http://www.business2.com/b2/web/articles/print/0,17925,1112586,00.html

GIF image


The Economics of Peer Production
Could the culture of participation threaten the existence of the firm?
By Erick Schonfeld, September 30, 2005

So far in the history of capitalism, we've had two major ways to organize economic activity: through companies and through markets. They work in tandem, of course, but they represent two different approaches. Companies coordinate resources (such as people, money, and equipment) through the management hierarchy. A market does the same thing by setting a price on the ultimate economic output that those resources will produce. Now we're seeing the beginnings of a third way to coordinate economic activity that, in some cases, may be more efficient than either the company or the market. It's called peer production.

The Web is creating new ways to coordinate economic activity by allowing individuals to create products for themselves and others to enjoy. Yale Law School professor Yochai Benkler coined the term peer production to describe "the emergence of a vibrant, innovative and productive collaboration, whose participants are not organized in firms and do not choose their projects in response to price signals." Peer production is part and parcel of what I call the culture of participation -- that is, the explosion of user-generated goods (mostly digital), including open-source software, the Wikipedia online encyclopedia, blogs, podcasts, and photo-sharing sites like Flickr. (I even devote a whole category to the subject on the Business 2.0 blog.)

Just as companies and markets coordinate economic activity (through management control and contracts, respectively), the Web allows individual producers and consumers to swarm together with like-minded individuals to create complex products. It also allows them to easily find an audience to test, use, and provide feedback on the content and products they create. Either way, peer production in some cases threatens to decimate the information advantage of companies and markets. In most companies, information about employees, equipment, and capital gets communicated through the management structure -- your boss is supposed to know what you can do and how best to motivate you. In markets it gets communicated via price signals -- "Sure, I'll design a toilet for you if you give me $20,000." In peer production it gets communicated directly between producers and is stored on the Web. Since peer production is not primarily driven by the profit motive, it threatens to destroy profits in those areas where it can effectively compete. If consumers are using peer- produced goods and content, many times it's at the expense of company- produced goods. So even if the peer producers are not making any money, they are potentially taking away sales and market share from companies. (Witness what Linux has done to Sun Microsystems (SUNW).)

At the most basic level, both firms and markets provide different ways to coordinate economic activity. A century ago companies like Ford had to own everything from the rubber plantations to the factories so that they could control all the economic inputs that went into their products. But as the flow of information between firms dramatically improved, the market took on more of that coordinating role. Firms began to specialize in certain activities and contract with other firms for the parts they did not do as well. It was no longer necessary for Ford to own the rubber plantations. But there was still a limit beyond which it did not make sense to specialize. (Ford (F) might contract out the manufacturing of all of a car's components and subsystems, for instance, but it still does the final assembly of the vehicle itself.)

Peer production takes specialization down to the next level -- that of the individual, rather than the business unit. Umair Haque, a management consultant and author of the blog Bubble Generation, explains: "You can only specialize in a firm to whatever degree it costs to coordinate you. Now what is happening with peer production is that it is a self-coordinating thing." Take Wikipedia as an example. There are more than 1.8 million articles on Wikipedia. Since it is a group blog (also known as a wiki), anyone can write a new entry or edit an existing one. If you are an expert in, say, quantum mechanics, you can contribute the two sentences of knowledge that you know best to the entry. This allows people to specialize in a way that is not economical in the real world. After all, Encyclopaedia Britannica cannot farm out a single article to 100 people, but 100 people can contribute to a single article on Wikipedia. The same is true for other forms of peer production. Once people can self- coordinate over the Web, it becomes possible to atomize economic specialization down to the individual. There are growing armies made up of literally millions of people willing to take part in this new form of production. And they are really good at coordinating their activities because of the near-perfect information sharing made possible by the Web.

But does a peer-produced good like Wikipedia really threaten a firm- produced good like the Encyclopaedia Britannica? In other words, is it a better product? Haque says that's the wrong question. "It's not that it is a better product," he maintains. "It's that it is just a little bit worse -- but it doesn't cost as much." Wikipedia is more error-prone than the Encyclopaedia Britannica, but it is also easier to correct. For a surprising number of subjects, that makes it good enough for most people -- and it's free.

Peer production seems to work best with information-based goods, especially those that can be assembled in a modular fashion (like software or an encyclopedia). Companies and markets still rule as organizing entities when capital-intensive equipment or other assets are required. (Oil companies, airplane manufacturers, and investment banks need not worry just yet.) But information goods, especially digital media, are ripe for disruption because the capital equipment needed to produce such media (computers and Internet connections, basically) is widely distributed. For this reason we are already seeing the rise of peer-produced publishing (blogs) and radio (podcasts). Video is not far off. And as the cost of fabrication comes down, light manufacturing and one-off physical goods are beginning to lend themselves to peer production as well. (How hard would it be for engineers or product designers to find each other on the Web, collaborate to design a product using shared computer-aided design software, and then have it manufactured at a custom fab like eMachineShop ?)

Benkler identifies two advantages of peer production, both of which are related to information. First, peer production is better than either companies or markets at "identifying and assigning" the best people to do a job. "That is," Benkler explains, "it loses less information about who the best person for a given job might be than do either of the other two organizational modes." Peer production can come into play whenever there is a low barrier to participation and individual producers can choose to join projects based on their skills and preferences. This ensures that only the most motivated workers take part.

The second advantage is one of increasing returns as more and more contributors seamlessly search through growing knowledge pools to find work that suits them. These knowledge pools take many forms, including online tutorials, software documentation, product reviews, reputation systems, product rankings, user-generated tags, archived playlists, and even Web links. Since there are virtually no transaction costs in peer production (anyone can contribute or consume), it is suddenly viable for millions of potential contributors to review and select the resources, projects, and collaborators they want to work with. Haque maintains that these knowledge pools are the key information-sharing resources for peer- production communities. They act as a collective memory for such communities and make them more productive by storing the most efficient way to transform economic inputs (like those two sentences on quantum mechanics) into finished goods (the collectively written article on quantum mechanics). In the Wikipedia example, every time a peer producer has new knowledge to add, he or she can type in a few more sentences, and it gets stored for everyone else to see. Or with Flickr, every time someone tags a photo with keywords (like "Italy," "pool," or "bubbles"), Flickr's knowledge pool increases. The economic inputs are the photo and the tag. The output is Flickr's growing database of searchable photos, which becomes more valuable as more photos are uploaded to it with related tags so that others can more easily find them.

Unlike at companies, where decisions about things like software coding and product design are kept private, in peer production all such knowledge is made explicitly public. This creates a feedback loop that can help the community learn to build, design, or code more efficiently and, thus, create better output. Not only is new knowledge produced every time we collaborate, but the fact that everything is on the table potentially gets rid of information bottlenecks that occur in firms or markets and leads to greater productivity. ("My productivity increases when you join the network," as Haque puts it.) Peer production promises to turbocharge economic network effects because instead of being limited by how many things you can find on the network, it is limited only by how many things you can do on the network. Haque further argues that this may presage a shift from the exponential growth we've seen so far in web business to a different, even faster-growing combinatorial trend.

All of this theory is well and good. But why do people participate in peer production in the first place? Why do they donate so much time and effort to write their blogs, upload their photos to Flickr, or tag their webpages on del.icio.us? It's certainly not for the money (as nearly any blogger can attest to). Some say it's for the sheer enjoyment of contributing to something you're really interested in. Others point to the ego boost that comes with burnishing your reputation online. I find all of these explanations unsatisfactory. (After all, nobody knows you on Wikipedia. There are no bylines.)

Rather, the strongest explanation is also the simplest: It is in people's self-interest to contribute. People participate in peer production because a) it's cheaper than buying the product outright, or b) the product would not be available otherwise. At its best, the final good is the result of a collective intelligence and could never be produced any other way. The peer producers are their own consumers. They get a better product by tapping into the knowledge pool. And they get a product that exactly fits their needs because they help design it (often with minimal effort). How do you compete with that?


Erick Schonfeld [EMAIL PROTECTED] is an editor-at-large for Business 2.0.

GIF image


Find this article at http://www.business2.com/b2/web/articles/ 0,17863,1112586,00.html.

Try a Free Issue of Business 2.0: Call (800) 317-9704


---
You are currently subscribed to telecom-cities as: [EMAIL PROTECTED] To 
unsubscribe send a blank email to [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Manage your mail settings at 
http://forums.nyu.edu/cgi-bin/nyu.pl?enter=telecom-cities
RSS feed of list traffic: 
http://www.mail-archive.com/telecom-cities@forums.nyu.edu/maillist.xml

Reply via email to