Colin wrote:
On the question of the role of colonial trade in
European growth, however, we risk going back over
ground covered a year ago, when you raised  this
question. I raised two points of analysis drawn from
Blackburn's  1997 book; let's call them the
"leading sector" and  "scale economies" arguments.
We had a brief back-and-forth on how to frame the
question, but you never  responded to these points.
Could you do so now?

You also raise again the "1% of GNP" argument:
> O'Brien's findings, however, cannot be pushed aside.
> ... the colonial profits
> re-invested would have amounted to only 1 % of GNP, or 10%
> of gross investment.
Which Barkley answered a year ago, saying
> Ricardo,
> 1% of GNP directed towards capital investment is
> non-trivial, especially over time, and especially if it is
> concentrated in crucial sectors, as the returns to
> Liverpool-based slave traders in England certainly were.
> Barkley Rosser

The archives don't show a response from you, and
it's an important point.
The same consideration would apply to your more
recent  raising of O'Brien's claim that

> colonial profits permitted British gross annual investment
> to be 7% higher than it would have otherwise been. So,
> Wallerstein played around with this figure to show that "it
> mattered".

These are not insignificant figures especially if
we  disaggregate.  And indeed as Marx and many others
emphasize this is vital because we are talking about
qualitative change in national economies.  Simply
comparing a sector like textiles to the mass of the
existing European economy may not tell you a whole
lot.

Ricardo:  
Colin, let's not lose track of my earlier post which distinctly 
recognized the importance of the colonial trade through the 
re-export market which obviously stimulated intra-European trade both 
indirectly and directly. Did it play a *decisive* role in the 
Industrial Revolution? The numbers seem to say no.  

I don't recall Robin Blackburn's arguments (I took a course with him)
except that our exchange then was specifically about the slave trade. 
Now, if we take Eric Williams's argument (who everyone 
would agree wrote highly readeable, masterful histories on the 
West Indies and the slave trade),  it is simply an exaggeration to say 
that slavery provided most of the profits in the formation of British 
capital. Someone has estimated that the percentage of slave profits 
in the making of British capital was a scrimpy 0.11% (Anstey)! 
Engerman, for his part, has calculated  "the gross value of slave trade 
output" to England's national income to be 1%, to rise to 1.7% in 1770.  
These two sources I have taken from David Landes's recently published 
book, The Wealth and Poverty of Nations (1998), which I am reading 
now (as well as using for one of my classes) as part of my evaluation 
of Frank. 

(BTW Landes and Frank just met this last December at 
Northeastern, heralded in some lists as a major debate, with cameras 
and all. Frank had been pestering him for a while to come and debate 
him as Landes's book takes a position too "eurocentric" for 
Re-Orient. I will bring Landes's argument soon, as it will connect to 
the issue of  China's economy in 1400-1800; but if I may anticipate  
a point, I am no follower of Landes, who I think is methodological 
closer to Frank than people assume.)

But in his book, Landes, in a a section which coincidentally I read 
this morning 
as part of my lecture, is quite fair to Williams's thesis, and 
reminds us that the slave trade was part of a broader "triangular 
trade" - which is why I framed the whole issue in terms of the 
colonial trade - adding that the role of this trade  consisted less on 
the profits made from it than on its forward and backward linkages. 
Nonetheless, he concludes,  correctly, that this trade accelerated an 
industrialization processs which would have happened only 
more slowly. 

I think this answers/conforms to some of what you say later. 
The additional point you make that

"the fact that silver from Potosi ended up in Canton
does not mean that Europe lost.  The key, surely,
was Europe's ability to position itself in an
international trading system" 

is precisely what I said Frank says 
about the colonial trade, that even if O'Brien is right what matters 
is that Europe gained a ticket into the world-economy as a result of 
this exploitation. But I already showed that there was no world 
economy but two dominant ones of which the intra-European 
was the dominant. 

Colin concludes: "But I would ask you to consider whether the very
question of locating e.g. "the main factor in the
industrialization of England" inside or outside
Europe is sensible.  Surely the force of AGF's
argument is that we have had a truly  international
economy for a very long time." 
Again, the numbers are against Frank's claim there was a world 
economy dominated by Asia, since the Asian economy was much smaller 
(with very few links to the European one) as compared to the 
intra-European world-economy...Perhaps the sibling rivalry between 
Louis Proyect and Doug Henwood is obscuring my points.




Reply via email to