These countries have limited options, and none of them is satisfactory. The
obvious option, further borrowing, is not at all attractive to the debtors
themselves. Additional loans, even if they could be obtained, would quickly
make the debt problem worse. At prevailing borrowing rates, it takes a trade
surplus with western countries of at least 10 percent of the value of a loan
just to pay the interest on it, and a much larger fraction if the loan is to
be amortized. To create such a surplus, the authorities must suppress
domestic consumption or slash public services. In countries where democratic
forces can make political repression extremely problematic, this suppression
of demand is not likely to be feasible. Even such oppressive regimes as
South Korea and Chile are not finding it hard to repress their populations
in the name of capital accumulation.

Economists in both Hungary and Yugoslavia have urged that their countries
avoid the burden of higher interest and amortization payments by pursuing a
second option, the promotion of direct foreign investment, including the
sale of domestic enterprises to foreign investors and the establishment of
joint ventures between foreign firms and state firms (in Hungary) or
cooperatively-owned firms (in Yugoslavia). Success in attracting foreign
investment has been very limited so far. This is probably fortunate, since
this alternative only promises "long-term pain for short-term gain." Foreign
firms invest in a host country for three main reasons: to take advantage of
low-wage labor to produce labor-intensive manufactures for re-export, to get
access to or control over raw material supplies, or to capture a share of
the host-country market. But neither Hungary or Yugoslavia has industrial
regions with much unemployed labor, and neither is particularly well endowed
with natural resources. And foreign investment to exploit domestic markets
is perhaps the least attractive option. Such firms are likely to spend much
of their initial investment on capital goods from the home country and to
repatriate their substantial earnings and depreciation allowances. Many of
their managers and technical personnel will come from the home country, so
few good jobs are created. And judging from the Canadian experience, they
will import an unusually large proportion of their material inputs. Thus the
second option, to attract foreign investment, does little to alleviate the
balance-of-payments problem that is as the root of the current crisis.

A third option was pursued in Romania: squeeze the living standards of the
workers to the point where the import of consumption goods is drastically
reduced, expropriate the domestic surplus and use it to pay off foreign
debts. The human welfare cost, however, is enormous and would not be
politically acceptable in the liberalized Hungary or Yugoslavia of today.

The ideal situation would be for the western industrial powers to cancel at
least a considerable portion of the accumulated debts. Not surprisingly,
their banks are reluctant to do this, though in fact they have done so as
much by unloading large amounts of it on a rapidly-depreciating secondary
market. (Yugoslavia's debt in September was being sold for 55 cents on the
dollar.)

An obvious solution, of course, would be to repudiate the debt, but this
would conflict with the aim of both Hungary and Yugoslavia (and Poland, for
that matter) to increase their economic integration with the west. As long
as the Soviet economy wallows in the doldrums, these countries have few good
alternatives to repudiation.

Yugoslavia has made some small headway recently in reducing its debt
exposure. Some enterprises have reportedly taken low-quality goods from the
Soviet Union in exchange for Soviet trade debts, sold them at discount in
western markets, and used the proceeds to repurchase Yugoslav debt on the
secondary market at 45 percent discount. According to a Globe and Mail
report (18 September 1989) this and other forms of direct buyback have
reduced Yugoslavia's western bank debts by close to a billion dollars.
However, this is a relatively small dent in the problem.

The real danger is that Yugoslavia, Hungary, and Poland will attribute their
debt-induced problems to their political and economic institutions. If they
do, and alter the latter without solving the former, they risk trading their
relatively egalitarian societies and comprehensive welfare systems for the
stagnation, inequality, and appalling poverty of so much of Latin America.


(These are the final paragraphs of Paul Phillips' February 1990 Monthly
Review article "The Debt Crisis and Change in Eastern Europe." I went to the
Columbia library at lunch and typed them in. As I don't have a scanner, this
labor-intensive job is meant as an olive branch. I also want to plead guilty
of staging an elaborate hoax. I've been spending much too much time with
Alan Sokal. There is no such person as "Bruno Hladjz, the Inspector General
of the Croatian navy". There is, however, a Second Avenue Deli in NYC, and a
very good one it is at that.)



Louis Proyect




Reply via email to