Copyright © 1998 by James K. Galbraith. Readers may redistribute this
article to other individuals for noncommercial use, provided that the text
and this notice remain intact. This article may not be resold, reprinted, or
redistributed for compensation of any kind without prior written permission
from the author. If you have any questions about permissions, please contact
The Electronic Policy Network at [EMAIL PROTECTED] 

The Butterfly Effect

James K. Galbraith

Small actions can have large consequences. The mathematics of chaos teaches
that a butterfly, flapping its wings in Brazil, can set off a chain of
events leading to a hurricane at Cape Fear. They call this the "butterfly
effect."

On March 24, 1997, the butterfly was named Alan Greenspan. That day, he
flapped his wings just once, raising the interest rate by one-quarter of one
percent point. 

Global currency instability started just about then. The Thai crisis hit
three months later. After that, it wasn't just the Asian Rim currencies --
Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines and Indonesia -- that fell. So did the Yen.
So did the Taiwan and Australian dollars. And so did an index representing
the Euro. Indeed there was a worldwide devaluation, leaving only the British
pound and the U.S. dollar flying high.

Seen this way, the so-called "Asian crisis" was not restricted to Asia. Nor
did the markets suddenly discover that particular countries suffered from
inefficiency and corruption, the theme of President Clinton's speech in Hong
Kong. Instead, Asian and non-Asian currencies have moved in striking
parallel, often day by day. The differences were of degree: since March,
1997 the currencies of Europe, Japan, Australia and Taiwan have fallen about
20 percent; a cluster of the Philippines, Malaysia, Korea and Thailand fell
40 percent, and Indonesia fell 80 percent. 

What caused the differences? Roughly, currencies collapsed in proportion to
their dependence on American capital. Those hit hardest were those that have
relied most on our investments, that had the least resident wealth, that
were most caught up in construction booms financed by short-term inflows.
When U.S. interest rates started to rise, dollar-sensitive investors came
home. The dollar went up, and its closest dependencies, like Suharto's
rupiah, were the greatest victims. In short, this was a crisis of the
American financial empire.

It is also a crisis of the "Washington consensus," that doctrine of
deregulation and open capital markets. Much nonsense has been written about
the collapse of the Asian development model -- a collapse which has not
taken down Taiwan, or China, two leading Asian success stories. But since
this crisis was made in Washington, it cannot be ended in Seoul or Djakarta.
Reforms of Asian domestic policies may be necessary. But they cannot cure a
problem that was caused, most fundamentally, by our own policies that raised
real and relative interest rates.

Equally, the vast capital inflows into the United States in 1997 -- the
portfolio investments that fueled the boom in the American stock market --
were kicked off by Greenspan's rate hike (and the expectation that more
would follow). The consequences for the American productive economy are now
surfacing in a vast increase in the U.S. trade deficit, as exports tumble
and cheapened imports flood our markets, and as falling exports lead to
slower economic growth and rising unemployment. These consequences will
multiply if we fail to act quickly -- and correctly.

Alan Greenspan seems aware of these dangers: he spoke of them vividly in an
important speech six months ago. But there are some people, incredibly, who
think U.S. interest rates should rise again. The Federal Reserve harbors a
faction led by Jerry Jordan and William Poole, two refugees from monetarism
who vote for higher interest rates at every meeting. (Jordan and Poole are
veterans of Ronald Reagan's Council of Economic Advisers; their survival in
power through the Fed's system of unaccountable appointments is the best
argument yet for throwing the regional bank Presidents off the
decision-making Open Market Committee.)

And so the debate at the Federal Reserve's Open Market Committee is between
those who say "raise rates" and those who say, "not yet." Greenspan and the
"not yet" faction have held the line so far. But such a stalemate must
always end, eventually, in a rate increase - never, until much too late, in
a rate cut.

Today, on the contrary, interest rates must come down. Indeed, interest
rates should be cut sharply -- let's say two full percentage points -- to
meet the global crisis. Further steps, of which the mildest would be a Tobin
Tax on capital flows and speculative transactions, might help. The proposed
multilateral agreement on investments (MAI) should be abandoned, and the
U.S. should instead recognize the fundamental right of every state to
control the immigration and emigration of capital. That loan to Japan was a
good step; more may be needed later. Special measures for Russia are
urgently needed, as that giant country, a security issue for the entire
globe, continues its slide toward disaster.

By stemming capital inflows, such actions might send stock prices downward
at first; a boom based on capital inflows will not continue when they stop.
But stock prices will recover if U.S. economic growth is sustained by an
early recovery of the world economy, of other currencies and of our export
markets. The alternative: more global instability and more of our own
debt-driven bubble, followed by a prolonged collapse, could be -- chaos. 



James Galbraith is Professor at the LBJ School of Public Affairs, The
University of Texas at Austin and author of Created Unequal: The Crisis in
American Pay, to be published in August by the Free Press. He is also Senior
Scholar, the Jerome Levy Economics Institute. This essay will appear in FOMC
Alert.



Copyright © 1998 by James K. Galbraith. Readers may redistribute this
article to other individuals for noncommercial use, provided that the text
and this notice remain intact. This article may not be resold, reprinted, or
redistributed for compensation of any kind without prior written permission
from the author. If you have any questions about permissions, please contact
The Electronic Policy Network at [EMAIL PROTECTED] 

Regards, 

Tom Walker
^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^
#408 1035 Pacific St.
Vancouver, B.C.
V6E 4G7
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
(604) 669-3286 
^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^
The TimeWork Web: http://www.vcn.bc.ca/timework/

Reply via email to