Since we were discussing the dollar, I thought this might be of interest:

 -----Original Message-----
*From:* Malpass, David (Exchange) [mailto: [snip]]
*Sent:* Wednesday, November 07, 2007 1:18 AM
*To:* Malpass, David (Exchange)
*Subject:* Dollar Weakness

Gold has topped $820, reflecting a new run on the dollar.  The dollar has
also hit new lows relative to the euro and oil.   The U.S. is in the odd
position of asserting that a currency reflects a country's economic
fundamentals even as the dollar continues its six-year plunge.

I'm recirculating below my 2004 WSJ article on this topic.  It argues that
governments and central banks should put more emphasis on currency
stability, and that the exchange rate, rather than reflecting a country's
fundamentals, itself creates a key fundamental (like tax and regulatory
policy).  This argues against the current Fed and Treasury neglect of the
dollar.

We note growing negatives for the U.S. from dollar weakness:

   - Due to dollar weakness, we think core inflation will be somewhat
   elevated in coming years.  If so, this would probably cause higher real
   interest rates, a Fed-engineered disinflation process, and a*relatively weak
   U.S. recovery from the 2008 slowdown*.
   - Rather than attracting investment and jobs, a weakening currency
   often discourages them.  Investments tend to be momentum plays, especially
   regarding currencies (which increasingly dominate over other investment
   considerations).  Cheap is assumed to become cheaper when a currency is
   weakening.  Investors more often seek countries with appreciating currencies
   -- Japan in the 1980s, the U.S. in the 1990s, and Europe and emerging
   markets now.  U.S. equities have severely underperformed foreign
   equities during the dollar's plunge, the reverse of the 1990s.
   - As foreign currencies strengthen, wealth abroad is rising faster
   than U.S. wealth.  This has implications for geopolitics, national
   security, and future U.S. wealth.  To the extent that it takes money
   (capital) to make money, the U.S. is falling behind fast.
   - While the U.S. trade deficit has declined some over the last year,
   most of that reflects the U.S. housing bust (home-building is
   import-intensive) and the foreign economic boom rather than dollar
   weakness.


Wall Street Journal
COMMENTARY
*February 11, 2004*
The Willy-Nilly Dollar
By David Malpass

Since the 1970s, currency values have been swinging wildly, with immense
impact on economies and lives. Just since 1999, the dollar has moved from
$1.17 per euro to $0.83 in 2001, and to $1.27 today, matching moves in the
dollar's value in terms of gold and commodities. The impact of this
volatility on U.S. farmers and manufacturers, developing countries, tourism,
and investment flows has been immense and disruptive.

At last weekend's G-7 meeting, the powerful group of finance ministers and
central bankers accepted this, asserting that exchange rates should be
flexible and reflect economic fundamentals. The U.S. hopes the G-7 language
will form a lasting consensus and be viewed as a set of long-term currency
principles. But there's a hitch: Rather than "reflecting" fundamentals, the
exchange rate is itself a key fundamental. It affects capital flows, jobs,
inflation, and interest rates. Currency changes harm the relationship
between debtors and creditors and dominate the profitability of many
companies.

Without considering the exchange rate, there is not even a ballpark economic
definition of a country's fundamentals -- one can't tell whether monetary
policy is tight or loose, or inflation likely to rise or fall.* If the idea
is that strong economic fundamentals cause a strong currency -- as the
Clinton administration argued -- it is unclear why the Bush administration
seems so comfortable with the two-year weakness in the dollar. It surely
doesn't agree with the dollar-bears' claim that U.S. fundamentals have
deteriorated substantially due to the tax cuts and fiscal deficits.*

My view is the opposite. U.S. fundamentals are much better now than in 2000,
in large part due to the change in the value of the dollar and the improved
tax structure. The fundamentals are reflected in important new records in
GDP, total employment according to the household survey, corporate profits,
productivity and disposable personal income. The U.S. potential growth rate
in coming years is one of the best on record, and hard to explain if the
current value of the dollar is thought to "reflect" economic fundamentals.

The irony in the fascination with the G-7's exchange-rate language is that
the causal relationship from economic fundamentals to currencies works so
poorly. The dollar reached its peak value in 2001 after the recession
started. Dollar strength wasn't the sole cause -- lax regulation plus high
tax rates, interest rates, and oil prices contributed -- but the dollar
certainly didn't reflect U.S. fundamentals.

Japan's experience also supports this "reverse-fundamentals" view. The yen
strengthened in 1990-1995 as Japan created a multi-year stagnation, record
unemployment, and a decade-long stock-market downturn. Not only was the yen
not reflecting fundamentals, it was the key negative fundamental.

At the weekend's G-7 meeting, participants added the idea that excess
volatility or disorder in exchange rates was undesirable for economic
growth. Good point, except the U.S. put very wide boundaries on the
definitions of "excess" and "disorder." It signaled that the euro's movement
against the dollar -- up 53% since 2001 -- has not qualified as undesirable,
nor did one-month moves of over 5% (September and December) constitute
excessive volatility. In the same vein, the U.S. has set very wide
boundaries in defining its "strong dollar" policy, asserting that it is
still in place even after the dollar has lost 35% of its value.

I don't think the G-7's formulation for currency policy -- flexible,
reflecting fundamentals -- is good for global growth. As a currency moves,
the demand for it moves in the same direction causing momentum to take over.
* This momentum nature of currency movements leads to wide, anti-growth
swings in exchange rates. A pro-growth stance would be for the G-7 to prefer
less currency instability in order to create better economic fundamentals.*

The U.S. has shown it can withstand the damage from wide swings in the value
of the dollar. The strong dollar reached an extreme in 2000 and 2001 causing
crises world-wide, a perfect storm, yet the U.S. recession was milder than
normal and unemployment peaked at 6.3%. The U.S. economy is big and
flexible, with multinational corporations well positioned for currency
chaos.

The brunt of the damage from currency volatility falls abroad. Latin America
suffered whiplash when the dollar levitated, then crashed, with serious
aftershocks still showing up almost daily. Though I'm optimistic about
Japan, its years of deflationary yen strength constitute a massive headwind
to its recovery.

*A better system would be one in which governments and their central banks
preferred currency stability over instability and used exchange rates as a
useful signal for monetary policy. If the currency is strong and
strengthening, it means that monetary policy should be loosened to meet
rising demand, and vice versa if the currency is weakening. Currencies would
still be flexible and would trade actively. Currency interventions would be
unnecessary and unwelcome. For the U.S., the result would be a "strong and
stable" dollar and relatively steady interest rates rather than the present
willy-nilly dollar and wide swings in interest rates. Europe, Japan and many
other countries are yearning for less instability in the dollar, and would
grow faster if it occurred.*

As one of the least regulated markets, foreign-exchange trading has moved to
new peaks of profitability on the uncertainty about future exchange rates.
George Soros is famous for making a royal fortune breaking the pound in
1992. But even bigger bucks were made by those who broke the euro in 1999
and 2000 and then broke the dollar in 2002 and 2003. For foreign-exchange
markets, the game never stops, there's nothing to go bankrupt, and no
pretense of fundamental value.

The financial stakes are also high for governments. Japan's Ministry of
Finance lost nearly $40 billion after the September G-7 meeting in Dubai
when the dollar weakened precipitously and the value of Japan's official
dollar holdings shrank. The MOF has been working overtime to make a small
fraction of that back through the risky carry trade, lengthening the
maturity and raising the yield on its U.S. bond holdings despite the grim
outlook for U.S. bonds.

*China and its neighbors are enjoying a boom in investment, in large part
due to good fundamentals provided by currency stability. Investor logic is
that the G-7 wants Asia's currencies to strengthen, so investment in Asia
might also gain even more than its fundamentals suggest. Asia will likely
reap tens of billions in extra investments if a currency-appreciation cycle
builds*, a parallel to Japan in the 1980s.  This raises another major
currency-related problem for the U.S. If currencies are to reflect economic
fundamentals, neighboring Latin America will see itself decapitalized while
Asia booms. Rather than Mexico joining China in currency stability and fast
growth, recent years have seen investment dollars redirected from Mexico to
China in search of China's yuan stability and future strength. Rather than
reflecting fundamentals, currencies are causing them.

On this page in June 2002, I explained my "Bullish on America1" views after
years of concern. I'm still bullish on America, but my latest concern is
that we have swapped an overly strong dollar for an overly weak dollar,
neglecting its value in both directions. The U.S. can survive these currency
swings, but the costs are high and unnecessary. The opportunity to improve
the currency system is palpable.* Around the world, countries yearn for less
instability, leaving the U.S. government and currency traders the principal
advocates of the status quo.*

Mr. Malpass is chief global economist at Bear Stearns.

<<malpass op-ed.pdf>>




-- 
Amit Varma
http://www.indiauncut.com

Reply via email to