over-investment

2002-10-04 Thread Devine, James
Title: over-investment





[was: RE: [PEN-L:30892] Re: PK's the man with the plan]


 - Original Message -
 From: Devine, James
 [Pen-l alumnus Brad deLong used to deny the possibility of 
 over-investment,
 even though it's the subject of my Ph.D. dissertation! 
 (UC-Berkeley Econ.,
 1981.) does he still do so?]


Ian: 
 I don't think so; he made some comments regarding the issue 
 on his blog a
 week or two ago..


Can you find them?


Brad's original argument, if I remember it correctly, against the Austrian and Schumpeterian versions of over-investment theory and in favor of a version of Keynesianism. The Austrian theory has usually been interpreted as saying that the policy response to a recession like those of 2001 or 1929-33 in the U.S. should be let nature take its course: eventually, the recession will purge the economy of the imbalances accumulated during the boom phase of the cycle, allowing recovery. In this view, active fiscal and/or monetary policy simply encourages the imbalances to persist or get worse. 

I haven't read all of what Brad says about this, but my (admittedly superficial) impression is that he doesn't analyze the Austrian or Schumpeterian perspectives in depth. Instead, he assumes that the current economics-profession orthodoxy is correct, which implies that over-investment theory is wrong. 

More importantly, he seems to generalize from a critique of the Austrian and Schumpeterian over-investment/recessionary purgation theories to reject _all_ theories that have this emphasis, including the Marxian and Keynes-Marxian ones. Of course, I may be missing one of his articles on this subject, so I may be misrepresenting his views. 

Daniel Davies writes:
I believe that the politically correct point of view on this topic among the
relevant crowd is that the economy as a whole cannot have over-investment,
but that individual industries can. Quite how this squares with an
aggregative view of capital I cannot say, but then I am not a theologian ...


this seems to be a dynamic version of Say's Law: if there's over-investment in one sector, there must be under-investment in another. This is as valid as Say's Law was (or even less so). 

BTW, the standard textbook flexible accelerator model allows for over-investment. It says that net investment reflects the difference between the desired (aggregate) stock of capital goods and the actually-existing stock. If the desired stock is actually less than the actually-existing stock, then all of the standard stories of monetary policy or corporate take breaks stimulating investment fly out the window. Despite low interest rates, why invest if companies already have more than enough fixed capital? We have to wait for depreciation and the like to get the actually-existing stock back below the desired stock in order to get back to more normal investment behavior.

My own view of the business cycle is a combination of over-investment theory and Keynes. In some eras, capitalism over-shoots relative to supply constraints (as in the late 1960s) so that there are cost constraints on the profit rate. In other eras, such as our current one, capitalism over-shoots relative to what's justified by consumer demand -- or consumers have to get into excessive debt to allow investment to continue. Either way, imbalances are created that keep the economy from snapping back and from responding quickly to monetary policy. Monetary policy may simply encourage unwise debt accumulation or continuation of an over-investment process or short-circuiting of the purgation process. 

The Keynesian component arises because over-investment can cross an invisible line that's not known until the owl of Minerva has flown the coop (i.e. until after the fact). The economy can spin into an underconsumption trap and/or Fisherian debt-deflation. In this situation, only fiscal policy can work. 

JD





Re: over-investment

2002-10-04 Thread Michael Perelman

Brad's critique of liquidationism -- The Austrian-Schumpeterian view of
overinvestment -- is quite nice, but it does not preclude the possibility
of overinvestment.  If his view is what Jim says, that overinvestment
can occur in individual industries but not in economy as a whole, then his
theory would amount to a repetition of what David Ricardo said a few years
ago.

 -- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: over-investment

2002-10-04 Thread Waistline2
In a message dated 10/4/02 9:15:08 AM Pacific Daylight Time, [EMAIL PROTECTED] writes:


My own view of the business "cycle" is a combination of over-investment theory and Keynes. In some eras, capitalism over-shoots relative to supply constraints (as in the late 1960s) so that there are cost constraints on the profit rate. In other eras, such as our current one, capitalism over-shoots relative to what's justified by consumer demand -- or consumers have to get into excessive debt to allow investment to continue. Either way, imbalances are created that keep the economy from "snapping back" and from responding quickly to monetary policy. Monetary policy may simply encourage unwise debt accumulation or continuation of an over-investment process or short-circuiting of the purgation process. 



The commodity form is under attack. This is not a classical "general crisis of capital" but something different, contingent of a phase of history in transition to a new mode of production. There is no cure on the basis of monetary policy. 


Melvin P. 


Re: over-investment

2002-10-04 Thread Ian Murray

over-investment
- Original Message -
From: Devine, James

Can you find them?

==

Give me a few and I'll fish 'em out.


The Keynesian component arises because over-investment can cross an
invisible line that's not known until the owl of Minerva has flown the coop
(i.e. until after the fact). The economy can spin into an underconsumption
trap and/or Fisherian debt-deflation. In this situation, only fiscal policy
can work.
JD

===

Well it's that time of year to be watching the earmarking process in
Congress again..Bush has already gotten his military fiscalism package
but I doubt that's going to be sufficient.


washingtonpost.com
Investors See Green in Government IT Sector
Government Contractors Take Advantage of Tech Bust To Actively Court Wall
Street

By Cynthia L. Webb
washingtonpost.com Staff Writer
Friday, October 4, 2002; 12:00 AM


Dendy Young, chairman and chief executive of GTSI Corp., used to have a
tough time getting the investment community to notice his company.

A year ago it was frankly difficult to get in and see people, said Young,
whose Chantilly-based company resells computer software and hardware to
local, state and federal government agencies. I would try and take trips to
New York and I would get one or two appointments set up and it would be
difficult to get others.

But as the broader technology sector continues to flail, GTSI Corp. [GTSI]
and other firms in the government contracting space are winning newfound
respect from investors seeking out companies with real customers and cash
flow.

Nowadays if I go to New York, I'm making five six calls a day, Young said.

Market analysts are taking note of the expected flood of information
technology spending by the federal government. According to FSI, an IT
market research firm in McLean, roughly $52.5 billion of President Bush's
proposed fiscal year 2003 budget is slated for IT-related systems and
services. That is an increase from $44.9 billion pegged in the budget
submitted for fiscal year 2002.

Higher government spending on technology was prompted in part by the Sept.
11 terrorist attacks. A good deal of that money is expected to be spent on
cybersecurity efforts and high-tech weapons and the systems that make them
work. Moreover, the government's war on terrorism is requiring bureaucrats
to link diverse computer systems -- from the CIA and Defense Department to
the Customs Service and newly formed Transportation Security
Administration -- to better share information and mine data.

Investment experts know the government will turn to private firms to carry
out many of these tasks. And with so much work potentially available to the
sector, the stock performances and bottom lines of defense and IT services
firms servicing the government have shown promise.

Case in point: Two years ago, GTSI's shares were trading in the $3 range. A
year ago, the stock was trading at below $6.50 and it has climbed to the $8
to $9 range recently. GTSI logged nearly $784 million in revenue last
year -- almost a 16 percent hike from 2000. The company has been profitable
year-over-year since 1998, and it has seen its employee roster grow from 574
workers in 2000 to 671 today.

The government sector was not a golden child to Wall Street for a number of
years, said Marylourdes Petty, who heads GTSI's investor relations. Founded
in 1983, GTSI went public in 1991, but its name is just now getting more
traction.

[S]uddenly we are the golden children, Petty said.

It doesn't hurt, however, that GTSI has ramped up its investor and public
relations efforts. Three years ago, the company didn't even have an investor
relation's department. The company started making a concerted effort to woo
big investors about two years ago, Young said. His schedule is now filled
with meetings to pitch investment clubs, the National Stockbroker's
Association and analysts.

Even larger players in government contracting circles have put a premium on
courting Wall Street. American Management Systems Inc. [AMSY] of Fairfax,
for example, has increased its focus on investor relations as part of the
information technology consulting company's recent management changes, said
spokeswoman Anne Burt.

Outreach is more active in both directions between the investment community
and contractors, said Doug Coffey, vice president of communications of
Arlington-based United Defense [UDI], a producer of combat equipment and
precision munitions. We are certainly answering more of their questions and
there are more calls coming in, Coffey said.

IPOs Evidence of Sector's Strength

Since last December, five Washington-area IT services companies have gone
public, according to New York-based IPO.com. United Defense went public in
December 2001, the only IPO in the industry last year, followed quickly this
year by Anteon International Corp. [ANT], SRA International Inc. [SRX],
Veridian Corp. [VNX] and ManTech International Corp. [MANT] Outside the
region

Re: Re: over-investment

2002-10-04 Thread Ian Murray


- Original Message - 
From: Ian Murray [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: Friday, October 04, 2002 12:19 PM
Subject: [PEN-L:30906] Re: over-investment


 over-investment
 - Original Message -
 From: Devine, James
 
 Can you find them?
 
 ==
 
 Give me a few and I'll fish 'em out.
 
 


http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/movable_type/archives/000802.html




Re: over-investment

2001-06-07 Thread Margaret Coleman

mutual funds.  maggie coleman

Jim Devine wrote:

 [was: Re: [PEN-L:12757] Re: Re: Re: Re: re: unemployment rate]

 The story below describes the kind of over-investment process that I
 theorized in my 1981 Ph.D. dissertation (another unpublished ms.) as does
 the over-investment in movie theaters in recent years. In my dissertation,
 I described not only the microeconomic cases of individual markets but also
 how the individual markets interact with -- and reinforce -- each other as
 part of a macroeconomic over-investment process. Does anyone know of any
 other industries besides telecom and movies that underwent over-investment
 during the late 1990s and 2000?

 a key issue is what limits exist that cause over-investment to eventually
 collapse. In the business cycles of the 1950s until the 1970s, there's some
 evidence that it was supply-side effects, including wages rising relative
 to productivity and raw materials prices rising. My impression is that the
 late-90s boom was more a matter of investment getting out of line with
 non-debt-driven consumer spending, as I hypothesize happened in the late
 1920s. Labor costs rose in the late 1990s, but not enough to put a serious
 squeeze on profits.

 Michael Perelman wrote:
   Elstrom, Peter. 2001. Telecom Meltdown. Business Week (23 April): pp.
  100-10.
 105: The model for how to make a fortune in the new world of telecom
  was set by one oft-forgotten telephone company: MFS Communications
  Co.  Led by James Q. Crowe, MFS laid telephone lines around major cities
  that would allow long-distance companies to bypass the Baby Bells.  By
  the time the Reform Act passed in 1996, MFS had networks in most of the
  big cities in the U.S., and WorldCom agreed to buy the company for a
  staggering $14 billion, only slightly less than what SBC had paid for
  Baby Bell Pacific Telesis Group earlier that year.  What WorldCom was
  paying for was not
 an operating business but strategic assets that would save it hundreds of
 millions of dollars it otherwise would have paid the Bells to deliver
 calls.  The figure that stuck out for every would-be telecom entrepreneur
 was that WorldCom paid more than six times the value of the assets MFS had
 put in the ground.
 105: The math was simple. You didn't need to build a business. You
  just needed to raise money, put telephone lines in the ground, and you
  could make a bundle. Some giant would pay you a multiple of every dollar
  you invested. The MFS model seemed to work for the next couple of years.
  In 1997, WorldCom bought another competitive upstart called Brooks Fiber
  for about $7 billion, or nine times the company's assets in the
  ground--the property, plant, and equipment.
 105: When Net mania hit in the late 1990s and data traffic started
  doubling every few months, the telecom buildout became a
  free-for-all.  Companies such as XO Communications (XOXO) and Focal
  Communications (FCOM) sprang up to build local telephone networks
  throughout the U.S.  RSL Communications (RSLCF) and Viatel Inc. (VYTL)
  started building telecom systems in Europe.  Global Crossing (GX), Flag
  Telecom (FTHL), and others started stringing fiber-optic cables through
  the world's oceans to carry the booming data and voice traffic.  At the
  same time, megacarriers were
 investing heavily: WorldCom, for example, was building its own
 metropolitan phone networks from Stockholm to Madrid.  All told, telecom
 players worldwide have raised $650 billion in debt and equity since 1996,
 according to Thomson Financial Securities Data.
 105: In their rush, many execs built less-than-steady foundations for
  their companies.  Rather than sell stock, they found the quickest way to
  get capital was to issue junk bonds.  It was high-yield heroin, says
  Royce J. Holland, former president of MFS and now CEO of Allegiance
  Telecom Inc. (ALGX), which provides voice and data services to
  businesses.  You didn't need to do a road show with investors.  You just
  had a conference call and you could get a few hundred million
  bucks.  While having debt equal to a company's equity value is
  reasonably healthy, telecom
 upstarts took on debt that was 5, 10, or even 20 times their equity.  They
 figured the more they could invest, the higher the price a giant would pay
 for their company.
 105-8 [sic]: Last year, the signs of trouble began.  With so many
  networks being built on both sides of the Atlantic, prices started to
  tumble.  Howard Jonas, CEO of international phone company IDT Corp.
  (IDT), estimates that an STM-1 -- a phone line that can carry 576
  conversations at once -- between the U.S. and Britain costs $1.8 million
  today, down 85% frrom $12 million in 1999. Prices have gone through the
  floor, says Jonas.  Why?  The economics of telecom are very similar to
  those for the railroad industry: Once you sink the money into the ground,
  it costs almost
 nothing to provide the service.  If there's a glut

over-investment

2001-06-06 Thread Keaney Michael

Michael P. wrote:

Movie theaters are an interesting example.  The new ones had better
features, so the old ones had to rennovate.  The new ones expected to be
able to capture the market, which everyone had overestimated. 
 -- 

Screens need silver lining

Due to an excess of theatres, many cinema chains are being threatened with
bankruptcy 
Norma Cohen, Financial Times, Jun 01 2001 00:00:00

Kevin Nunnink, chairman of property consultancy Integra Realty Resources,
thought it incredible that the cinema industry went on a five-to seven-year
building binge. It's almost incredible that nobody ever thought through the
implications, he said 

Given the swingeing losses caused by over-lending to real estate in the late
1980's, surely financiers would have been cautious about this property type
as well. 

Evidently not, the data suggest. 

Currently, there are 15 US cinema chains seeking protection from creditors
under the US bankruptcy code - including eight of the 10 largest operators -
while others are teetering on the brink. So far, an estimated 4,600 of the
US's 37,100 theatres have been closed and far more are slated to go. 

In Europe, where many US cinema operators have tried to establish a beach
head, the problems are far less severe. Nevertheless, there are signs that
Europe is not immune. 

Screen Digest, a magazine that tracks the film industry, notes that as of
last September, the UK had become the highest earning cinema market in
Europe. However, the strong growth in cinema openings has undermined sales
per screen, with the average falling below £50,000 in 2000 for the first
time since 1984. 

Tom Chandos, a non-executive director at Cine-UK and a non-executive at
shopping centres specialists Capital  Regional - host to a number of cinema
operators - says that expansion of cinemas in the UK has been aided by the
way they affect the economics of shopping centres. 

If you can get night-time footfall, he says, it can transform the
economics for food operators. With food operators in situ, shoppers view
the centre as more of a leisure destination rather than a mere convenience
centre. 

And cinemas, combined with the right food offering, allow shopping centres
to work 18 hours out of every day, rather than just 12. 

However, too many retail operators have had the same idea at the same time,
and because UK planners tend to view state-of-the-art cinemas as a kind of
social service provision, planning permission for new schemes with cinemas
has been relatively easier to come by, Mr Chandos says. 

However, Mr Chandos says the overbuilding is nowhere near that of the US
where the industry is in turmoil. In the US, that industry has hit the
buffers some time ago, he notes. The bankruptcy filings are the
aftershocks. 

But it is the bankruptcy filings that are finally dumping the woes of the
cinema industry into the laps of landlords. 

For with bankruptcy comes the opportunity for cinema operators to extract
themselves from unprofitable leases, leaving landlords with large, empty
space at regional malls that cannot easily be converted to other uses. 

So pressing is the issue of cinema operators, that a panel was devoted to a
discussion of how mall operators are coping in the present environment. 

Nuclear winter, was how one participant characterised the state of the
US's cinema theatre industry, telling his audience that conditions are
likely to remain that way for several years to come. 

What has happened in the US, in short, is that movie theatre chains have
been on a loan-induced development spree that has helped the number of
screens grow by 58 per cent. And while movie-going has risen, it has not
risen nearly enough to accommodate all that extra capacity. 

At the heart of the problem lies the modern megaplex, the movie theatre
large enough to accommodate 15, 20 or even 30 screens at a time. And it does
so in auditoriums with state-of-the-art seating, sound systems and
environmental control. 

Mr Nunnink says that lenders are partly to blame for the overbuilding in the
nation's cinema industry. Recalling the discussion panel on cinema
operators, Mr Nunnink says that one participant asked the audience - packed
with leading developers and financiers - how many had ever asked for, or
been asked for, a feasibility study for the opening of a new site. Not one
person had, he recalls. 

Lenders, he said, provided loans against the balance sheet of the theatre
operators, and did not consider the specifics of whether the new site was
viable. Anecdotal evidence, he says, suggests that lenders are now shutting
the barn door with a vengeance. Mall operators seeking to finance their
purchases are given little or no credit for the income generated by the
cinema on the site, he says. A mall yielding 11 per cent, for example, will
have the percentage of space occupied by the cinema treated as though the
yield were 15 per cent - meaning its capital value is reduced - and that is
for a healthy cinema. 

For malls 

Re: over-investment

2001-06-06 Thread Patrick Bond

 Date:  Tue, 05 Jun 2001 09:04:41 -0700
 From:  Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 a key issue is what limits exist that cause over-investment to eventually 
 collapse. 

Jim, here's a poli-econ answer from this neighbourhood. The case of 
Zimbabwe, a land-locked and historically ISI-oriented little economy, 
includes extreme bouts of overinvestment, dating back a century or 
so, in a highly-protected Dep't 2 (and to some extent Dep't 1 due to 
very heavy, capital-intensive mining operations). I did a PhD on the 
ebb and flow of overaccumulated capital (1900s, 1920s, 1950s, 1970s, 
1990s) into spatial and temporal fixes like the built environment, 
financial speculation and so on. (David Harvey was my supervisor.) 
The Zim case showed me a) a very meaningful proxy for 
overaccumulation in the productive sectors was the ratio of 
inventories (stocks) to output (once that ratio-signal rose to 150% 
of normal, it virtually guaranteed an investment strike); b) the 
displacement of overaccumulation into other investment outlets 
created all sorts of tensions that really only got resolved through 
the actions of various political blocs and the state (using, for 
example, extremely sophisticated kinds of fin-capital/trade 
regulation and directed investment); and c) even the heaviest-handed 
financial regulation couldn't prevent periodic (Kuznetsian) real 
estate and financial crashes, in approximately 15-30 year cycles. 
Once political blocs -- mainly associated with different fractions of 
capital -- realigned as a result of the economic tensions, the 
deadwood was invariably cleared away and a new round of accumulation 
could begin. The story is complicated by scale politics (Zimbabwe's 
periodic insertion and delinking from int'l circuits of K) but the 
data are pretty consistent and the political story holds up fairly 
well, I'd argue, even over traumatic incidents like the 1900s 
mineral-speculation crash, the 1930s Depression-related ISI upturn, 
the 1950s FDI boom, the mid-1960s Rhodesian Unilateral Declaration of 
Independence, the 1970s guerrilla war, the 1980s alleged turn to 
socialism, the 1990s neoliberal reversion, and the post-1997 
zigzagging associated with the nationalist rulers' exhaustion and 
desperation. So I talk in this thesis about uneven development of 
sector, space and scale, and how each gets amplified by rising 
financial circuitry in relation to productive circuitry...

Does that make sense?

Similar story in SA but of course much more complicated...




Re: Re: over-investment

2001-06-06 Thread Jim Devine

yes, this makes sense. Of course, over-investment in a dependent country 
such as Zimbabwe would be manifested differently than in the U.S. (though 
the latter is slowly becoming a dependent country itself).

At 09:09 AM 6/6/01 +, you wrote:
  Date:  Tue, 05 Jun 2001 09:04:41 -0700
  From:  Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  a key issue is what limits exist that cause over-investment to eventually
  collapse.

Jim, here's a poli-econ answer from this neighbourhood. The case of
Zimbabwe, a land-locked and historically ISI-oriented little economy,
includes extreme bouts of overinvestment, dating back a century or
so, in a highly-protected Dep't 2 (and to some extent Dep't 1 due to
very heavy, capital-intensive mining operations). I did a PhD on the
ebb and flow of overaccumulated capital (1900s, 1920s, 1950s, 1970s,
1990s) into spatial and temporal fixes like the built environment,
financial speculation and so on. (David Harvey was my supervisor.)
The Zim case showed me a) a very meaningful proxy for
overaccumulation in the productive sectors was the ratio of
inventories (stocks) to output (once that ratio-signal rose to 150%
of normal, it virtually guaranteed an investment strike); b) the
displacement of overaccumulation into other investment outlets
created all sorts of tensions that really only got resolved through
the actions of various political blocs and the state (using, for
example, extremely sophisticated kinds of fin-capital/trade
regulation and directed investment); and c) even the heaviest-handed
financial regulation couldn't prevent periodic (Kuznetsian) real
estate and financial crashes, in approximately 15-30 year cycles.
Once political blocs -- mainly associated with different fractions of
capital -- realigned as a result of the economic tensions, the
deadwood was invariably cleared away and a new round of accumulation
could begin. The story is complicated by scale politics (Zimbabwe's
periodic insertion and delinking from int'l circuits of K) but the
data are pretty consistent and the political story holds up fairly
well, I'd argue, even over traumatic incidents like the 1900s
mineral-speculation crash, the 1930s Depression-related ISI upturn,
the 1950s FDI boom, the mid-1960s Rhodesian Unilateral Declaration of
Independence, the 1970s guerrilla war, the 1980s alleged turn to
socialism, the 1990s neoliberal reversion, and the post-1997
zigzagging associated with the nationalist rulers' exhaustion and
desperation. So I talk in this thesis about uneven development of
sector, space and scale, and how each gets amplified by rising
financial circuitry in relation to productive circuitry...

Does that make sense?

Similar story in SA but of course much more complicated...

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




over-investment

2001-06-05 Thread Jim Devine

[was: Re: [PEN-L:12757] Re: Re: Re: Re: re: unemployment rate]

The story below describes the kind of over-investment process that I 
theorized in my 1981 Ph.D. dissertation (another unpublished ms.) as does 
the over-investment in movie theaters in recent years. In my dissertation, 
I described not only the microeconomic cases of individual markets but also 
how the individual markets interact with -- and reinforce -- each other as 
part of a macroeconomic over-investment process. Does anyone know of any 
other industries besides telecom and movies that underwent over-investment 
during the late 1990s and 2000?

a key issue is what limits exist that cause over-investment to eventually 
collapse. In the business cycles of the 1950s until the 1970s, there's some 
evidence that it was supply-side effects, including wages rising relative 
to productivity and raw materials prices rising. My impression is that the 
late-90s boom was more a matter of investment getting out of line with 
non-debt-driven consumer spending, as I hypothesize happened in the late 
1920s. Labor costs rose in the late 1990s, but not enough to put a serious 
squeeze on profits.

Michael Perelman wrote:
  Elstrom, Peter. 2001. Telecom Meltdown. Business Week (23 April): pp. 
 100-10.
105: The model for how to make a fortune in the new world of telecom 
 was set by one oft-forgotten telephone company: MFS Communications 
 Co.  Led by James Q. Crowe, MFS laid telephone lines around major cities 
 that would allow long-distance companies to bypass the Baby Bells.  By 
 the time the Reform Act passed in 1996, MFS had networks in most of the 
 big cities in the U.S., and WorldCom agreed to buy the company for a 
 staggering $14 billion, only slightly less than what SBC had paid for 
 Baby Bell Pacific Telesis Group earlier that year.  What WorldCom was 
 paying for was not
an operating business but strategic assets that would save it hundreds of 
millions of dollars it otherwise would have paid the Bells to deliver 
calls.  The figure that stuck out for every would-be telecom entrepreneur 
was that WorldCom paid more than six times the value of the assets MFS had 
put in the ground.
105: The math was simple. You didn't need to build a business. You 
 just needed to raise money, put telephone lines in the ground, and you 
 could make a bundle. Some giant would pay you a multiple of every dollar 
 you invested. The MFS model seemed to work for the next couple of years. 
 In 1997, WorldCom bought another competitive upstart called Brooks Fiber 
 for about $7 billion, or nine times the company's assets in the 
 ground--the property, plant, and equipment.
105: When Net mania hit in the late 1990s and data traffic started 
 doubling every few months, the telecom buildout became a 
 free-for-all.  Companies such as XO Communications (XOXO) and Focal 
 Communications (FCOM) sprang up to build local telephone networks 
 throughout the U.S.  RSL Communications (RSLCF) and Viatel Inc. (VYTL) 
 started building telecom systems in Europe.  Global Crossing (GX), Flag 
 Telecom (FTHL), and others started stringing fiber-optic cables through 
 the world's oceans to carry the booming data and voice traffic.  At the 
 same time, megacarriers were
investing heavily: WorldCom, for example, was building its own 
metropolitan phone networks from Stockholm to Madrid.  All told, telecom 
players worldwide have raised $650 billion in debt and equity since 1996, 
according to Thomson Financial Securities Data.
105: In their rush, many execs built less-than-steady foundations for 
 their companies.  Rather than sell stock, they found the quickest way to 
 get capital was to issue junk bonds.  It was high-yield heroin, says 
 Royce J. Holland, former president of MFS and now CEO of Allegiance 
 Telecom Inc. (ALGX), which provides voice and data services to 
 businesses.  You didn't need to do a road show with investors.  You just 
 had a conference call and you could get a few hundred million 
 bucks.  While having debt equal to a company's equity value is 
 reasonably healthy, telecom
upstarts took on debt that was 5, 10, or even 20 times their equity.  They 
figured the more they could invest, the higher the price a giant would pay 
for their company.
105-8 [sic]: Last year, the signs of trouble began.  With so many 
 networks being built on both sides of the Atlantic, prices started to 
 tumble.  Howard Jonas, CEO of international phone company IDT Corp. 
 (IDT), estimates that an STM-1 -- a phone line that can carry 576 
 conversations at once -- between the U.S. and Britain costs $1.8 million 
 today, down 85% frrom $12 million in 1999. Prices have gone through the 
 floor, says Jonas.  Why?  The economics of telecom are very similar to 
 those for the railroad industry: Once you sink the money into the ground, 
 it costs almost
nothing to provide the service.  If there's a glut, it's going to be 
brutal, says the University of Chicago's

Re: over-investment

2001-06-05 Thread Michael Perelman

Movie theaters are an interesting example.  The new ones had better
features, so the old ones had to rennovate.  The new ones expected to be
able to capture the market, which everyone had overestimated. 
 -- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Re: over-investment

2001-04-13 Thread Louis Proyect

that doesn't change anything: the competitive capitalist investment
process inevitably
produces crises. The companies have to provide attractive theaters, movies
that people
want to see, etc., if they want people to spend money at the concession
stands (where they
paid captive audience monopoly prices). 
-- Jim Devine

I wasn't trying to score a theoretical point. Just trying to provide some
interesting empirical background. I am heavily into facts.

Louis Proyect
Marxism mailing list: http://www.marxmail.org/




over-investment

2001-04-12 Thread jdevine

This afternoon, on US National Public Radio, there was an interesting story about the
process of over-investment in movie screens in the US. The movie theater chains were 
all
competing to introduce multiplexes into the many local markets. They introduced such
innovations as drink holders and stacked seating so that no-one could block anyone's 
view,
threatening to drive established theaters out of business. Many of the latter were in 
turn
forced to invest in similar improvements (in fear of going under). In the end, there 
are
many too many movie screens available (given the market) and the rate of profit fell. 
I'm
interpolating on the latter, since NPR didn't provide statistics, but such large 
chains as
Loewe's Cineplex have declared bankruptcy. It looks as if one third of the screens in 
the
US will have to be shut down -- a major shake-out -- to allow the achievement of normal
profits. 

Anyway, this seems like a classic example of a Marxian story of over-accumulation on a
microeconomic (industry) level. I'm sure that the desperate movie chains, now that 
they've
fouled their own nest, will try to get their employees to suffer the cost. Or they'll
continue the trend toward importing popcorn from Indonesia (or at least that's the way 
it
tastes) or follow Yahoo! into the porn trade.
-- Jim Devine



-
This message was sent using Panda Mail.  Check your regular email account away from 
home
free!  http://bstar.net/panda/




Re: over-investment

2001-04-12 Thread Louis Proyect

This afternoon, on US National Public Radio, there was an interesting
story about the
process of over-investment in movie screens in the US. The movie theater
chains were all
competing to introduce multiplexes into the many local markets. They
introduced such
innovations as drink holders and stacked seating so that no-one could
block anyone's view,
threatening to drive established theaters out of business.
-- Jim Devine

Keep in mind that the profits of the movie industry come almost exclusively
from concession rather than ticket sales. For a fascinating study of
Hollywood economics, see Wall Street Journal reporter Julie Salamon's
"Devil's Candy" about the Brian DiPalma fiasco "Bonfire of the Vanities".

Louis Proyect
Marxism mailing list: http://www.marxmail.org/




Re: Re: over-investment

2001-04-12 Thread jdevine

I wrote:This afternoon, on US National Public Radio, there was an interesting story
about the process of over-investment in movie screens in the US. The movie theater 
chains
were all competing to introduce multiplexes into the many local markets. They 
introduced
such innovations as drink holders and stacked seating so that no-one could block 
anyone's
view, threatening to drive established theaters out of business.

Louis writes:  Keep in mind that the profits of the movie industry come almost
exclusively from concession rather than ticket sales. 

that doesn't change anything: the competitive capitalist investment process inevitably
produces crises. The companies have to provide attractive theaters, movies that people
want to see, etc., if they want people to spend money at the concession stands (where 
they
paid captive audience monopoly prices). 
-- Jim Devine



-
This message was sent using Panda Mail.  Check your regular email account away from 
home
free!  http://bstar.net/panda/




over-investment

2001-01-18 Thread Jim Devine

[was: Re: [PEN-L:7101] Re: Predicting 9 of the last 3 recessions]

It's notable that Zarnowitz's theory and empirical observations -- which 
(except for that "natural" bit) are consistent with not only a lot of the 
pre-Keynesian mainstream and "Austrian" theory summarized in Gottfried 
Haberler's survey but also some versions of Marxian crisis theory -- 
conflict with the assertions of pen-l's Brad deLong, who rejects the 
phenomenon of over-investment. It would be interesting to hear Brad's 
critique of Zarnowitz.

  Victor Zarnowitz, a longtime student of the business cycle, said much of the
  problem was that forecasters had become prisoners of an economic ideology
  that assumed too much rationality on the part of the economic players or
  factors.
  .
  Thus, they spend too much time looking for recession indicators in official
  economic data, which often arrive too late to be of any use in forecasting,
  and not enough at the anecdotal evidence around them.
  .
  Mr. Zarnowitz starts from the assumption that there are natural ups and
  downs to the economy, dictated by the ability of businesses to find good
  things in which to invest.
  .
  At the end of a recession and at the beginning of a new expansion, there are
  plenty of low-risk, high-payoff opportunities and a rush of new investments,
  sparking a cycle of higher profits and greater investment that feeds on
  itself and pushes the economy higher.
  .
  At some point, however, the supply of "good" investments diminishes, Mr.
  Zarnowitz said. Businesses and investors then become overconfident and start
  paying too much for assets, assuming risks that are too great and taking on
  too much debt.
 .
[Starting with about the same model of the U.S. economy as Mr. Zarnowitz lays
  out, Mr. [Edward] Leamer last year went looking for conditions that 
appeared to
  be uniquely present at the end of expansions.
 .
  In each case, he found that investment spending was growing faster than
  profit. ...]
  .
  Finally, a tipping point is reached, and overconfidence gives way to an
  equally excessive pessimism, leading the economy to unwind quickly.
  .
  After a recession cleanses the economy of its excesses and imbalances,
  growth resumes.
  .
  On casual observation, this theory of investment booms and busts squares
  nicely with the run-up in the stock market that preceded the 1973 recession
  and the real-estate boom and bust before the 1990-91 recession.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine