Further to the despicable and revolting travesty of "employment policy
analysis" by T. Boeri, R. Layard and S. Nickell in their Welfare to Work
report to Prime Ministers Blair and D'Alema and the Council of Europe, I
am forwarding three texts. The first is the central argument of the 1901
London Times series, The Crisis in British Industry, allegedly
co-authored by William Collison, debonair scoundrel and publicist for
the "National Free Labour Association", an organization whose main
purpose was to supply scab labour for the strike-breaking but whose
secondary role was to pose as a phony "Labour" political party,
presumably to confuse working class voters and split the labour vote. I
believe they actually ran candidates in an election around 1911. 

The second is the "lumpy bit" from the Boeri, Layard, Nickell (the
latter two from the London School of Economics) report to the Council of
Europe at
http://www.palazzochigi.it/esteri/lisbona/dalema_blair/inglese.html
Please note that the paragraphs presented here were emphasized by bold
text in the report.

The third text is a letter to the editor of the London Times, from
Sidney and Beatrice Webb, responding to the Crisis in British Industry
series. It should be remembered that the Webbs had considerable to do
with the founding of the British Labour Party as well as the
establishment of the London School of Economics. Sidney also co-authored
a book in the 1890s on the economics of the eight-hour day. Beatrice was
a prominant dissenting member of a Royal Commission on Unemployment,
whose minority report was influential in establishing the social
insurance benefits that the Boeri, Layard, Nickell report is bent on
dismantling.

1. The Collison/Pratt hypothesis about the motive behind the movement
for an eight-hour day (from "The Crisis in British Industry, London
Times, November 28, 1901:

It was hoped to "absorb" all the unemployed in course of time, not by
the laudable and much-to-be-desired means of increasing the volume of
trade, and hence, also, the amount of work to be done, but simply by
obtaining employment for a larger number of persons on such work as
there was already. The motive of this aspiration, however, was not one
of philanthropy pure and simple. When all the unemployed had been
absorbed the workers would have the employers entirely at their mercy,
and would be able to command such wages and such terms as they might
think fit. The general adoption of the eight hours system was to bring
in a certain proportion of the unemployed; if there were still too many
left the eight hours system was to be followed by a six hours system;
while if, within the six, or eight, or any other term of hours, every
one took things easy and did as little work as he conveniently could,
still more openings would be found for the remaining unemployed, and
still better would be the chances for the Socialist propaganda. 


2. From the Report to Prime Ministers Blair and D’Alema, WELFARE-TO-WORK
AND THE FIGHT AGAINST LONG-TERM
UNEMPLOYMENT, by T. Boeri, R. Layard and S. Nickell:

The welfare-to-work approach outlined above is incompatible with the
view that full employment can be
achieved only by reducing the number of persons in the labour market.
Yet many people doubt whether
society can actually provide jobs for more people. According to this
popular wisdom (the so-called
"lump-of-labour" fallacy), the number of jobs is fixed. Hence
unemployment can only be reduced by
redistributing the stock of jobs available across individuals and
pushing people out of the labour force.
This widespread belief lies at the root of the campaign for earlier
retirement, and explains much of the
pessimism about welfare-to-work policies for the unemployed. 

We discuss these issues at some length in our report. In the very
short-run there is of course a limit to
the number of jobs, which is set by the level of aggregate demand. But
aggregate demand in Europe is
rising and will continue to do so until it hits its long-run upper
limit. This limit is set not by demand but by the effective supply of
employable labour. And if the supply of labour rises the number of jobs
responds.
If history tells any lesson, it is that.


3. The Webb's reply to THE CRISIS IN BRITISH INDUSTRY:

December 6, 1901

TO THE EDITOR OF THE TIMES.

Sir, In the articles which you have lately published attacking trade
unionism you expressly challenge reply, and you even infer that the
absence of contradiction in your columns proves, not only the
correctness of the allegations themselves, but also the validity of the
deductions made from them. We venture therefore, to say that six years'
detailed investigation into the actual working of trade unionism all
over Great Britain convinced us that, as an institution, it has a good
and (to those who will take the trouble to study the facts) a conclusive
answer to your charges. But working men do not read The Times, any more
than your Correspondent reads our Industrial Democracy, in which he
would have found all his charges against trade unionism examined in full
and minutre detail, and, we hope, with candour, four years ago. This
elaborate work has not been refuted or replied to. The absence from your
columns of any answer to your Correspondent's allegations is therefore
no proof of their truth.

What your Correspondent alleges comes, in brief, to this -- that English
workmen do not put their full strength into their work; that they give
when they can a "light stroke," or skulk; that they are not eager for
the greatest possible productivity, and even resent it, as tending to
diminish employment; that they resist labour-saving contrivances; and
that they are in a constant conspiracy to keep down the speed and energy
of their labour.

Now, so far as they relate to the instinctive sentiment of a manual
working class, employed at time wages, we believe that your
Correspondent's charges contain much truth. It is a special evil of the
separation of industrial classes, the reduction of all relations between
employer and employed to the "cash nexus," and the growing intensity of
competition, that masters and men are always tempted to try to take
advantage of one another. The employers seek to get more work for the
same wages, or otherwise to alter the proportion of remuneration to
effort, and the workmen seek to effect a similar alteration in the other
direction -- namely, by getting more wages for the same work, or
expending less energy for the same remuneration. The result in either
case is bad for the community, and it is to be unreservedly deplored
that conditions so vital to national well-being as the citizen's
standard of life and industrial productivity should be left to this
anarchic duel between individuals.

But your Correspondent also alleges that the evil (he characteristically
thinks only of the workman's malpractices) is worse than formerly, and
that it is increasing; and he identifies it with trade unionism, which
he accuses of being the cause of what he dislikes. We believe, after
considerable investigation, that these statements are quite incorrect
and the reverse of the truth.

The complaints as to diminished quantity or energy of work, and of the
tacit conspiracy to discourage individual exertion, occur with curiously
exact iteration in every decade of the last 100 years at least. Even in
the 16th century there were found those who, in the words of Orlando in
*As You Like It*, sighed for --

"The constant service of the antique world, When service sweat for duty,
not for meed." 

But such complaints are evidence only of the psychological condition of
their utterers -- they prove no objective fact. To give one instance
only, we have found exactly the same accusation of the bricklayers'
limiting the number of bricks, and precisely the same belief that they
were only doing "half as much" as they did 20 years before, in the great
strikes of 1833, in those of 1853, again in 1859-60, and again in 1871.
We believe them all -- that is to say, we take them as some evidence
that the employers felt the workmen's constant attempt in all ages to
alter the bargain to their own presumed advantage. But we have found
absolutely notheing that can be called evidence that the actual
*quantum* of work done per hour, quality and conditions being taken into
account, is less today than it was a hundred years ago. (It must be
remembered that brickwork differs enormously, and that some that passed
muster in old days would not now be allowed by the architect or district
surveyor.) We must add that we entirely disbelieve in the existence of
any unwritten limit of 400, or any other number, of bricks per day as a
consciously agreed-upon limit. This is another old story, for which,
after much investigation, we have never been able to find any evidence.

Passing from the bricklayers to the whole range of English labour, we
can only record as the result of our own studies that, so far from the
aggregate product being less per head, and decreasing, we are convinced,
on the evidence of employers themselves, that greater sobriety, greater
regularity, increased intelligence, and improved methods of remuneration
make the manual labour of this country (irrespective of the results of
machinery) far more productive to-day than it ever was before. Would any
great employer exchange his present workers for those of 1801?

Moreover, in so far as the disposition to limit the amount of energy
exists, it is incorrect to ascribe it to trade unionism. Only 5 per
cent. of the population are trade unionists, and many of the most
important occupations are free from trade unionism. Do we find that the
manual worker is there exempt from his typical economy of energy or
resentment of labour-saving appliances? Is the agricultural labourer,
for instance, a worker at high pressure, a keenly alert enthusiast for
high productivity, or free from the "lump of labour" fallacy? On the
other hand, there is certainly no keener advocate of "speeding up," no
more eager user of the newest machinery, than the Lancashire cotton
spinners, who form, perhaps, the most completely organized and powerful
of trade unions. It is clearly not possible to decide whether trade
unionism is or is not a cause of so widely prevalent a characteristic of
the manual worker without a fairly complete comparison of trade with
trade, whcihc your Correspondent does not attempt. Again, we can only
give our own conclusion for what it may be worth, formed after such a
comparison. This is that trade unionism is certainly not the cause, or
even a cause, of what is an instinctive attitude of the hired manual
worker as such; that, whilst trade unionism (as a working-class
movement) has naturally at no time been uninfected by this
characteristic, it has during the past 100 years been steadily shaking
it off; and that at the present time the influence of trade unionism,
considered as a whole, is more efficacious in increasing than in
reducing the productivity of the labour of its members.

Take, for instance, the question of piecework. No one would gather from
your Correspondent -- no doubt, he is unaware of it -- that (omitting
the general labourers and transport workers, where piecework is plainly
impossible) more than half the membership of trade unionism positively
insists on piecework., and would instantly strike if an employer tried
to pay by the hour or day. Another large section accepts piecework or
timework with equal favour. Only about 20 per cent. fight against
piecework. A larger percentage of trade unionists work by the piece than
of the workers in occupations free from trade unionism. We have analysed
fully elsewhere the reasons which make some trades prefer piecework and
others timework. WE can only say here that all experience shows that
where piecework is not accompanied by a collectively agreed upon
standard list (and in many cases this is impossible) it inevitably leads
to "sweating." This is, indeed, the conclusion of enlightened employers
themselves -- see, for instance, the convincing testimony of the great
shipbuilder William Denny, in his Life, by A.B. Bruce, p. 113. In other
industries it is timework which may mean "sweating." It is noteworthy
that it is often the employers who insist on changing from piecework to
timework. Thus, "stab" (timework) among the compositors was introduced
by the employers, in a trade that origianlly worked entirely on
piecework. And, to come to more recent times, much of the friction in
the boot and shoe trade has undoubtedly been due to the fact that the
employers, when introducing new or additional machinery, frequently
insisted on substituting time wages for piecework. They professed no
hostility to piecework but they declared that the time was not
opportune, or that they could not settle rates, and so on. But meanwhile
they have often made men who had hiterto worked by the piece henceforth
work for fixed wages, at a moment when their productivity was greatly
increasing. No worder there has been trouble!

The fact is, the problem of establishing, on a "cash nexus," such
conditions of the wage contract as shall give the greatest possible
stimulus, boht in workmen and employers, to the utmost productivity, and
at the same time secure the maintenance and progressive improvement of
the operatives' standard of life, is one of the most difficulat ever set
to mortal man. It is doing no injustice to employers to say that,
occupied only with one side of this problem, they have not, up to the
present, contributed much to its solution -- even the best of them
regarding it as no part of their business to rack their brains to
discover how to maintain or raise the workman's standard of life. The
trade unionists have had to puzzle out the answers for themselves. That
they should, like the employers, have regarded primarily their own side
of the problem was only to have been expected. The result is that,
except in a few trades (and these, be it remarked, exactly the trades in
which trade unionism is strongest), the problem has not been solved --
has, indedd, as yet scarcely been seriously grappled with -- either by
masters or men.

We hold no brief for trade unionism. We do not believe that trade
unionism, by itself, can supply the solution of this problem of vital
import to the community. We regard the legislation of Victoria and New
Zealand as pointing a more excellent way. But we do not think that any
instructed person doubts that the admirable collective arrangements
which regulate employment in Lancashire cotton-spinning, or, in another
form, Northumberland coalmining -- adopted maily at the instance of the
trade unions concerned -- approach nearer to a solution of the problem
than anything existing in other trades in the United Kingdom. On the
other hand, the industries free form trade unionism, or analogous
regulation by law, are exactly those in which the productivity per
worker is at its lowest, the standard of effort at a *minimum*, the use
of machinery most discouraged, and (what is perhaps to the community the
most important fact) the character, intelligence, and physique of the
workers undergoing a fatal deterioration. We need only refer in
confirmation to the House of Lords' Committee Report on the Sweating
System, and to the evidence obtained by the subsequent Royal Commission
on Labour.

In conclusion, surely it is too late to oppose trade unionism by a
torrent of indiscriminate abuse. A campaign of libel and insinuation; a
condemnation in one sentence of such utterly contradictory devices as
the standard rate and the restriction of output; the omission of all
references to the "sweating" devices of the employers which (in the
interest of the community as well as their own) the workmen have somehow
to parry -- all this gives an impression of ignorance and unfairness
which deprives such a criticism of any useful effect. What is wanted is
discrimination -- discrimination between those devices of trade unionism
(such as the enforcement on all employers of a minimum standard rate, a
normal day, and conditions of sanitation and safety) which economic
science proves to be sound and to the benefit of the trades concerned
and the community as a whole, and on the other hand those others (such
as all forms of restriction of output, or opposition to improved
processes) which do nothing but injure all parties. In English trade
unionism, as we have proved elsewhere by elaborate statistics, the
former constitute, fortunately, the predominant and the growing force.
But indiscriminate abuse of trade unionism as such does not encourage
the pary of progress within the trade-union movement. 

We are, &c.,
SIDNEY AND BEATRICE WEBB.
41, Grosvenor-road, Westminster.

Reply via email to