Krugman tries so hard to make his case that he ignores some other factors (perhaps even more controversial) that contribute to some of the new social developments that Krugman describes.  Unfortunately, I don't have time to comment on them, but they would not in any event cancel out the basic direction of socio-economic evolution that Krugman describes.~ams
-----------

http://www.nytimes.com/2002/10/20/magazine/20INEQUALITY.html

The New York Times Magazine

October 20, 2002

For Richer

By PAUL KRUGMAN

I. The Disappearing Middle

When I was a teenager growing up on Long Island, one of my favorite excursions
was a trip to see the great Gilded Age mansions of the North Shore. Those
mansions weren't just pieces of architectural history. They were monuments to
a bygone social era, one in which the rich could afford the armies of servants
needed to maintain a house the size of a European palace. By the time I saw
them, of course, that era was long past. Almost none of the Long Island
mansions were still private residences. Those that hadn't been turned into
museums were occupied by nursing homes or private schools.

For the America I grew up in -- the America of the 1950's and 1960's -- was a
middle-class society, both in reality and in feel. The vast income and wealth
inequalities of the Gilded Age had disappeared. Yes, of course, there was the
poverty of the underclass -- but the conventional wisdom of the time viewed
that as a social rather than an economic problem. Yes, of course, some wealthy
businessmen and heirs to large fortunes lived far better than the average
American. But they weren't rich the way the robber barons who built the
mansions had been rich, and there weren't that many of them. The days when
plutocrats were a force to be reckoned with in American society, economically
or politically, seemed long past.

Daily experience confirmed the sense of a fairly equal society. The economic
disparities you were conscious of were quite muted. Highly educated
professionals -- middle managers, college teachers, even lawyers -- often
claimed that they earned less than unionized blue-collar workers. Those
considered very well off lived in split-levels, had a housecleaner come in
once a week and took summer vacations in Europe. But they sent their kids to
public schools and drove themselves to work, just like everyone else.

But that was long ago. The middle-class America of my youth was another
country.

We are now living in a new Gilded Age, as extravagant as the original.
Mansions have made a comeback. Back in 1999 this magazine profiled Thierry
Despont, the ''eminence of excess,'' an architect who specializes in designing
houses for the superrich. His creations typically range from 20,000 to 60,000
square feet; houses at the upper end of his range are not much smaller than
the White House. Needless to say, the armies of servants are back, too. So are
the yachts. Still, even J.P. Morgan didn't have a Gulfstream.

As the story about Despont suggests, it's not fair to say that the fact of
widening inequality in America has gone unreported. Yet glimpses of the
lifestyles of the rich and tasteless don't necessarily add up in people's
minds to a clear picture of the tectonic shifts that have taken place in the
distribution of income and wealth in this country. My sense is that few people
are aware of just how much the gap between the very rich and the rest has
widened over a relatively short period of time. In fact, even bringing up the
subject exposes you to charges of ''class warfare,'' the ''politics of envy''
and so on. And very few people indeed are willing to talk about the profound
effects -- economic, social and political -- of that widening gap.

Yet you can't understand what's happening in America today without
understanding the extent, causes and consequences of the vast increase in
inequality that has taken place over the last three decades, and in particular
the astonishing concentration of income and wealth in just a few hands. To
make sense of the current wave of corporate scandal, you need to understand
how the man in the gray flannel suit has been replaced by the imperial C.E.O.
The concentration of income at the top is a key reason that the United States,
for all its economic achievements, has more poverty and lower life expectancy
than any other major advanced nation. Above all, the growing concentration of
wealth has reshaped our political system: it is at the root both of a general
shift to the right and of an extreme polarization of our politics.

But before we get to all that, let's take a look at who gets what.

II. The New Gilded Age

[T]he Securities and Exchange Commission hath no fury like a woman scorned.
The messy divorce proceedings of Jack Welch, the legendary former C.E.O. of
General Electric, have had one unintended benefit: they have given us a peek
at the perks of the corporate elite, which are normally hidden from public
view. For it turns out that when Welch retired, he was granted for life the
use of a Manhattan apartment (including food, wine and laundry), access to
corporate jets and a variety of other in-kind benefits, worth at least $2
million a year. The perks were revealing: they illustrated the extent to which
corporate leaders now expect to be treated like ancien regime royalty. In
monetary terms, however, the perks must have meant little to Welch. In 2000,
his last full year running G.E., Welch was paid $123 million, mainly in stock
and stock options.

Is it news that C.E.O.'s of large American corporations make a lot of money?
Actually, it is. They were always well paid compared with the average worker,
but there is simply no comparison between what executives got a generation ago
and what they are paid today.

Over the past 30 years most people have seen only modest salary increases: the
average annual salary in America, expressed in 1998 dollars (that is, adjusted
for inflation), rose from $32,522 in 1970 to $35,864 in 1999. That's about a
10 percent increase over 29 years -- progress, but not much. Over the same
period, however, according to Fortune magazine, the average real annual
compensation of the top 100 C.E.O.'s went from $1.3 million -- 39 times the
pay of an average worker -- to $37.5 million, more than 1,000 times the pay of
ordinary workers.

The explosion in C.E.O. pay over the past 30 years is an amazing story in its
own right, and an important one. But it is only the most spectacular indicator
of a broader story, the reconcentration of income and wealth in the U.S. The
rich have always been different from you and me, but they are far more
different now than they were not long ago -- indeed, they are as different now
as they were when F. Scott Fitzgerald made his famous remark.

That's a controversial statement, though it shouldn't be. For at least the
past 15 years it has been hard to deny the evidence for growing inequality in
the United States. Census data clearly show a rising share of income going to
the top 20 percent of families, and within that top 20 percent to the top 5
percent, with a declining share going to families in the middle. Nonetheless,
denial of that evidence is a sizable, well-financed industry. Conservative
think tanks have produced scores of studies that try to discredit the data,
the methodology and, not least, the motives of those who report the obvious.
Studies that appear to refute claims of increasing inequality receive
prominent endorsements on editorial pages and are eagerly cited by
right-leaning government officials. Four years ago Alan Greenspan (why did
anyone ever think that he was nonpartisan?) gave a keynote speech at the
Federal Reserve's annual Jackson Hole conference that amounted to an attempt
to deny that there has been any real increase in inequality in America.

The concerted effort to deny that inequality is increasing is itself a symptom
of the growing influence of our emerging plutocracy (more on this later). So
is the fierce defense of the backup position, that inequality doesn't matter
-- or maybe even that, to use Martha Stewart's signature phrase, it's a good
thing. Meanwhile, politically motivated smoke screens aside, the reality of
increasing inequality is not in doubt. In fact, the census data understate the
case, because for technical reasons those data tend to undercount very high
incomes -- for example, it's unlikely that they reflect the explosion in
C.E.O. compensation. And other evidence makes it clear not only that
inequality is increasing but that the action gets bigger the closer you get to
the top. That is, it's not simply that the top 20 percent of families have had
bigger percentage gains than families near the middle: the top 5 percent have
done better than the next 15, the top 1 percent better than the next 4, and so
on up to Bill Gates.

Studies that try to do a better job of tracking high incomes have found
startling results. For example, a recent study by the nonpartisan
Congressional Budget Office used income tax data and other sources to improve
on the census estimates. The C.B.O. study found that between 1979 and 1997,
the after-tax incomes of the top 1 percent of families rose 157 percent,
compared with only a 10 percent gain for families near the middle of the
income distribution. Even more startling results come from a new study by
Thomas Piketty, at the French research institute Cepremap, and Emmanuel Saez,
who is now at the University of California at Berkeley. Using income tax data,
Piketty and Saez have produced estimates of the incomes of the well-to-do, the
rich and the very rich back to 1913.

The first point you learn from these new estimates is that the middle-class
America of my youth is best thought of not as the normal state of our society,
but as an interregnum between Gilded Ages. America before 1930 was a society
in which a small number of very rich people controlled a large share of the
nation's wealth. We became a middle-class society only after the concentration
of income at the top dropped sharply during the New Deal, and especially
during World War II. The economic historians Claudia Goldin and Robert Margo
have dubbed the narrowing of income gaps during those years the Great
Compression. Incomes then stayed fairly equally distributed until the 1970's:
the rapid rise in incomes during the first postwar generation was very evenly
spread across the population.

Since the 1970's, however, income gaps have been rapidly widening. Piketty and
Saez confirm what I suspected: by most measures we are, in fact, back to the
days of ''The Great Gatsby.'' After 30 years in which the income shares of the
top 10 percent of taxpayers, the top 1 percent and so on were far below their
levels in the 1920's, all are very nearly back where they were.

And the big winners are the very, very rich. One ploy often used to play down
growing inequality is to rely on rather coarse statistical breakdowns --
dividing the population into five ''quintiles,'' each containing 20 percent of
families, or at most 10 ''deciles.'' Indeed, Greenspan's speech at Jackson
Hole relied mainly on decile data. From there it's a short step to denying
that we're really talking about the rich at all. For example, a conservative
commentator might concede, grudgingly, that there has been some increase in
the share of national income going to the top 10 percent of taxpayers, but
then point out that anyone with an income over $81,000 is in that top 10
percent. So we're just talking about shifts within the middle class, right?

Wrong: the top 10 percent contains a lot of people whom we would still
consider middle class, but they weren't the big winners. Most of the gains in
the share of the top 10 percent of taxpayers over the past 30 years were
actually gains to the top 1 percent, rather than the next 9 percent. In 1998
the top 1 percent started at $230,000. In turn, 60 percent of the gains of
that top 1 percent went to the top 0.1 percent, those with incomes of more
than $790,000. And almost half of those gains went to a mere 13,000 taxpayers,
the top 0.01 percent, who had an income of at least $3.6 million and an
average income of $17 million.

A stickler for detail might point out that the Piketty-Saez estimates end in
1998 and that the C.B.O. numbers end a year earlier. Have the trends shown in
the data reversed? Almost surely not. In fact, all indications are that the
explosion of incomes at the top continued through 2000. Since then the plunge
in stock prices must have put some crimp in high incomes -- but census data
show inequality continuing to increase in 2001, mainly because of the severe
effects of the recession on the working poor and near poor. When the recession
ends, we can be sure that we will find ourselves a society in which income
inequality is even higher than it was in the late 90's.

So claims that we've entered a second Gilded Age aren't exaggerated. In
America's middle-class era, the mansion-building, yacht-owning classes had
pretty much disappeared. According to Piketty and Saez, in 1970 the top 0.01
percent of taxpayers had 0.7 percent of total income -- that is, they earned
''only'' 70 times as much as the average, not enough to buy or maintain a
mega-residence. But in 1998 the top 0.01 percent received more than 3 percent
of all income. That meant that the 13,000 richest families in America had
almost as much income as the 20 million poorest households; those 13,000
families had incomes 300 times that of average families.

And let me repeat: this transformation has happened very quickly, and it is
still going on. You might think that 1987, the year Tom Wolfe published his
novel ''The Bonfire of the Vanities'' and Oliver Stone released his movie
''Wall Street,'' marked the high tide of America's new money culture. But in
1987 the top 0.01 percent earned only about 40 percent of what they do today,
and top executives less than a fifth as much. The America of ''Wall Street''
and ''The Bonfire of the Vanities'' was positively egalitarian compared with
the country we live in today.

III. Undoing the New Deal

In the middle of the 1980's, as economists became aware that something
important was happening to the distribution of income in America, they
formulated three main hypotheses about its causes.

The ''globalization'' hypothesis tied America's changing income distribution
to the growth of world trade, and especially the growing imports of
manufactured goods from the third world. Its basic message was that
blue-collar workers -- the sort of people who in my youth often made as much
money as college-educated middle managers -- were losing ground in the face of
competition from low-wage workers in Asia. A result was stagnation or decline
in the wages of ordinary people, with a growing share of national income going
to the highly educated.

A second hypothesis, ''skill-biased technological change,'' situated the cause
of growing inequality not in foreign trade but in domestic innovation. The
torrid pace of progress in information technology, so the story went, had
increased the demand for the highly skilled and educated. And so the income
distribution increasingly favored brains rather than brawn.

Finally, the ''superstar'' hypothesis -- named by the Chicago economist
Sherwin Rosen -- offered a variant on the technological story. It argued that
modern technologies of communication often turn competition into a tournament
in which the winner is richly rewarded, while the runners-up get far less. The
classic example -- which gives the theory its name -- is the entertainment
business. As Rosen pointed out, in bygone days there were hundreds of
comedians making a modest living at live shows in the borscht belt and other
places. Now they are mostly gone; what is left is a handful of superstar TV
comedians.

The debates among these hypotheses -- particularly the debate between those
who attributed growing inequality to globalization and those who attributed it
to technology -- were many and bitter. I was a participant in those debates
myself. But I won't dwell on them, because in the last few years there has
been a growing sense among economists that none of these hypotheses work.

I don't mean to say that there was nothing to these stories. Yet as more
evidence has accumulated, each of the hypotheses has seemed increasingly
inadequate. Globalization can explain part of the relative decline in
blue-collar wages, but it can't explain the 2,500 percent rise in C.E.O.
incomes. Technology may explain why the salary premium associated with a
college education has risen, but it's hard to match up with the huge increase
in inequality among the college-educated, with little progress for many but
gigantic gains at the top. The superstar theory works for Jay Leno, but not
for the thousands of people who have become awesomely rich without going on
TV.

The Great Compression -- the substantial reduction in inequality during the
New Deal and the Second World War -- also seems hard to understand in terms of
the usual theories. During World War II Franklin Roosevelt used government
control over wages to compress wage gaps. But if the middle-class society that
emerged from the war was an artificial creation, why did it persist for
another 30 years?

Some -- by no means all -- economists trying to understand growing inequality
have begun to take seriously a hypothesis that would have been considered
irredeemably fuzzy-minded not long ago. This view stresses the role of social
norms in setting limits to inequality. According to this view, the New Deal
had a more profound impact on American society than even its most ardent
admirers have suggested: it imposed norms of relative equality in pay that
persisted for more than 30 years, creating the broadly middle-class society we
came to take for granted. But those norms began to unravel in the 1970's and
have done so at an accelerating pace.

Exhibit A for this view is the story of executive compensation. In the 1960's,
America's great corporations behaved more like socialist republics than like
cutthroat capitalist enterprises, and top executives behaved more like
public-spirited bureaucrats than like captains of industry. I'm not
exaggerating. Consider the description of executive behavior offered by John
Kenneth Galbraith in his 1967 book, ''The New Industrial State'': ''Management
does not go out ruthlessly to reward itself -- a sound management is expected
to exercise restraint.'' Managerial self-dealing was a thing of the past:
''With the power of decision goes opportunity for making money. . . . Were
everyone to seek to do so . . . the corporation would be a chaos of
competitive avarice. But these are not the sort of thing that a good company
man does; a remarkably effective code bans such behavior. Group
decision-making insures, moreover, that almost everyone's actions and even
thoughts are known to others. This acts to enforce the code and, more than
incidentally, a high standard of personal honesty as well.''

Thirty-five years on, a cover article in Fortune is titled ''You Bought. They
Sold.'' ''All over corporate America,'' reads the blurb, ''top execs were
cashing in stocks even as their companies were tanking. Who was left holding
the bag? You.'' As I said, we've become a different country.

Let's leave actual malfeasance on one side for a moment, and ask how the
relatively modest salaries of top executives 30 years ago became the gigantic
pay packages of today. There are two main stories, both of which emphasize
changing norms rather than pure economics. The more optimistic story draws an
analogy between the explosion of C.E.O. pay and the explosion of baseball
salaries with the introduction of free agency. According to this story, highly
paid C.E.O.'s really are worth it, because having the right man in that job
makes a huge difference. The more pessimistic view -- which I find more
plausible -- is that competition for talent is a minor factor. Yes, a great
executive can make a big difference -- but those huge pay packages have been
going as often as not to executives whose performance is mediocre at best. The
key reason executives are paid so much now is that they appoint the members of
the corporate board that determines their compensation and control many of the
perks that board members count on. So it's not the invisible hand of the
market that leads to those monumental executive incomes; it's the invisible
handshake in the boardroom.

But then why weren't executives paid lavishly 30 years ago? Again, it's a
matter of corporate culture. For a generation after World War II, fear of
outrage kept executive salaries in check. Now the outrage is gone. That is,
the explosion of executive pay represents a social change rather than the
purely economic forces of supply and demand. We should think of it not as a
market trend like the rising value of waterfront property, but as something
more like the sexual revolution of the 1960's -- a relaxation of old
strictures, a new permissiveness, but in this case the permissiveness is
financial rather than sexual. Sure enough, John Kenneth Galbraith described
the honest executive of 1967 as being one who ''eschews the lovely, available
and even naked woman by whom he is intimately surrounded.'' By the end of the
1990's, the executive motto might as well have been ''If it feels good, do
it.''

How did this change in corporate culture happen? Economists and management
theorists are only beginning to explore that question, but it's easy to
suggest a few factors. One was the changing structure of financial markets. In
his new book, ''Searching for a Corporate Savior,'' Rakesh Khurana of Harvard
Business School suggests that during the 1980's and 1990's, ''managerial
capitalism'' -- the world of the man in the gray flannel suit -- was replaced
by ''investor capitalism.'' Institutional investors weren't willing to let a
C.E.O. choose his own successor from inside the corporation; they wanted
heroic leaders, often outsiders, and were willing to pay immense sums to get
them. The subtitle of Khurana's book, by the way, is ''The Irrational Quest
for Charismatic C.E.O.'s.''

But fashionable management theorists didn't think it was irrational. Since the
1980's there has been ever more emphasis on the importance of ''leadership''
-- meaning personal, charismatic leadership. When Lee Iacocca of Chrysler
became a business celebrity in the early 1980's, he was practically alone:
Khurana reports that in 1980 only one issue of Business Week featured a C.E.O.
on its cover. By 1999 the number was up to 19. And once it was considered
normal, even necessary, for a C.E.O. to be famous, it also became easier to
make him rich.

Economists also did their bit to legitimize previously unthinkable levels of
executive pay. During the 1980's and 1990's a torrent of academic papers --
popularized in business magazines and incorporated into consultants'
recommendations -- argued that Gordon Gekko was right: greed is good; greed
works. In order to get the best performance out of executives, these papers
argued, it was necessary to align their interests with those of stockholders.
And the way to do that was with large grants of stock or stock options.

It's hard to escape the suspicion that these new intellectual justifications
for soaring executive pay were as much effect as cause. I'm not suggesting
that management theorists and economists were personally corrupt. It would
have been a subtle, unconscious process: the ideas that were taken up by
business schools, that led to nice speaking and consulting fees, tended to be
the ones that ratified an existing trend, and thereby gave it legitimacy.

What economists like Piketty and Saez are now suggesting is that the story of
executive compensation is representative of a broader story. Much more than
economists and free-market advocates like to imagine, wages -- particularly at
the top -- are determined by social norms. What happened during the 1930's and
1940's was that new norms of equality were established, largely through the
political process. What happened in the 1980's and 1990's was that those norms
unraveled, replaced by an ethos of ''anything goes.'' And a result was an
explosion of income at the top of the scale.

(Continued)


Yahoo! Groups Sponsor
ADVERTISEMENT

Message from the Decline of Western Civilization List
Homepage: http://groups.yahoo.com/group/dowc-L
Subscribe: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Unsubscribe: [EMAIL PROTECTED]



Your use of Yahoo! Groups is subject to the Yahoo! Terms of Service.

Reply via email to