RE: Republican Reversal

2002-06-26 Thread John Samples

There is some political science on this question. Perhaps the leading article in 
Dynamic Representation by James Stimson and his colleagues, American Political 
Science Review, 1995. They argue policy follows public opinion closely. 
 
John Samples
Washington, DC

-Original Message- 
From: fabio guillermo rojas [mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]] 
Sent: Wed 6/26/2002 1:48 PM 
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
Cc: 
Subject: Re: Republican Reversal



 These are all good comments on the Republican reversal.  Thus, I take it
 that the list agrees that democracy works pretty well in reflecting the
 wishes of the voters.
 Alex

I'd say democracy reflects general trend in voter opinion pretty
well, although some policies may be way out of whack. For example,
who would argue that either Bush or Gore is very far from the median
voter (except on abortion)? Or that conservative states like Idaho
tend to have more conservative policies?

Fabio 







winmail.dat
Description: application/ms-tnef


RE: Republican Reversal

2002-06-26 Thread John Samples

I always thought the Republican challenge was given voice by an elderly woman in USA 
Today who said, when asked about the government shutdown, They can close the whole 
thing down as far as I'm concerned as long as they get the Social Security checks 
out.
 
John Samples
Washington, DC

-Original Message- 
From: Carl Close [mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]] 
Sent: Tue 6/25/2002 8:18 PM 
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
Cc: 
Subject: Re: Republican Reversal



Alex asks whether the Radical Republicans that were swept into the
House in '94 were co-opted by institutions (Hypothesis #1), or
co-opted by their constituents' softer views (Hypothesis #2)?

I am inclined to hold Hypothesis #2. Why? Two reasons: First, if the
Republican politicians softened while their constituents remained
hardliners, then in the next elections they would have lost to
challengers who castigated them for selling out.

Second, the Radical Repubican Revolution didn't run deep in the
electorate. Much of the Radical Republican strategy and image was
forged by Newt Gingrich, who convinced many freshman Republicans to
sign the so-called Contract with America.

Gingrich saw the public's anger with Clinton (re: tax hikes, health
care, and don't ask, don't tell) as an opportunity to shoot for a
radical Republican agenda, but apparently misread the public, or at
least misread its support for Gingrich himself, who lost popularity
when his efforts contributed to temporary shutdowns of federal
services. (Remember federal buildings being forced to close down
for a day at a time, due to budget uncertainties?)

With the demise of Gingrich, the Radical Repubicans lost their
figurehead, and the so-called Radical Republican movement
evaporated. It evaporated because it was thin to begin with.

I don't think the above fully answers Alex's call for a way to
distinguish between Hypothesis #1 and Hypothesis #2, but perhaps it's
a good enough story to satisfy some of us.

Comments? Criticisms?

Carl

Remember when the Republicans took control of the house in 1994 for
the first time in something like 40 years and all the new young blood
was talking about cutting government programs and scaling back
everywhere?  Remember all the newspaper reports about how everything
would now change.  Yeah, I can hardly remember it either.  How distant
those days seem.  Notice that in recent days the Republicans have been
proudly asserting how much *more* expensive their prescription drug plan
is than the one Democrats have proposed.

   There are different ways of interpreting this volte-face.  One way
is to assert that this shows how corrupting the institutions of
Washington are, how even people with good ideas are sucked in to the
spending way of life etc.  Calls for term limits etc. follow.

  An alternative interpretation, but ultimately perhaps the same
thing, is to say that the public didn't really want what the Republicans
said they were offering and the failure of the cut government group is
simply a reflection of the public's desires.  In this view it's the
American people who are to blame for their government and not peculiar
institutions.

Comments?  Ways to distinguish these explanations?

Alex
--
Dr. Alexander Tabarrok
Vice President and Director of Research
The Independent Institute
100 Swan Way
Oakland, CA, 94621-1428
Tel. 510-632-1366, FAX: 510-568-6040
Email: [EMAIL PROTECTED]







winmail.dat
Description: application/ms-tnef


RE: fantastically entertaining paper

2002-06-21 Thread John Samples

I wonder if entry is cheap. To effectively enter this market, you have to do more than 
edit articles and print copies of the journal. You have to attract valued 
contributions and thereby, readers. I believe contributors send articles to journals 
on the basis of their brand name. How can a journal build its brand name? Have any 
journals sought to build a brand name by paying well-known scholars for their 
contributions for several years? 

The most expensive academic journals are in the fields of science, technology and 
medicine. European commercial publishers who charge thousands for an annual 
institutional subscription own the most prestigious of these journals. A few years ago 
a few American universities looked into starting up their own competitors to the STM 
leaders. Nothing came of it. I suspect they discovered that entry costs were high as 
was the risk of failure.

Academic books cost a lot because their markets are small (300-500 copies on average 
per title) while production costs are relatively high. Total production costs for an 
academic press run of 500 copies are in the $30,000 range. Unit sales are so small in 
part because universities heavily subsidize book production. Even if all the subsidies 
were dedicated to the demand side (or were eliminated), academic books would be 
expensive compared to the average trade book. Without production subsidies, however, 
there would many fewer producers. And the world would be a better place.

John Samples
Cato Institute

-Original Message-
From: Michael Etchison [mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
Sent: Friday, June 21, 2002 1:44 PM
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: RE: fantastically entertaining paper

Robin Hanson:

Michael E. Etchison wrote:
 an industry (academic journals) where . . .  entry is cheap

As a non-academic, I have to wonder -- if getting in is so cheap, why
is getting a copy so expensive?

Standard armchair econ question, really. 

Yes, I know, and I know what we'd suspect.  I was wondering if anyone
had some grounded explanations.

Michael

Michael E. Etchison
Texas Wholesale Power Report
MLE Consulting
www.mleconsulting.com
1423 Jackson Road
Kerrville, TX 78028
(830) 895-4005





academic journals

2002-06-21 Thread John Samples

I have taken the liberty of changing the subject line since the discussion seems to 
have shifted.

Given that this is the Armchair list, what would economists make of an industry that 
works like this:

A firm (the university) hires employees (professors) to make products (articles) that 
are then given gratis to other firms (journal publishers) who produce a product (a 
journal) that is then sold back to a part of the original firm (the university 
library) who buys it on behalf of other parties (its faculty) who by and large will 
not spend their own money on the product (and do so only when there is severe price 
discrimination in their favor). Academic books fit the same model except the product 
is sold to the publisher but the proceeds go to the employee and not the firm that 
originally invested in the writing of the book.

Steve Landesberg recently remarked to me in relation to his experience with university 
administration that it's clear universities are maximizing something, but it's not 
clear what. Perhaps by publishing journals, universities maximize the quality of 
students who seek admission.

 

John Samples

Cato




winmail.dat
Description: application/ms-tnef


RE: Me and the eminent econometrician Dr. Joyce

2002-05-14 Thread John Samples

Most reporters are interested in, and skilled at writing narratives. They generally 
are not interested in or skilled at analytical approaches to politics and society. 
Professor Auld's work was absorbed into the narrative form man bites dog. That is, 
everyone believes hard work and sobriety leads to wealth, but Auld shows the 
opposite. The story was the thing, not the data or the analysis.

On bad days I'm convinced that narratives and anecdotes drive all public policy. But I 
still think there could be a kind of journalism that blends narratives and analysis in 
a useful way. Professor McCloskey has written a lot about the need for narrative in 
economics. However, the fact remains that the market for journalism prefers a good 
story to an ambiguous truth most of the time. 

John Samples
Cato

-Original Message-
From: Christopher Auld [mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
Sent: Monday, May 13, 2002 7:12 PM
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: Me and the eminent econometrician Dr. Joyce


I am somewhat surprised no one has written to this list to give me a bad
time over my recent spate of media attention, for example

http://www.foxnews.com/story/0,2933,51889,00.html  

I found the whole experience of being misquoted, misrepresented, and
generally mistreated quite fascinating, albeit annoying.  I can state for
the record that correlation does not imply causation is far too advanced
a concept for most reporters, even those who are supposed to have a
technical bent.

My advice: When some reporter calls you up and asks you about your
research, say No comment, hang up, change your phone number.


Cheers,

Chris Auld 
Department of Economics
University of Calgary   
[EMAIL PROTECTED]