[Pen-l] The Fall and Rise of Economic History

2014-12-01 Thread Louis Proyect
Chronicle of Higher Education December 1, 2014
The Fall and Rise of Economic History

By Jeremy Adelman and Jonathan Levy

Irritated, one shoos it out the door, and almost immediately it climbs 
in through the window. Without the concept of capitalism, the late 
French historian Fernand Braudel once wrote, it was impossible to study 
economic history. But the reverse is equally true: We can’t understand 
capitalism without economic history.

Once a mainstay of history departments, economic history was, with 
historians’ complicity, seized in the mid-20th century by economists who 
sucked the culture and chronology out of it and turned it into an 
obscure province of mathematical formulas. There it languished. The 
field became increasingly uncool. By the 1990s, to be a materialist in 
the age of Michel Foucault and Pierre Bourdieu was to be 
deterministic—in other words, a dinosaur. So economic history further 
retreated to economics departments, where many self-described economic 
historians had already been gathering under the banner of the new 
economic history.

The past decade has exposed some fundamental problems with that division 
of disciplinary labor. The now-old new economic history either fizzled 
or has become so technical, so unrecognizable to anyone who cannot wield 
its finely tuned analytics, that few historians can engage with it. 
Meanwhile, fewer and fewer economics departments now consider 
history—including the history of economics itself—a relevant domain of 
disciplinary inquiry, with many of the top departments having eliminated 
economic history from their programs altogether.

Lately historians have started to take it back, spurred by a demand to 
better understand the roller coaster of capitalist life, particularly 
how inequality and globalization factored into the recession. The 
economic crisis pushed courses on the history of capitalism to the top 
of the charts in history departments around the country, even making 
front-page news in The New York Times. With conferences, courses, and 
book series, the history of capitalism, one of the few areas of inquiry 
where job postings are growing, is on the verge of becoming an 
established subfield. The runaway success of Thomas Piketty’s Capital in 
the Twenty-First Century (Harvard University Press) raised even higher 
the political and intellectual profile of capitalism and its history.

In this way, a prodigal-son subfield has returned. Historians do not 
leave political history to political scientists, or social history to 
sociologists. Why should economic history be left to economists, 
especially when they ignore it? Besides, the humanities might well 
benefit from the revival of a field that once served as a bridge to the 
social sciences.

The history of capitalism performs heroic service, but bereft of a 
broader grasp of the history of economic life, it can’t provide deep 
insights into the makings of systems of production, circulation, and 
distribution. Capitalism is a latecomer in that story, and, like all 
latecomers, more reliant on its precursors and alternatives than its 
apostles and critics like to admit. There can be no history of 
capitalism without an economic history near its explanatory core.

Like democracy or modernity, capitalism is a historical problem, 
specific to time and place. If only because it eludes easy definition, 
it must be studied from different perspectives, with different 
historical methodologies. There are social histories of democracy, 
intellectual histories of democracy, and, of course, political histories 
of democracy. The economy could be the subject of similar multiple 
approaches. But it is not. It has been treated as a realm apart.

This is a surprising state of affairs. Looking back to 1960 or even 
1980, one would not have predicted the eclipse of economic history. From 
the Progressive Age (1900 to 1930) onward, it was almost de rigueur to 
proclaim the material roots of everything and to tie one’s research to 
the broad spirit of reform. Capitalism’s postwar golden age was good 
for economic history, as it was for the world economy. The pairing of 
social and economic history was the fallback working methodology of 
many professional historians. The works of Eric Hobsbawm, Thomas C. 
Cochran, and Braudel himself were touchstones. Even books by the first 
generation of new economic historians, such as Robert Fogel and Stanley 
Engerman’s Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Slavery (Little, 
Brown and Company, 1974), were read and reckoned with by noneconomic 
historians. Surely globalization, the ascendance of China, and the rise 
of Apple should have continued to fuel the field.

A confluence of several forces broke things up. By the 1960s, economic 
history was increasingly associated with development economics, at a 
time when that field was seen as running out of steam. It often took the 
likes of Alexander Gerschenkron and R.H. Tawney as departure points and 

Re: [Pen-l] The Fall and Rise of Economic History

2014-12-01 Thread Hinrich Kuhls
An unrepentant Marxist could have added:

On the other side, much more important for us is that our method indicates the
points where historical investigation must enter in, or where bourgeois economy
as a merely historical form of the production process points beyond itself to
earlier historical modes of production.

In order to develop the laws of bourgeois economy, therefore, it is not
necessary to write the real history of the relations of production, but the
correct observation and deduction of these laws, as having themselves become  in
history, always leads to primary equations - like the empirical numbers e.g. in
natural science - which point towards a past lying behind this system.

These indications, together with a correct grasp of the present, then also offer
the key to the understanding of the past - a work in its own right which, it is
to be hoped, we shall be able to undertake as well.

This correct view likewise leads at the same time to the points at which the
suspension of the present form of production relations gives signs of its
becoming - foreshadowings of the future. Just as, on one side the pre-bourgeois
phases appear as merely historical, i.e. suspended presuppositions, so do the
contemporary conditions of production likewise appear as engaged in suspending
themselves and hence in positing the historic presuppositions for a new state of
society.

(Marx, Grundrisse, Penguin 1973 edition, p. 461-2)


Louis Proyect l...@panix.com forwarded:


 Chronicle of Higher Education December 1, 2014
 The Fall and Rise of Economic History

 By Jeremy Adelman and Jonathan Levy

 [...]

 The history of capitalism performs heroic service, but bereft of a
 broader grasp of the history of economic life, it can’t provide deep
 insights into the makings of systems of production, circulation, and
 distribution. Capitalism is a latecomer in that story, and, like all
 latecomers, more reliant on its precursors and alternatives than its
 apostles and critics like to admit. There can be no history of
 capitalism without an economic history near its explanatory core.

 Like democracy or modernity, capitalism is a historical problem,
 specific to time and place. If only because it eludes easy definition,
 it must be studied from different perspectives, with different
 historical methodologies. There are social histories of democracy,
 intellectual histories of democracy, and, of course, political histories
 of democracy. The economy could be the subject of similar multiple
 approaches. But it is not. It has been treated as a realm apart.

 [...]

 Moreover, seen globally, the economy is the product of more than just
 the attributes of one particular place (the West) or time (the modern
 age). Recent and pipeline works will push historians of American
 capitalism to think in more global, transnational, and comparative
 terms, and to be mindful that what appear today to have been outdated,
 precapitalist formations—slavery, household economies, ennobled
 magnates—had essential places in the story and have not faded away so
 easily or tidily. In some cases, as anyone attentive to current social
 inequality can attest, they acquired a new lease on life.

 The study of capitalism requires scope and imagination. It needs an
 economic history reconnected to the broad trunk of history and the
 humanities. Then, who knows—rather than historians imitating economists,
 perhaps we’ll see the reverse.
___
pen-l mailing list
pen-l@lists.csuchico.edu
https://lists.csuchico.edu/mailman/listinfo/pen-l