The Seven Sisters

The Great Oil Companies and the World They Made

Anthony Sampson

Hodder and Stoughton, 1975, ISBN 0 340 19427 8

Chapter 11 - Part 1

The Crunch

The price of an article is exactly what it will fetch.
-- Marcus Samuel of Shell, 1911

AFTER the Teheran and Tripoli agreements, for the next two-and-a-half 
years, the companies were in trouble on three separate fronts. First 
the producers were demanding part-ownership of the concessions, or 
'participation'. Second, there were increasing signs of an oil 
shortage. Third, the Arab-Israel situation was again heading towards 
conflict. The convergence of the three was to produce the greatest 
crisis in the history of world oil.

Participation

For the more radical Arabs the whole concept of oil concessions -- 
which had been leased to the companies under quite different regimes 
and conditions for very long periods -- was increasingly 
unacceptable. The notion that a producing country was entitled to 
part-ownership of the concession -- as opposed to merely taxing it -- 
had been enshrined as long ago as 1920, as we have seen, in the San 
Remo agreement over Iraq, and ever since ignored. In the meantime the 
angrier radicals had favoured the more extreme course of wholesale 
nationalisation. But that drastic remedy, whether in Mexico in 1938 
or in Iran in 1951, carried the danger of excluding the producers 
from the oil markets. How could producers take over control, and yet 
remain part of the world market system? In the late 'sixties they 
began to concern themselves with the idea of gradual nationalisation, 
under the tactful slogan of 'participation'.

The chief advocate of participation was not one of the fiery 
extremists from Libya or Iraq, but the man who had been the special 
favourite of the oil companies, a graduate from Harvard, from the 
most conservative country of all. Sheikh Zaki Yamani of Saudi Arabia 
was to be the dominant figure in the next stage of the conflict. He 
had gained great confidence since he had first become King Feisal's 
oil minister in 1962. His old oil company friends, who used to regard 
him as a clever young protegˇ, now found themselves being kept 
waiting outside his huge office in Riyadh, or pursuing him as he 
flitted between capitals, exercising his growing power with obvious 
relish. He was quicker than most of them; with his sharp eyes, his 
Mephistophelean beard and his debonair style, he was like an 
unbottled genie from Arabia, impatient to take over from his master.

Yamani had been a director of Aramco since 1962, but his apparent 
involvement only made him more aware of his exclusion from the 
crucial decisions. As he put his case later, 'I want to know what is 
going on and I want to have a say in it. And that is what frightens 
them most.' (Leonard Mosley: Power Play, London, 1974, P. 395.) 
Yamani realised the dangers of abrupt nationalisation, and the need 
to maintain the orderly system of the oil companies; and in this he 
was at loggerheads with his predecessor Tariki, who was now advising 
other oil countries, and firmly advocating nationalisation. Yamani 
believed that the oil producers should gradually edge their way into 
the intricate world system, without disrupting it. The producing 
countries could take over a share of the oil, and could thus build up 
their own national oil companies -- Petromin in Saudi Arabia, KNPC in 
Kuwait, NIOC in Iran. In other words, OPEC would not beat the cartel, 
but join it.

Yamani had been interested in some form of participation for many 
years, but he first boldly proclaimed his policy in a seminar at the 
American University in Beirut in June 1968. It was in the wake of the 
humiliation of the Six-Day War, when the West was most sceptical of 
Arab effectiveness and Yamani felt the need for a militant 
initiative. He pointed out that many of the newcomers to the Middle 
East had agreed to various forms of partnership, and he warned the 
sisters: 'the June war, with all its psychological repercussions, has 
made it absolutely essential for the majors -- and not least Aramco 
-- to follow suit if they wish to continue operating peacefully in 
the area. Partnership with the host governments is a must; any delay 
will be paid for by the oil companies concerned.' (Middle East 
Economic Survey, June, 1968.) A meeting of OPEC in the same month 
duly endorsed the principle in a Declaratory Statement, that 'the 
Government may acquire a reasonable participation'.

But the oil companies were very far from agreeing. Some company men 
realised that their control could not last, but the sisters could not 
bring themselves to give anything up before they had to -- for the 
profits were still so vast that every extra day seemed worth hanging 
on to. Some ammunition to the Arabs was given in 1970 by the U.S. 
Department of Commerce. It estimated that the net assets of the 
petroleum industry in the Middle East were $1.5 billion, yielding 
profits of $1.2 billion, a return on investment of 79 percent -- 
compared to only 13.5 percent from smelting and mining industries in 
the developing countries. It was a calculation that was carefully 
noted by OPEC. (Abdul Amir Kubbah: OPEC Past and Present, Vienna 
1974, p. 78.)

Yamani saw the Saudis' position as being now so strong that they 
could get what they wanted; and in March 1969 he described 
participation to Richard Johns of the Financial Times, as creating a 
bond which 'would be indissoluble, like a Catholic marriage'. At the 
same time, he urged that participation would be in the interests of 
the oil companies. 'It will save them from nationalisation,' he 
explained at a seminar in Beirut, 'and provide them with an enduring 
link with the producing countries'. But some of the majors, he 
observed wryly, 'seem to be obsessed with the empire they have built. 
It is so vast and it took them so many decades to achieve. And now 
they see these newcomers -- these national oil companies in the 
producing countries -- wanting to come and take a piece of their 
cake, which is the last thing they want to happen.' (3rd Seminar of 
Economics of the Petroleum Industry, American University of Beirut, 
1969.)

It was not until after the Teheran agreement in 1971, when OPEC was 
stretching its muscles, that Yamani made much further progress. The 
Saudis again felt the need to show an initiative, after the success 
of the Shah, and the two chief oil producers were more than ever 
rivals for leadership. The Teheran agreement, binding for five years, 
appeared to leave no room for argument; but participation provided a 
field for demands outside the agreement. 'It was like labour unions', 
said one Dutch Shell director: 'when they've agreed about wages, they 
go for co-determination.' For the next two years the battle for 
participation took over from the battle for prices.

At the OPEC conference in June 1971 Yamani succeeded in convincing 
most other members, against the arguments of Tariki, that they should 
immediately demand a 20 percent share in the. companies' operations, 
to be gradually increased to 51 percent, with the assets to be paid 
for at 'net book value'. Later Yamani was put in charge of 
negotiating with the companies for all the Gulf countries. The 
companies on their side again resolved to stand together. John McCloy 
got special permission from the anti-trust chief, McLaren. The seven 
sisters and others met in London to decide on common tactics, 
renewing their agreement to share out their oil if one company was 
singled out.

The two sides were again heading for confrontation: the pace was 
quickening, and the more radical members of OPEC were determined not 
to be outdone.

Already in February 1971 Algeria, after bitter disputes about prices, 
had nationalised 51 percent of all French interest in her oil, thus 
dashing French hopes of a special connection. Now ten months later, 
just as OPEC was meeting again, the Libyans announced the 
nationalisation of all BP's assets, on the unconvincing grounds that 
Iran had just occupied three islands in the Persian Gulf that 
technically were under British protection; and that BP, because it 
was half-owned by the British government, must take responsibility. 
The nationalisations encouraged the other producers to be more 
militant.

In January 1972 OPEC met the companies again in Geneva. OPEC's first 
aim was to obtain more money because the dollar had been devalued: 
the companies quickly agreed to link the posted price to a basket of 
currencies, instead of the dollar, and thus put up the price by 8.5 
percent, which cost the consuming countries another $700 million a 
year for oil from the Persian Gulf alone. Then OPEC went on to demand 
participation in more detail: the companies soon bitterly complained 
about the terms, and the new battle began.

The prospect of participation placed the sisters in a much more 
exposed position, stuck in their no-man's-land between producers and 
consumers. Their problem was forcefully analysed by the oil 
consultant Walter Levy in New York, a man who from now onwards was to 
play an increasingly important role in oil policy. Levy had a very 
international background: he had been educated in Hamburg and worked 
as an oil journalist in London before moving to Washington during the 
war; and then set up as an independent consultant. He was now 
retained as adviser to all seven sisters, and to several governments. 
Writing in Foreign Affairs in 1971, Levy warned that participation 
was a grand design, in Yamani's mind, to 'bind the interests of the 
oil companies.' Levy predicted that 'the oil companies would be 
destined to become completely subservient to their host government.' 
They would thus face a major decision: 'to what extent and for how 
long they can be held hostage by their resource interests in 
producing countries ... It should now be recognised that their 
position as an internationally integrated private industry depends on 
a closer relationship and better understanding with consuming 
governments.'

The companies were already, as Sir Eric Drake put it in 1970, the 
tax-collectors of the producers; now they would be much closer 
partners. Professor Maurice Adelman of MIT, writing in 1972, accused 
them of being simply 'agents of a foreign power'. (Foreign Policy, 
New York, Fall 1972.) For a few oilmen participation appeared a worse 
evil than nationalisation, for it would impair their freedom of 
movement, and commit them to the producers' side: Sir David Barran of 
Shell (which had no huge Middle East concessions like the Aramco 
partners) said in April 1972 that nationalisation would be preferable 
to participation, which he regarded as 'intolerable'. But most of the 
companies, though they were to argue bitterly over terms, were 
inclined slowly to give way to participation; for it was still the 
crude oil that provided most of their profits. And they began to 
perceive that what mattered in a growing shortage was not so much who 
owned the oil, as who was able to buy it.

Aramco was now the critical battleground for participation; it was 
both on Yamani's home ground, and it was by far the richest prize in 
the Middle East. The four owner-companies -- Exxon, Texaco, Socal and 
Mobil -- were more thoroughly dependent on it as the shortage 
elsewhere was more pronounced, and for each of them Aramco was the 
source of 'the incremental barrel'. Since the 'fifties the Aramco 
company town at Dhahran had expanded into a settlement with every 
indication of permanence. Trees, gardens and two-storey houses had 
grown up inside the barbed wire, and the 'Aramcons' had become almost 
a separate breed. There was now a generation of employees who had 
been born and brought up in the desert. It had become a kind of 
symbol of the no-man's land of the oil companies, belonging to no 
culture and no country. Visiting it, I felt as if I were inside an 
idealised America, like an old cover of the Saturday Evening Post; an 
America untouched by the turmoil of the 'sixties, by long hair or 
drugs, with its citizens watching old movies on Aramco TV, playing 
baseball or mending their cars. To the Aramco engineers the compound 
offered not only fat salaries and early retirement, but a kind of 
engineer's utopia -- progress without politics, and technology 
without doubts. All around them the twisting pipes, the giant towers 
and flares were the monuments to their skills.

The Aramcons had done what they could to satisfy the Saudis. Ever 
since the early 'fifties, the headquarters of the company had been 
out in the desert, whither the directors would fly from New York or 
California. Saudi engineers lived alongside the Americans and 
hundreds of Saudis were sent to America for training. There were 
Saudi-pleasing public relations projects, and Aramco experts on Saudi 
culture, history and politics. The new president, Frank Jungers, had 
been in Arabia ever since graduating at Washington University, and 
his son was following him into Aramco. A stocky slow-speaking 
engineer, Jungers was essentially a pragmatist, talking about Saudi 
politics in the same matter-of-fact style as he talked about Aramco's 
great projects -- the unique installations, the 'first-time-built 
size-wise facilities'. His Texan-style house, with romanticised 
pictures of idealised Arabs on the walls, looked on to a bright green 
garden, with the desert beyond the wire: Aramco was his life, and 
Dhahran was his home. Jungers disseminated to the Saudis a quiet 
confidence in all things American. As one oilman described him: 'he's 
like W. C. Fields, who dropped out of the sky into the bed of a fair 
maiden, and reassured her in a state of shock: "Don't worry about a 
thing ma'am. I'm a citizen of the United States of America."'

Yamani began his negotiations withJungers early in 1972. The two men 
got on well, but in the background the owning companies -- 'the four 
neurotic parents' -- were standing fast. Yamani was exasperated by 
their stubbornness: 'It is always hard to be moderate,' he complained 
to a British visitor in January 1972, 'but it is particularly hard 
with American oil people, because they are apt to mistake moderation 
for weakness ... I am afraid that sometimes, when oilmen think only 
from a money angle, they get blind.' (Mosley, pp. 400-402.) Aramco 
put forward a rival proposition, that the Saudis could have a 50 
percent share in future developments, which Yamani quickly rejected.

Aramco also rashly tried to recruit the help of Washington, thus 
breaking the tradition of separation from government. Ken Jamieson, 
the Chief of Exxon, called on Nixon at the White House, who passed a 
message to Riyadh. Yamani, furious at the intervention, retaliated by 
recruiting the support of the King himself. The next day he read a 
stern message from His Majesty, with a clear threat of unilateral 
action. 'Gentlemen: the implementation of effective partnership is 
imperative, and we expect the companies to co-operate with us with a 
view to reaching a satisfactory settlement. They should not oblige us 
to take measures in order to put into effect the implementation of 
participation.'

Yamani warned that the producers 'must prepare for battle', and 
convened another extraordinary conference of OPEC. But on the eve, 
Aramco accepted the principle of immediate government participation 
of 20 percent. It was now the Americans who were making the mistake 
that they had attributed to BP in Iran twenty years before; of 
'failing to yield gracefully that which they were no longer in a 
position to withhold'. (Dean Acheson, quoting Burke: see Chapter 6.)

The next month Yamani continued his talks on participation in San 
Francisco with the Aramco sisters and BP and CFP. The diehard 
companies were still resisting, and Socal bluntly told Yamani that 
their share in Aramco was not for sale. There were more attempts at 
U.S. government pressure; John Connally, then Secretary of the 
Treasury, made a hawkish speech on April 18, saying that the U.S. 
would soon have to back up private corporations in dealing with 
foreign governments which controlled natural resources critical to 
America. The OPEC negotiators promptly warned that any such 
intervention would greatly complicate the participation negotiations. 
The State Department agreed with the companies that the Teheran 
agreement did not allow for participation; and they made 
representations through the Ambassadors in Iran, Saudi Arabia and 
Kuwait. But they eventually restricted themselves to protesting about 
compensation at book value, pointing out that future OPEC investments 
in the U.S. might meet a similar fate -- an issue which was 
eventually resolved with a complex compromise. (James Akins: Foreign 
Affairs, April 1971.)

Participation was now the catchphrase of the Middle East. The rich 
Sheikhdoms of Abu Dhabi, Qatar and Kuwait all soon wrested agreements 
for 20 percent ownership from the companies. And in Iraq the long 
arguments with the IPC, the grandfather of all the consortia, were 
reaching a bitter climax. The Iraqis were demanding a greater share 
in the revenue, participation in the concessions, and a guarantee of 
high production; they complained that the companies had been 
restricting production to punish Iraq for the past decade. (The 
Nationalisation of IPC's Operations in Iraq, Baghdad, 1974, p. 8.) 
Eventually in June 1972 Iraq finally nationalised the consortium, and 
soon afterwards agreed with the French company, CFP, to take its 
usual share of the nationalised oil. The Iraqis, in a time of 
shortage, could now play the French against the seven. The old 
warning of 'look what happened to Mossadeq' was no longer valid, as 
the nationalised companies showed they could operate their own oil.

Through 1972 Yamani went on bargaining with Aramco, who still 
resisted, and the King repeated his warning. Eventually in October 
the companies met in New York with the five Persian Gulf States, 
headed by Yamani, and reached a 'General Agreement', that they would 
give up 25 percent of the established concessions, rising to 51 
percent in 1983. The final agreement was signed at the end of the 
year in Riyadh.

But the Battle for Aramco still raged, now centring on the question 
of the price the four companies should pay for the oil that they 
bought back from the Saudi government's share -- the so-called 
'buy-back price'. Yamani knew that he now held the whip hand, and the 
four sisters, led by Exxon, could not risk a real showdown. For the 
Aramco board had now approved a plan to expand vastly the Aramco 
oilfields to provide for 13.4 million barrels a day by 1976, and as 
much as 20 million barrels a day by 1983. For this breathtaking 
prospect, even though it would be shared with the Saudis, the Aramco 
partners were prepared to yield over prices. Their greater fear was 
that the Saudis would sell their oil to other companies.

By December 1972 George Piercy of Exxon noted that Yamani was 
'prepared to relax and await capitulation' and recommended his 
colleagues to improve their offers. But Gulf, which was outside 
Aramco, was exasperated by the other companies' willingness to 'buy 
back at inflated and irrational prices'. Gulf did not have the same 
self-contained system of outlets as Exxon or Mobil, and was thus more 
concerned about price -- and about consumers. Their chairman Bob 
Dorsey protested to the team: 'your insistence on maintaining control 
of the oil for your own use has given strength to the OPEC position 
and has brought us to this point'. He went on with asperity to 
suggest that the prompt acceptance of higher prices 'might not prove 
acceptable to consumer interests'. (Multinational Report: 1975, p. 
136-7.) But Aramco was desperate to settle their access to the oil, 
and Gulf eventually had to negotiate an agreement in Kuwait similar 
to Aramco's.

Yamani could now divide and rule the sisters, as they had once done 
with him. Mobil, still hungry for crude oil, and more militant under 
the regime of Warner and Tavoulareas, was determined to get more than 
its 10 percent share of the 'buyback oil'. They were threatening to 
make a separate deal with the Saudis if their terms were not good 
enough, as the Socal negotiator, Jones McQuinn, anxiously observed 
(Ibid: p. 139-40), and Yamani could use the threat to extract better 
terms from the others.

The negotiations dragged on through the summer of 1973. Yamani 
refused to bargain on the buyback price, and at one point in August, 
he warned the Aramco team: 'don't be surprised if at any moment, I 
pick up the phone and instruct Brock or Frank [Brock Powers, chairman 
of the board of Aramco, and Frank Jungers, president of Aramco, see 
Multinationals Report, p. 138] to cut production to seven million 
barrels a day.' At last, on September 13, 1973, the Aramco partners 
gave in to Yamani's stiff terms -- a buyback price of 93 percent of 
the posted price -- which would soon increase the price to the West.

Yamani had got what he wanted -- a stake in the great concession. And 
the companies, having fought so long and ruthlessly, were now more 
relaxed about the new prospect. For participation now established a 
common interest between the companies and the producing countries, 
with both sharing the same interest in the orderly world market. It 
worked like the fifty-fifty tax deal twenty years earlier, but at a 
deeper level. The oligopoly of the companies had now been effectively 
joined by the oligopoly of OPEC.

------------

[continued: The Crunch - Part 2]

------------------------ Yahoo! Groups Sponsor ---------------------~-->
Buy Stock for $4
and no minimums.
FREE Money 2002.
http://us.click.yahoo.com/k6cvND/n97DAA/ySSFAA/FGYolB/TM
---------------------------------------------------------------------~->

Biofuel at Journey to Forever:
http://journeytoforever.org/biofuel.html
Please do NOT send "unsubscribe" messages to the list address.
To unsubscribe, send an email to:
[EMAIL PROTECTED] 

Your use of Yahoo! Groups is subject to http://docs.yahoo.com/info/terms/ 


Reply via email to