino/reports.nsf/html/9820ce.html

I will have the Bio to you over the Weekend and  Y2Kit has been put in the
mail
to your office.

Our Web-site is   http://www.homecheck.netwww.homecheck.net

Candice Mitchell
General Manager
SKF Millennium Sales Inc.
250-833-1970 work
250-832-7492 home


.
Bob Olsen, Toronto  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
.






[PEN-L:10470] Co-optation and Heterodoxy

1999-08-30 Thread Craven, Jim

I read a book this weekend that many may have read but I do recommend it:
"The Conquest of Cool: Business Culture, Counterculture, and the Rise of Hip
Consumerism" by Thomas Frank, U of Chicago Press, Chicago and London, 1995.

I was taken by two passages:

   "This book is a study of co-optation rather than counterculture, an
analysis of the forces and logic that made rebel youth cultures so
attractive to corporate decision-makers rather than a study of those
cultures themselves. In doing so, it risks running afoul of what I will call
the co-optation theory: faith in the revolutionary potential of 'authentic'
counterculture combined with the notion that business mimics and
mass-produces fake counterculture in order to cash in on a particular
demographic and to subvert the great threat that 'real' counterculture
represents. 'Who Built America?', the text book produced by the Social
History project, includes a reproduction of the now-infamous '[The]Man Can't
Bust Our Music' ad and this caption summary of co-optation theory: 'If you
can't beat' em, absorb' em.' (p. 7)

and:

"...it was and remains difficult to distinguish precisely between authentic
counterculture and fake: by almost every account, the counter-culture, as a
mass movement distinct from the bohemias that preceded it, was triggered at
least as much by developments in mass culture (particularly the arrival of
the Beatles in 1964) as changes at the grass roots. Its heroes were rock
stars and rebel celebrities, millionaire performers and employees of the
culture industry; its greatest moments occurred on television, on the radio,
at rock concerts, and in movies. From a distance of thirty years, its
language and music seem anything but the authentic populist culture they
yearned so desperately to be: from contived cursing to saitly communalism to
the embarrassingly faked Woody Guthrie accents of Bob Dylan to the
astoundingly pretentious works of groups like Iron Butterfly and The Doors,
the relics of the counterculture reek of affectation and phoniness, the
leisure-dreams of white suburban children like those who made up so much of
the Grateful Dead's audience throughout the 1970s and 1980s." (p.8)

So I wondered about the application of this dialectical model (what is
counterculture vs "mainstream" culture; fake counterculture vs "real"
counterculture; influence of counterculture on "mainstream" culture vs de
facto co-optation of counter-culture by "mainstream" culture nominally
passed off as increasing acceptance of aspects of "counterculture" within
"mainstream" culture; etc ass applied to "Heterodox" versus "Orthodox"
Economics. 

Real versus Fake Heterodoxy?; What does Heterodoxy really mean and what
distinguishes a genuinely Heterodox approach from a Fake Heterodox approach
or from an "Orthodox" approach? Why the use of "Heterodox instead of
"Radical" or is Heterodoxy indeed synonomous with "Radical" or
Radical-Left"?
How much of Heterodoxy has been co-opted by the so-called "Orthodoxy" in
order that the Heterodox might operate in some of the same "permissible" and
"acceptable" media dominated by Orthodoxy? How much of Orthodoxy has been
really challenged or co-opted by the Heterodox? How much of Heterodoxy is a
co-opted caricature--of the caricatures of Radical Left held and spread by
the Orthodoxy? How much of Heterodoxy is based on caricatures of the
Orthodoxy? 

These were some of the questions that crossed my mind. I see all sorts of
academic programs now openly proclaiming "heterodox" approaches available
(after a thorough grounding in the orthodox) but I wonder if this is not
simply analogous to the synthetic counterculture that is in reality neither
"counter" or any kind of real sub or separate culture from the dominant
culture of crass eogism, materialism, competition, racism, sexism, etc. Sort
of like the fake Ken Kesey bus that tours the US for Coca Cola's "Fruitopia"
drink line?

Just some random musings.

Jim C


James Craven
Clark College, 1800 E. McLoughlin Blvd.
Vancouver, WA. 98663
(360) 992-2283; Fax: (360) 992-2863
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
http://www.home.earthlink.net/~blkfoot5
*My Employer Has No Association With My Private/Protected
Opinion*






[PEN-L:10469] Re: Re: Re: Re: FWD: Re: Baker on IP

1999-08-30 Thread Jim Devine

Eugene writes:

My point was different.  I'm arguing that without product differentiation
(or a "barrier to entry", which Jim addresses separately) -- there can't BE
any profits.  In other words, for an industry with large overhead costs,
there can't be economic efficiency without some sort of "cooperation"
(collusion) on production. 


I missed the assumption that the industry had large overhead costs. See
below for an explanation of that assumption. 

BTW, I was never concerned with the issue of "economic efficiency" in this
thread, since for capitalist enterprises, "minimum cost" operations means
not _true_ economic efficiency but instead "minimum _private_ cost"
operations, which can mean high external costs (e.g. pollution). That's
inefficient. 


 It isn't a question, in my view, of "appropriating" profits.  If there is
textbook competition -- which I think is the "cutthroat competition" which
even Alfred Marshall deplored ... if there is that kind of competition (and
without cooperation) then prices are driven below average costs and hence
zero profits.  (Even "normal profits" can't be earned.)  Then, the story
goes, firms will leave the industry.  Of course then we are into Joan
Robinson's "leets". 


This makes sense given the assumption of large overhead costs. 

I don't see why leaving the industry gets us into issues of "leets."
Typically, the losers/leavers end up selling off their capacity at prices
below what they paid. But see my comment at the end. 


In the airline industry, after deregulation, there was entry, excess
capacity, and numerous bankruptcies.  (Pan Am, Eastern, People's,
Continental, Braniff, TWA, etc. etc.  some went bankrupt twice.)  But
capacity did NOT leave the industry.  The bankrupt airlines kept flying,
and adding to the problem by cutting prices to get some contribution to
overhead costs. 


This is partly the result of the nature of US bankruptcy laws. 

BTW, this seems a lot like the kind of problem that Brenner talks about in
his ECONOMICS OF GLOBAL TURBULENCE, i.e., excessive capacity that doesn't
go away. (The relevant theory part is at the beginning, in ch. 1.)


 It isn't just "Price setting power."  I argue that price discrimination
is necessary for existence.  The airlines MUST gouge the business customers
-- i. e. charge above (way above) average cost to get the revenue to be
profitable.  And then, they pick up additional revenue above marginal cost
by pricing leisure fares for whatever they will bring.  And then, they sell
"distressed merchandise" on the internet.  This isn't price setting power,
per se, but pricing that is required if you have the cost structure of the
airlines. ...


It makes sense to me that given large overhead costs (relative to the
total), cutthroat competition pushes individual firms to do all sorts of
things, including cheating a little on safety standards now and then. [As
some hairy old German guy wrote, "Free competition brings out the inherent
laws of capitalist production, in the shape of external coercive laws
having power over every individual capitalist."] I tell my students that
the CAB (which regulated airline prices, acting as a government-sponsored
cartel) and the FAA (which, among other things, regulates safety) were
_complementary_. Protection from vicious competitive pressures gives
individual firms "monopoly rents" that allow them to more easily live up to
FAA standards. With "deregulation" (the abolition of the CAB), the FAA's
job got much harder. Thus, Value-Jet and similar disasters. Does this make
sense to you, Eugene? 


Why do universities discriminate so severely among their customers?  They
price for survival because they face large overhead costs.  They gouge with
very high tuition, then fill the seats with discounted prices.
Universities call the discounted tickets "student aid" but it is just
discounted seats.  They are non-profits -- so where are the monoploy
profits? They don't price in a discriminatory way to get "profits" but
rather to survive.  The only way to get total costs covered is to charge
some more than average costs and some less -- but more than MC.  If they
set all prices at Average cost they wouldn't get enough students to cover
total costs. 


Universities, to my mind, have differentiated products but are very
competitive. The differentiated products gives them a little bit of
monopoly and price-setting power (and the ability to price-discriminate).
(By the way, it's hard to imagine universities being anything but
differentiated. You can't have two places with identical faculties.) But
the inter-firm competition means that they can't get "above-normal"
profits. It's a little like monopolistic competition, except that the
universities are not-for-profit, so that no "normal" profits are earned,
either. Why are universities non-profit? It seems that running a for-profit
university (like one of Chris Whittle's for-profit schools) only is
workable as long as _all_ universities are 

[PEN-L:10468] labor day

1999-08-30 Thread Jim Devine

 Monday, August 30, 1999 

 Commentary 

 Missing in Action: Media Images of Real Workers 

 By MATT WITT, Special to the Baltimore Sun

 As the Labor Day weekend approaches, we will see advertisements
 for back-to-school sales, reports on holiday traffic deaths and
 recipes for backyard barbecues. 
 
 What we won't see is much reporting on the lives of people who labor
 in the nation's offices, factories and service industries. There isn't much
 coverage of how jobs are changing in America or of the growing gap in
 wealth between those who do the work and those who profit from it. 

 Issues of work and class are largely invisible, not just on Labor Day
 but year-round. Rarely do we see stories exploring important questions
 facing working families. For example: 

 * Why is the average entry-level wage at least one-fifth less than it
 was 20 years ago, with starting pay declining even for new college
 graduates? 

 * What business strategies are leading the shift to "contingent"
 labor--the part-time, temporary or subcontracted jobs that make up 30%
 of the work force? 

 * What has forced the average married couple to work 326 more
 hours a year than 20 years ago to maintain its buying power? 

 A study by Fairness and Accuracy in Reporting, a liberal
 media-watchdog group, found that the evening news programs of CBS,
 ABC and NBC recently devoted only 2% of their total air time to
 workers' issues, including child care, the minimum wage, and workplace
 safety and health. 

 During a full year, the broadcasts reportedly spent a total of 13
 minutes on job safety and health, while an average of more than 16
 workers die daily from work-related injuries and more than 650,000
 annually suffer back, wrist or other injuries from poorly designed
 workstations and repetitive motion. 

 Although local television news shows are full of "how-to" consumer
 stories--how to find good eyeglasses, how to choose a baby-sitter, how to
 stay fit--they rarely give advice on problems at work. 

 Not only are work-related topics missing in the media, but so are
 workers. Studies of ABC's "Nightline" and PBS' "NewsHour With Jim
 Lehrer" found that almost all guests were corporate or government
 officials, politicians or professors, while fewer than 1% were non-elite
 workers or their representatives. A general examination of news reports
 in the New York Times and the Washington Post (or the Los Angeles
 Times) finds few sources who are workers or union representatives. 

 ABC reporter Sam Donaldson was candid in a magazine interview
 about the media's practice of turning mainly to the corporate and political
 elite for on-camera comment. "You can't come to me and say, 'Sam, I
 know you're on deadline, you need a comment on such and such, go out
 and take a chance on Mr. X.' No, I'm sorry, folks, I don't have time to
 take a chance on Mr. X." 

 Working people are also nearly invisible in television entertainment
 programming. Heads of households were working-class characters in only
 11% of prime-time network family series from 1946 to 1990, according to
 a study by Rider University professor Richard Butsch. 

 When working-class characters are shown, they often are portrayed
 as "dumb, immature, irresponsible or lacking in common sense," Butsch
 noted, referring to shows such as "The Honeymooners," "The Flintstones,"
 "All in the Family" and "The Simpsons." 

 Public television doesn't do much better, according to a study of two
 years of PBS prime-time programming by City University of New York's
 Committee for Cultural Studies. Only about one hour a month dealt with
 the lives and concerns of workers, while nearly 10 times that much time
 was spent on the upper classes. 

 A number of factors contribute to media bias on labor issues. 
 One is that the news media are owned by big corporations, with strong
 interests and opinions. NBC, for example, which might be expected to
 inform working people about international trade agreements that make it
 easier for U.S. corporations to exploit foreign workers in cheap-labor
 havens such as Mexico, is owned by General Electric--one of the
 companies practicing such exploitation. 

 A second factor is the influence of advertisers, who insist on a
 "positive environment" for their ads--meaning one free of controversial
 issues or opinions that clash with their corporate agendas. 

 A third is the class background of editors, producers and others who
 make decisions about media coverage. Many live like corporate officials
 and have little contact with working people. A Los Angeles Times survey
 found that 54% of newspaper editors said they generally took business'
 side in disputes with workers, while only 7% generally sided with
 employees--a contrast with polls that show most Americans generally side
 with workers. 

 A fourth consideration is that working people usually do not have the
 time, money or training to compete with corporate media-relations
 operations. Union workers 

Re: request for information

1999-08-30 Thread Colin Danby

here's another set of replies for Mitchell.


1. Especially in introductory classes, how do you balance conveying 
information and helping students to think critically?

A central purpose of intro classes is to teach 
skills, which lie between these things.  
Conveying information in the sense of simple 
facts - the Battle of Adowa was fought in 1898
 - is one of the the least important things a 
college teacher can do.  On the other hand 
critical thinking relies on the ability to 
think systematically - in coherent logical 
structures of concepts.  You normally have to 
teach that first.  

It might also be noted that most students in 
100-level courses, and even higher up, think of 
knowledge as unitary - there are right things 
and wrong things and we teach only the right 
things which all fit together nicely.  This is 
not their fault - this is an idea of knowledge
that's been used to establish pedagogical 
authority for their entire schooling up to that 
point.  Working them toward a more critical 
position is not easy, and many turn resistant 
if you try it too abruptly.  Critique, ideally, 
should emerge out of understanding.

2. How do you evaluate the development of your students as critical 
thinkers?

Writing.  In general I look for ability to 
grasp the internal logic of a position and 
develop critique from that.

3. How important is it to you that classes be structured democratically?

This is a bit like asking a wage-laborer how 
important it is that firms be worker-owned.  
A fine idea, but generally out of the reach of 
individual initiative.  (Of course you might
reply that the real parallel is asking a
*boss* this question, and teachers just like
power.  But note that even your own questions
e.g. "how do you evaluate ..." assume 
hierarchy.)

In any case, as a teacher I'm inserted in an 
authoritarian structure which is pretty firmly 
rooted in students' own minds.  As another pen-l 
respondent noted, when you try to be more 
relaxed a lot of students stop working, which 
pushes you back into a more parental role.

A thoroughgoing shift in student and 
institutional culture, as Evergreen has tried, 
may be able to change this.  But otherwise 
it's a great example of how structure 
constrains.

4. How much freedom do you have to plan your own syllabus, or to alter
your syllabus so as to better meet the needs of students?

Large pedagogical freedom and quite substantial 
content freedom.  In more traditional econ 
programs there is an expectation that certain 
material will be covered, e.g. if you're 
teaching intro micro you of course do 
neoclassical consumer and firm theory (if for 
no other reason than that your students will be 
hurt in upper-level courses if they've never 
seen this stuff).  But even when I've taught at 
fairly traditional places other faculty have not 
really given a monkey's what I did in class - 
not so much out of tolerance, but because they 
know that 90% of what is taught in most classes 
is quickly forgotten.  

5. What relationship do you see between academic education in economics
and 
social justice movements?

As it is now normally taught, the relation is 
surely antagonistic.  Presumably it could
be taught better.  But any reasonably-educated 
person can learn new stuff as needed.  My
undergrad work was mainly in literature and
philosophy and that served me better as an
activist than any number of econ courses 
would have.  

Finally, remember that while on the one hand
education in general is a social good and 
better educated people have, hopefully, skills 
that can contribute to movements, on the other 
hand higher education (no matter what the 
content) plays a very large role in reproducing 
class.


You might want to get in touch with the Center
for Popular Economics at UMass Amherst, which 
has presumably thought these questions through
and which may have a sunnier take on some of 
them.

Best, Colin
(Colin Danby, U. Wash., Bothell)





[PEN-L:10467] Re: Re: Re: FWD: Re: Baker on IP

1999-08-30 Thread Eugene Coyle

Jim Devine replied to my post on this thread. Jim's post was very
useful in clarifying my thoughts. But we disagree.



I wrote:
> For pharmecueticals, the problem is taken care
of by diffrentiating the
>product, through patent protection.

Jim Devine wrote:
Product differentiation isn't enough. In the textbook
"monopolistic
competition" model, there is still a tendency toward zero "economic
profits" due to entry (so that the actual profit rate moves to the
average
profit rate). As Baker notes, it's the government-guaranteed monopoly
(patent protection) that gives the pharmaceutical companies the ability
to
appropriate profits.

My point was different. I'm arguing that without product
differentiation (or a "barrier to entry", which Jim addresses separately)
-- there can't BE any profits. In other words, for an industry with
large overhead costs, there can't be economic efficiency without some sort
of "cooperation" (collusion) on production. It isn't a question,
in my view, of "appropriating" profits. If there is textbook competition
-- which I think is the "cutthroat competition" which even Alfred Marshall
deplored -- and certainly all gentlemen deplore -- if there is that
kind of competition (and without cooperation) then prices are driven below
average costs and hence zero profits. (Even "normal profits" can't
be earned.) Then, the story goes, firms will leave the industry.
Of course then we are into Joan Robinson's "leets".

 In the airline industry, after deregulation, there
was entry, excess capacity, and numerous bankruptcies. (Pan Am, Eastern,
People's, Continental, Braniff, TWA, etc. etc. some went bankrupt
twice.) But capacity did NOT leave the industry. The bankrupt
airlines kept flying, and adding to the problem by cutting prices to get
some contribution to overhead costs.

 After a while, traffic grew, planes were retired,
and now there is a shortage of capacity.
PLUS cooperation on pricing through a central computer. So prices
and profits soar. But during the excess capacity we didn't have "economic
efficiency" -- too much capacity compared to what consumers want
isn't "efficient" nor in the shortage phase do we have economic efficiency.
The point is that we never have economic efficiency in an industry with
the airlines cost structure. Nor in pharmecueticals, nor in farming,
nor in vitamins, nor in railroads, nor in ADM's line of products, nor in
 anywhere.

 It is cost structure, not "barriers to entry"
that is important. Barriers to entry is a defense in these kinds
of industries, an attempt to cope with cost structure problems that are
always present.
I wrote:

>There was an earlier thread about software -- where the MC of production
>is trivial, but the price is hundreds of dollars. Here the
>differentiation is through copyright.
Jim replied


I'd say that copyright is the basis of not only differentiation but
also of
a barrier to entry (and thus monopoly power).
What I am saying is that without monopoly power, (or cooperation/collusion
on capacity and prices) industries with these cost structures can't
exist.


>... Another out for these kinds of industries is price discrimination.
>If you can discriminate among customers, collect more than Average
Cost
>from some, you can charge less than AC from others. An obvious
example
>is the airline industry, which severly discriminates against business
>customers and then fills the seats with leisure travelers. And
then, in
>a third tier, sells distressed inventory on the internet. The
need for
>discrimination, forced by overhead costs, became clear with the
>railroads, with huge overhead costs. Price discrimination there
brought
>on regulation, actually embraced by the railroads themselve, as Gabriel
>Kolko persuasively argues. The railroads were not able to control
>themselves, to self-enforce price-fixing deals, and so turned to
>regulation to keep each other from "cutthroat competition."
Jim wrote:


Price discrimination doesn't guarantee "economic profits." Rather, it's
a
result of having price-setting power (among other things).
It isn't just "Price setting power." I argue that price discrimination
is necessary for existence. The airlines MUST gouge the business
customers -- i. e. charge above (way above) average cost to get the revenue
to be profitable. And then, they pick up additional revenue above
marginal cost by pricing leisure fares for whatever they will bring.
And then, they sell "distressed merchandise" on the internet. This
isn't price setting power, per se, but pricing that is required if you
have the cost structure of the airlines. Or universities!!!

 Why do universities discriminate so severely among
their customers? They price for survival because they face large
overhead costs. They gouge with very high tuition, then fill the
seats with discounted prices. Universities call the discounted tickets
"student aid" but it is just discounted seats. They are non-profits
-- so where are the monoploy profits? They don't price 

[PEN-L:10465] request on teaching

1999-08-30 Thread Ellen Frank

Penners,

I had replied to Mitch's questions off-list.  But
since Michael thought the questions of general interest, 
I'm forwarding my responses to the list.

Ellen Frank

1. Especially in introductory classes, how do you balance conveying 
information and helping students to think critically?

Introductory classes, in my opinion, are not fundamentally about
conveying information.  Look at an introductory textbook - all
theory, very little hard facts.  The object of an introductory economics
course is to indoctrinate, to teach a theory uncritically.  It's fairly
easy
to subvert this intent (and teach students to think critically) simply
by assigning readings that take issue with the textbook.   I use the 
Dollars and Sense readers and other materials.  

2. How do you evaluate the development of your students as critical 
thinkers?

I ask for a lot of compare and contrast papers.   I organize debates.
I also have students do an investigative project, finding out
all they can about a particular market or program and compare
the actual to the textbook ideal.


3. How important is it to you that classes be structured democratically?

I'm not sure what it means to structure a class democratically, at least
in introductory classes.  When I started teaching, I tried very hard
not to be authoritarian, to seek students input and so on, but the nature
of an introductory course is that I know alot more than the students and 
I have a much better sense of how they learn than they do.  I do try
not to lecture too much and I always stop talking immediately when
a student raises his/her hand.  I don't require students to raise their
hands, actually, and sometimes, if I have a very motivated and talkative
group of students, my classes turn into free-for-alls.  But I reserve the
right to pull rank and move on.  


4. How much freedom do you have to plan your own syllabus, or to alter
your syllabus so as to better meet the needs of students?
 
Well, nobody's standing over my shoulder telling me how to teach
and my colleagues are generally supportive of pedagogical 
experimentation.  But I work within the context of  broader
institutional and social constraints.  I need to be cognizant
of discipline boundaries, to make sure my courses
transfer to other institutions, to give grades that will be
understood by graduate institutions and so on.  

5. What relationship do you see between academic education in economics
and 
social justice movements?

I do feel there's a relationship.  I teach economics in a very
critical manner and students who take my courses are
often motivated to become involved in social justice work.
Also, education is important, even if I'm not reaching thousands
of people.   How many places are there in the US  where people
have frank on-going discussions about whether income 
distribution is just, or what justice even means in an economic
context.  While I understand that teaching is not a substitute
for social justice efforts, it's not unimportant.  I am often asked
to teach classes organized by labor groups or other activist 
groups who tell me that their members need more education 
about economics.

Best of luck with your project.  

Ellen Frank
Emmanuel College
Boston, MA








[PEN-L:10464] Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: competition vs monopoly

1999-08-30 Thread ann li

Ah yes, engineers versus  marketing departments, our Dilbert cartoon and
comic strip here does a good job with that (with all due respect to Norman
Solomon's critique of it as more PMC soma)


 Low earth orbit satellites are yet to be tested in the world of low cost
 fast high capacity - it all seems a little behind schedule already - and
 certainly they're not attracting the press they were two years ago.


I agree, but once they do get implemented, the skys will be alive with the
sound of Gates ( Julie Andrews et al ) and other corporations ( this may be
especially since LEO, because of height  and cost may be a more 'natural'
radiospectrum monopoly).


 Bypass may be a more compelling issue for haves and have-nots.
 I'm not sure whether the flag of the win95 key will become the
 (trans)national symbol yet.

 Well, it's my vote for that role - and bigger than the twin arches, too.


I'm betting on the red (van(Value-Added Network?))guard of PRC intellectual
property pirates undermining that and filling all of those panes red, and do
we trust the id # on our current chips, pentiumIII notwithstanding?


 Y2K may be a much better test,

 I haven't met a single person who reckons they have a clue how that one is
 gonna wash out - and then there's the real possibility it becomes a
 technical non-event and a whopping great sociological phenomenon (panic
 buying and panic selling etc).

well, we know about those types of 'black' day capital crises, and I am
amused by my less political acquintances beginning to hoard gold ( and food
and water and... ), Oh gosh, that sounds like Waco!


 Still not sure it bites any more deeply into MS's flesh than anybody
else's,
 though ...

You're right, it may be so diversified that there is a kind of
'sustainability' and of course there are things to step in eg MCI-Worldcom
(or is it Welt-Kom?)

Ann






[PEN-L:10462] Re: request for information

1999-08-30 Thread michael

I was dissapointed that nobody answered Mitchell until I realized how difficult
his questions were.

Mitchell Chanin wrote:

 1. Especially in introductory classes, how do you balance conveying
 information and helping students to think critically?

I am not sure how to answer this question since both go together.

 2. How do you evaluate the development of your students as critical
 thinkers?



 3. How important is it to you that classes be structured democratically?

It is impossible to do.  I tried when I started teaching, but unlike Evergreen,
our students respond to democratic opening by sluffing off on the most
democratic classes.


 4. How much freedom do you have to plan your own syllabus, or to alter
 your syllabus so as to better meet the needs of students?

I am pretty free to do what I want, just so I cover the basics.



 5. What relationship do you see between academic education in economics and
 social justice movements?

Critical thinking is important.  Also, students need to be able to see through
conventional economic arguments, while anticipating the consequences of policies
that they favor.
--
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]






[PEN-L:10466] Labor Day

1999-08-30 Thread Louis Proyect

THE CHRISTIAN SCIENCE MONITOR 

September 3, 1982, Friday, Midwestern Edition 

SECTION: Opinion and Commentary; Pg. 23 

LENGTH: 740 words 

HEADLINE: Labor Day 

BYLINE: By Thomas V. DiBacco; Thomas V. DiBacco is a historian at The
American University, Washington, D.C. 

Labor Day, begun 100 years ago, is the nation's most unusual holiday in
terms of its origin and passage through time. On the one hand, it was
initiated by workers to break up the long interval between July 4 and
Thanksgiving when there were no holidays. On the other hand, it was
supported by union laborers as a day to show the strength and solidarity of
their ranks through parades and similar demonstrations. Because the two
objectives were divergent, the holiday would fall victim to some fine points. 

To amass large numbers of union workers was a difficult, if not unrealistic
goal in America. Since colonial times labor was viewed as a temporary
status in a society with enormous opportunities. To pursue unionism was
admission that upward mobility was not possible. 

In such a social environment a Union Day would not fly, but Labor Day was
too general, the monopoly of one group: the farmer labored, as did the
merchant, physician, and clerk. And there would be far more of the latter
then there would be blue-collar workers carrying union cards. 

For these reasons the big parade that labor leaders predicted for the first
celebration in 1882 fell short of expectations. The initital national
observance in 1895 was also uneventful, except as a day of leisure: ''The
labor organizations in this city,'' read one newspaper account, ''with the
exception of the Knights of Labor who are garment makers, refrained from
parading yesterday, but observed the day by attending picnics, where they
had music, dancing, and speaking. . . .'' 

There were other developments that worked to the disadvantage of organized
labor's hopes. In the 1880s European unions moved toward adopting May 1 as
the international labor celebration. But American leaders were divided over
the matter, opting ultimately for the late summer break. And the attempt to
identify with the international day would be discredited, first by the riot
associated with the Haymarket Square bombing in Chicago in the wake of May
Day, 1886, later by the perception of European movements as too radical. 

Then came the Pullman railroad strike and boycott in the spring of 1894
which Samuel Gompers, head of the American Federation of Labor, could not
fully support. This division in organized labor's camp provided Congress
with the opportunity to take full advantage of the situation. Legislation
establishing a national Labor Day was rushed through both houses - with
unanimous votes - and signed by President Cleveland during the Pullman
crisis in June, with the immediate beneficiaries the large number of
working people who preferred the obvious (a day off) to principle (unionism). 

The gains that organized labor would make had little to do with the
activities of Labor Day. The AFL for a long time eschewed political action
and demonstration in preference to the bargaining table. Its own method of
organization along skilled lines worked against the goal of building an
army of laborers, some of whom could perceive that skill was becoming an
anachronism anyhow. 

Finally, organized labor had no Armageddon or Gettysburg to rally the
troops, and the first Monday in September just didn't quite fit the bill,
although Gompers tried to ennoble the day. ''It is regarded,'' he said in
1898, ''as the day for which the toilers in past centuries looked forward,
when their rights and their wrongs might be discussed, placed upon a higher
plane of thought and feeling; that the workers of our day may not only lay
down their tools of labor for a holiday, but upon which they may touch
shoulders in marching phalanx and feel the stronger for it; meet at their
parks, groves and grounds, and by appropriate speech, counsel with, and
pledge to, each other that the coming year shall witness greater effort
than the preceding in the grand struggle to make mankind free, true and
noble.'' 

To be sure, later in the 20th century Labor Day would give unions some
limelight from politicians in search of votes. However, after 100 years
organized labor finds its ranks dwindling (from a peak of 25 percent of the
civilian labor force to less than 20 percent percent) and its special days
not so special. May Day in America after World War II became Loyalty Day -
in opposition to communist regimes flexing their military muscle - and more
recently is observed as Law Day. 

As for Labor Day, it has come to mean for most Americans the ending of
summer and the beginning of fall. 

Copyright© 1999, LEXIS-NEXIS, a division of Reed Elsevier Inc. All Rights
Reserved. 

 


Louis Proyect

(http://www.panix.com/~lnp3/marxism.html)






[PEN-L:10459] Water

1999-08-30 Thread Louis Proyect

 . the future of one of the earth's most vital resources is being
determined by those who profit from its overuse and abuse.

Blue Gold: The Global Water Crisis and the Commodification of the World's
Water Supply

INTRODUCTION: 

"The wars of the next century will be about water." Ismail Serageldin,
vice-president of the World Bank We'd like to believe there's an infinite
supply of water on the planet. But the assumption is tragically false.
Available fresh water amounts to less than one-half of one percent of all
the water on Earth. The rest is sea water, or is frozen in the polar ice.
Fresh water is renewable only by rainfall, at the rate of 40-50,000 cubic
kilometers per year. Global consumption of water is doubling every 20
years, more than twice the rate of human population growth. According to
the United Nations, more than one billion people on earth already lack
access to fresh water. If current trends persist, by 2025 the demand for
fresh water is expected to by 56 percent more than is currently available.

The push to commodify water comes at a time when the social, political and
economic impacts of water scarcity are rapidly becoming a destabilizing
force, with water-related conflicts springing up around the globe. For
example, Maylasia, which supplies about half of Singapore's water,
threatened to cut off that supply in 1997 after Singapore criticized its
government policies. In Africa, relations between Botswana and Namibia have
been severly strained by Namibian plans to construct a pipeline to divert
water from the shared Okavango River to eastern Namibia. Much has been
written about the potential water wars in the Middle East, where water
resources are severly limited. The late King Hussein of Jordan once said
the only thing he would go to war with Israel over was water because Israel
controls Jordan's water supply.

Meanwhile, the future of one of the earth's most vital resources is being
determined by those who profit from its overuse and abuse. At the 1998
annual World Economic Development Congress, which follows the annual
International Monetary Fund/World Bank meeting, corporations and financial
institutions met with government representatives from more than 84
countries to attend panels on such subjects as "Overcoming Obstacles to
Water Investment" and " Navigating Transparency and Banking Regulation in
Emerging Capital Markets." The agenda was clear: water should be traded
like any other tradable good, with its use determined by market principles.

At the same time, governments are signing away their control over domestic
water supplies by participating in trade treaties such as North American
Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and institutions such as the World Trade
Organization (WTO). These agreements effectively give transnational
corporations the unprecedented right to the water of signatory countries.

Already, corporations have started to sue governments in order to gain
access to domestic water sources. For example, Sun Belt, a California
company, is suing the government of Canada under NAFTA because British
Columbia (B.C.) banned water exports several years ago. The company claims
that B.C.'s law violates several NAFTA-based investor rights and therefore
is claiming $220 million in compensation for lost profits.

With the protection of these international trade agreements, companies are
setting their sights on the mass transport of bulk water by diversion and
by super-tanker. Several companies are developing technology whereby large
quantities of fresh water would be loaded into huge sealed bags and towed
across the ocean for sale.

The U.S. Global Water Corporation, a Canadian company, is one of those
seeking to be a major player in the water trade. It has signed an agreement
with Sitka, Alaska, to export 18 billion gallons per year of glacier water
to China where it will be bottled in one of that country's "free trade"
zones to take advantage of cheap labour. The The company brochure entices
investors "to harvest the accelerating opportunity... as traditional
sources of water around the world become progressively depleted and degraded."

Selling water to the highest bidder will only exacerbate the worst impacts
of the world water crisis.

SOCIAL INEQUITY:

* In India, some households spend a staggering 25 percent of their incomes
on water.

* Poor residents in Lima, Peru, pay private vendors as much as $3 per cubic
meter for buckets of often-contaminated water while the more affluent pay
30 cents per cubic meter for treated municipal tap water.

* In the maquiladora zones of Mexico, water is so scarce that babies and
children drink Coca-Cola and Pepsi instead. 

DISEASE:

* More than five million people, most of them children, die every year from
illnesses caused by drinking poor quality water. Food Security:

* China is facing the likelihood of severe grain shortages because of water
depletion and the current shift of limited water resources from agriculture
to industry and 

[PEN-L:10458] Re: Re: competition vs monopoly

1999-08-30 Thread Rob Schaap

G'day Michael,

For what it's worth, I agree with you (and thus just about everybody who's
not in our parliaments) about competition.  But you're closing
quote-of-self has some implications, I think.

Remember Castells putting down the SU's implosion to an inability to keep
up in the 'information age'?  By his reasoning (if memory serves), the SU
managed to put off the inevitable precisely because of its large industrial
base and the stability it afforded.  But by the mid-eighties (a decade
after the erstwhile military-industrial convergence technologies had been
redirected to the 1st world civilian market-place), it had begun to creak
most ominously.

Today, the likes of Microsoft might be said to offer a buffer in this
sense.  The decisive question might be, can they survive stuff like the
directions in which photonics seems to be taking us (liquid-state
'instant/mega-capacity' processing, if you like)?  Have they the political
economic power to stifle this one?  Or control its diffusion?

Or does it matter at all?  Is the thing to let the temporary gales pass you
by, and just make sure you corner the market on the stuff that actually
give computers and networks their value: software and IP regimes?  That
way, the better others make the technology, the greater the cut of the
content owners.  Whilst others bend and crash before these destructive
gales, you just sit there like Jabba the Hutt, growing more inertly fat all
the while.

On that account, the likes of IBM need to worry, but Microsoft certainly
need not.  They've got so much stability they'd be advised to play to their
strengths and stay inert altogether.  Just buy up ISPs and would-be
competitors as they rear their pimpled little heads; give their software
away to new users (like a smack dealer always gives away that first hit);
and buy up every text and image that comes along.

Let's face it - this is what they're doing already.  in short:

- A commodified net,
- in concert with a Microsoft default setting on every computer,
- a US-authored but globally binding IP regime,
- and a State Department which seems to lack either (or both) the power or
inclination to compromise this gargantuan monolith,

constitutes:

- a blue sky future for Microsoft (hence the Kudlow warcry: never mind
those p/e's - borrow at 7% and buy 20% a year for life!),
- a classic dependency configuration as far as the rest of the world is
concerned, and
- an accurate description of the world today.

If any of this holds water, the thing to do is to look for likely
inhibitors to this incipient leviathan (I doubt it'll be the domestic
institutional setting, whose interests are contingent - and I don't think
mainstream economics has anything to tell us about it - but the net might
yet evince some technical shortcomings, or the rest of the world might yet
have something to say about revising IP's currently catch-all nature -
otherwise it's a matter of waiting for the implicit gross distortions to
bite in the form of underconsumption and mebbe some desperate
belligerence).  Anyway, I guess I'm suggesting even an apparently stable
(to the point of apparent omnipotence/omnipresence) monolith like this
might constitute what some of us call a 'contradictory unity'.

Yours Nostradamically,
Rob.


You'd written:

 We should also take note that this same sort of inertia that Keynes,
Galbraith, and Schumpeter advocated can prove to be dangerous when
maintained
too long, as they themselves recognized.  For example, after World War II,
many
large firms in the United States used a combination of market power and
protectionism to permit them to maintain their outdated plant and equipment,

while Europe and Japan were deploying more modern technologies.  This
strategy
allowed them to enjoy a greater degree of stability, at least in the short
run,
but it eventually left these same firms vulnerable to a competitive shock
from
imports during the 1970s and 1980s.






[PEN-L:10457] Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: normal profits, etc.

1999-08-30 Thread Ajit Sinha



Michael Perelman wrote:

 The reason that inflation and depreciation has to do with the rate of profit is that 
the
 numerator has a capital stock associated with it.  For example, if a computer is 
bought in
 one year, we cannot merely take the market price from last year as its contribution 
to the
 total capital stock.

___

Of course not. We take the price of the computer today to value the capital stock. 
What is the
problem with that? Cheers, ajit sinha



 Ajit Sinha wrote:

  What inflation or deflation has got to do with calculating the generalized rate of
  profits? It is a measure for a given point in time, it has nothing to do with 
changes in
  prices. And if the calculation of the
  generalized rate of profits is "abstract", then what economic calculation could be
  characterized as "concrete"?

 ---
 Michael Perelman
 Economics Department
 California State University
 Chico, CA 95929

 Tel. 530-898-5321
 E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]