Sorry forgot the references!
Steve,
Well-met.
First time I came across Ilyenkov was in Mandel's The formation of the Economic Thought of Karl Marx.  Mandel wasn't very
enthusiastic about his work - more or less regarded Ilyenkov as just another
Stalinist apologist.  In the course of reviewing Marxist theory and its
relation to Vygotsky's work, about two years ago, I happened upon several
writers who regarded Ilyenkov as "the Marxist philosopher who fully
integrates Vygotsky's works into general theory."  Through the good services
of MIA and its extensive archive on Ilyenkov it's possible to do a very
thorough personal examination of Evald's writings. Then I ran into P Jones
articles (yeah the same ones you've read) and shortly thereafter joined the
XMCA CHAT site.

As you may recall, from my earlier messages, I regard Peter Jones strong
distinction between ideal objects and instruments of production etc. to be
most consistent with Marx's theory, and a more useful explanatory tool for
the kinds of work I do than the Bakehurst-Cole formulations.  P. Jones does
a very good job showing that Marx and Ilyenkov make a strong distinction
between social tools and tools of production, but he's considerably weaker
in demonstrating the importance of this distinction for the general theory
of political economy.  In the general theory the distinction between
instruments and subjects of production (which together comprise the "means
of production" and  as means of production joined with "labour" comprise
"forces of production) and "relations of production" (which are all those
social relations that concern social production, exchange, and distribution
of material wealth) is a critical feature of the dialectical analysis of
capital. After all it is the continual contradiction between ever developing
forces of production and the mode of production ( The method of producing
the necessities of life which is a unity of the forces of production and
"relations of production") that generates the normal revolutionary state of
political economic systems.

You may recall that one part of my recent critique of Paul Adler's
article "Rethinking Labor Process Theory" was that he did not consider the importance of the
revolutionary (if you are a proletarian you would probably rather call it
"counterrevolutionary,"  though in the larger picture most
"counterrevolutionary" strategies usually turn out to be as productive of
revolution as "revolutionary" ones do)  role of the "personal contract" in
the preservation of capitalist relations of production under conditions of
the growing socialization of labour in the productive process.  The
"personal contract" is a strictly social instrument that represents an
extensive collection of social relations ranging from the mutual obligations
between employee and employer, to the laws concerning rights of labour and
property, to the rights and obligations of citizens of the US of A
guaranteed by the Constitution of the United States of America etc. etc.
While Adler presents a very convincing argument concerning socialization of
labour, his analysis is incomplete because he misses the critical changes in
the social relations of production that have evolved through the
capitalists' efforts to preserve the modes of production of their
necessities of life   So the importance of the distinction between
instruments of production and the ideal objects that are the instruments of
social relations of production goes far beyond the issue of their immediate
referents or of the particulars of their construction and form.
Yours,
Victor

_______________________________________________
Marxism-Thaxis mailing list
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
To change your options or unsubscribe go to:
http://lists.econ.utah.edu/mailman/listinfo/marxism-thaxis

Reply via email to