<http://www.truth-out.org/dean-baker-why-didnt-we-make-these-guys-run-around-naked-their-underpants-over-their-heads/131585621>

Dean Baker: Why Didn't We Make These Guys Run Around Naked With Their 
Underpants Over Their Heads?

Wednesday 14 September 2011

by: Keane Bhatt, Truthout | Interview

Economist Dean Baker is co-director of the Center for Economic and 
Policy (CEPR) in Washington, DC. In his most recent book, "The End of 
Loser Liberalism: Making Markets Progressive," Baker argues that the 
market is politically structured to ensure that income flows upward.

He provides a range of strategies to reframe economic debates and 
offers proposals to reshape the economy to serve the interests of the 
majority of the population instead of a small elite. The book is 
available to be downloaded for free at CEPR's web site. 
<http://deanbaker.net/images/stories/documents/End-of-Loser-Liberalism.pdf>

Keane Bhatt: The prevailing economic model has been defended on the 
grounds of its dynamism and efficiency. But it's allowing 25 million 
people to be without adequate employment and 42 million to be on food 
stamps, while the private sector sits on $2 trillion in cash. There 
are millions of foreclosed homes standing idle despite the urgent 
need for decent housing. How do you evaluate this situation, where 
vast resources aren't being allocated efficiently in a time of such 
desperate poverty?

Dean Baker: There are two different issues, I think. One is the 
presumably short-term issue, but what's quickly turning into a 
long-term issue, of a serious downturn. The other is the more general 
issue of an efficient system with efficient outcomes. I don't think 
focusing on efficiency is a bad place to begin. My book argues that 
most economists are not honest about this. But in the short-term, 
which, as I said is becoming longer-term, efficiency is kind of moot. 
We have an incredible amount of idle resources and this is just 
totally self-inflicted stupidity. We know how to get out of this: we 
just have to spend money.

You can spend it on better or worse things, but it's really simple. 
You have a vast amount of idle workers, idle capacity and idle 
resources in just about every sector of the economy. So what you 
really need to do is spend money, have the Federal Reserve Board be 
more aggressive in its monetary policy and eventually we will have to 
get the dollar down to get something closer to balanced trade. That's 
the major imbalance in the US economy. But these aren't efficiency 
questions; it's a question of putting resources to use. There are 
political obstacles - there's nothing inherent in the economy. We 
weren't in this situation four years ago - there were plenty of 
problems in the economy, but huge amounts of idle resources were not 
one of them. But because of political obstacles, it's totally 
possible that we'll have a decade of high unemployment, vast amounts 
of idle resources and waste.

KB: Your book argues that financial crises don't have to lead to 
"lost decades" of massive pain and suffering and, even more 
importantly, that the US never even experienced a true financial 
crisis.

DB: There's a lot of real sloppy thinking here. The main promulgators 
of this view are Kenneth Rogoff and Carmen Reinhart and they say that 
they look back over 600 years of history and find that in almost all 
these cases, countries took over a decade to recover. It's painful, 
because I'd like to think - and one would expect that they'd like to 
think - that we know more economics than we did 600 years ago. If we 
don't - and we really haven't learned anything - why do you guys get 
paid high salaries? I say that only partially facetiously. If we were 
to look back through time, a very high percentage - probably the 
majority - of newborn babies didn't survive to age 5. You'd be an 
idiot to say that the past trend holds today - we have modern 
medicine, so we have a very good reason to expect that the 
overwhelming majority of children will survive to age 5. We have 
learned something in economics over six centuries, so it's not some 
curse, they're concrete problems.

Finance gets very mysterious and complicated. There are instruments 
that are hard for people to understand; they're hard for me to 
understand. The basic story is not complicated: we need demand. As I 
say in the book, there's very little about the financial crisis that 
explains where we are today. People who want to buy homes have no 
problem getting credit - you can't go 0% down, but someone who, say, 
15 years ago was able to get a home mortgage can expect to get a home 
mortgage today. In terms of businesses, the US, unlike Japan, has a 
very large capital market where firms can directly access capital 
through commercial paper and bond financing. The current rates are 
extraordinarily low in both nominal and real terms. So the idea that 
the banks being crippled would impede the economy doesn't follow when 
hundreds of the largest firms can go straight to the market and get 
financing.

Let's imagine that the big firms can get credit but the small ones 
can't. That would create a situation in which the big firms are 
running wild, grabbing market share at the expense of smaller 
competitors crippled by lack of access to capital. This is not 
happening.

There's a survey that the National Federation of Independent Business 
has done for a quarter century that asks businesses what are the 
biggest problems to expanding. And currently, almost no one mentions 
finance - either access or cost. So clearly the problem is not 
finance.

KB: They mention a lack of consumer demand, right?

DB: Consumption is still higher than normal as a share of income. The 
saving rate is just above 5 percent. Through the post-war years prior 
to the bubbles, it averaged over 8 percent. So there's zero evidence 
that finance is a real big obstacle in the economy today.

KB: So, apart from right-leaning economists who construe years of 
high unemployment as almost a natural law that the public must 
accept, there's also a tendency among liberals and even the left to 
view the problem as largely financial. There's little reference to 
the fallout of the $8 trillion housing bubble and resulting decline 
in wealth and spending. Why is this so widespread?

DB: I think there are very different rationales. For conservatives, 
or mainstream economists, saying there's nothing we can do about it 
creates very low expectations. They can say, "Don't be upset at us, 
that's the way of the world. Grin and bear it." They, of course, are 
not bearing it at all. They're employed at very well-paying jobs. 
Among the left, there's always been a catastrophe-strain which 
believes capitalism is a horrible system and there's nothing you can 
do about it. In my view, capitalism has all sorts of problems, but 
the reality is, that's what's there. Saying that it's a horrible 
system is fine, but that's what we have to work with. It can't be an 
excuse for inaction.

KB: Your book makes a strong case that the neoclassical school's 
appreciation of markets is mediated by power relations. For example, 
immigration quotas, which block freer movement of professional labor 
that would undercut overpriced US lawyers and doctors, are an 
unchallenged form of protectionism. At the outset of the 2008 crisis, 
however, it seemed that even this selective belief in efficient 
markets would implode. But it seems to stagger on as a zombie 
ideology - Alan Greenspan seems to have actually retracted his mea 
culpa for being so wrong in the past. Do you see any hopeful signs 
for a new, more accurate economics?

DB: It's been very interesting. I think part of it is that people are 
wrong to say it was free-market fundamentalism because it wasn't - 
they weren't being honest. So it gives Greenspan an easier out 
because it's a really confused ideology. If you're an honest Ayn 
Rander - and I'm not putting words in his mouth, she actually was 
Greenspan's hero and his book mentions how much he admired her - you 
would've expected this. What was going on? You had these Wall Street 
honchos that were stealing. They were stealing from everyone. 
Stealing from the people taking out bad mortgages; stealing from the 
people that bought these junk mortgage-backed securities; and they 
were stealing from their shareholders - that's because they were 
taking on enormous risk and a lot of shareholders like Bear Stearns 
and Lehman Brothers lost their shirts. But what would Ayn Rand say? 
These were supermen, they were great guys, they're not bothered by 
that. So Greenspan should've expected this. If the cops - and he's 
the cop - are on the sidelines saying, "Go ahead: steal, steal, 
steal," well, what do you expect? These brilliant guys who are out 
for themselves are going to steal and that's exactly what happened.

Part of the point of the book, I think, is to clear up some confusion 
here. We were not living in a world of laissez-faire. These guys were 
in a situation where they were allowed to steal by state structures 
like the implicit guarantee of too-big-to-fail, which basically gave 
them the green light. And after the fact, nobody pays any 
consequences. There have been no serious investigations of 
higher-ups; only a few lower-ranking people here and there.

KB: Bernie Madoff stole from the rich, right?

DB: Yeah, so Madoff got it. But the people at Citigroup, AIG and 
Countrywide have largely gotten off. There was a civil suit against 
Angelo Mozilo of Countrywide and he ended up paying somewhere around 
$47 million to the Securities and Exchange Commission [SEC], but 
still walked away with hundreds of millions.

KB: And Goldman Sachs reached a relatively small settlement with the 
SEC that allowed them to deny any wrongdoing.

DB: It's sort of like being a bank robber, getting caught robbing the 
bank and giving back two of the 10 sacks of money that you stole. And 
then they tell you to go on. And that's the extreme case - most 
didn't even get punished at all. In the cases where you actually did 
have some legal action, it was less than a slap on the wrist because 
for the most part, they're still better off doing what they've done 
even after they're caught.

KB: One of the state structures that facilitated the ripe conditions 
for this robbery was the Federal Reserve, which plays a very 
prominent part of your book. Why are its decisions so important, yet 
so little known? You note that progressives "spend far more time 
arguing over jobs bills that will have a trivial impact on employment 
compared to the Fed's monetary policy," and "devote major lobbying 
efforts to tax or budget items that don't have a tenth of the impact 
on the debt as the Fed's decisions on its asset holdings."

DB: The Fed has the responsibility for maintaining growth and 
stability in the economy. As much as people complain about 
deregulation, the Fed had all the authority it needed to prevent this 
bubble. Greenspan just looked the other way. Either he didn't see it, 
or more likely, he thought it was cool. We'll find that out when we 
get all the minutes, but that's exactly what happened with the stock 
bubble. I remember hearing him give a talk in January 2004, where he 
was patting himself on the back, saying, "Yeah, we did the right 
thing with the stock bubble. We let it run its course and picked up 
the pieces." Then I went down to hear a talk by Ben Bernanke where he 
explained why we still had a 1% federal funds rate. And he said, 
"Actually, the labor market is still very weak," more than two years 
after the recession. So obviously it wasn't that easy to pick up the 
pieces but that's the lesson that Greenspan took away and so did most 
economists for that matter.

KB: You've attributed the Fed's willingness to "pick up the pieces" 
to a couple of factors, but what sticks out is that bankers, the 
Fed's primary decision makers, are "likely to be less concerned about 
a 1 to 2 percentage point rise in the unemployment rate than 
autoworkers, sales clerks, or custodians. It is unlikely that many 
bankers, or their friends and family members, will lose their jobs if 
the unemployment rate were to increase by this amount." And the only 
reason they tolerated a low interest rate after the tech bubble was 
that they knew a crushed labor force couldn't demand higher wages, a 
motor for inflation.

DB: That's right, because you did have the hawks of that day yelling, 
"What are you doing? A 1% interest rate?" And Bernanke said, "Look at 
the numbers - employment is weak." The point is that it was not an 
easy bubble to recover from, but that's the mythology and that's 
certainly what Greenspan was saying. But they had all the tools they 
needed to rein in the stock bubble. I've always emphasized that the 
Fed could have attacked the bubble but did nothing. At the most basic 
level I always ask, "Why didn't you even talk about the bubble?"

People love to ridicule that and I say, "Fine. Let him do it and see 
what happens." I really have a hard time believing that if 
Greenspan's staff had been putting out stuff along the lines of what 
I was writing, showing that stock prices were out of line with any 
plausible projection of profit growth - not mumbles of "irrational 
exuberance," but real documentation - that the Fed would have been 
ignored.

KB: Later, with the housing bubble, he defended it by saying that the 
unprecedented rise in housing prices was based on solid fundamentals.

DB: So he argued 180 degrees the wrong way. If he had clearly made 
the case again and again through speeches, testimony to Congress, 
Federal Reserve publications, people wouldn't have ignored that. They 
may not have agreed, but there was no argument on the other side. I 
challenged the chief economists at Fannie, Freddie, the Mortgage 
Bankers Association; I was in the middle of this and no one had any 
arguments that held water.

In addition, he had enormous regulatory authority. He didn't exercise 
it and said, "We only control one-third of the mortgage market." This 
is nonsense stuff, because the Fed's regulations are the gold 
standard. If he had said, "Here are the mortgages that we think are 
okay," it's inconceivable that no one would care. Plus, all the other 
regulators looked to him. So the other regulatory bodies would have 
likely followed suit.

KB: So in your view, the housing bubble - the primary cause of the US 
economic crisis - could have been headed off by an active Federal 
Reserve, and all this without having to raise interest rates.

DB: I would say 99 percent for sure. If that were inadequate, yes, 
you raise interest rates and Greenspan has raised interest rates, 
like in 1994. I would be very, very reluctant to do that, because the 
economy was weak and it would mean raising the unemployment rate 
further. But it would've been better than where we ended up. I think 
almost certainly, though, it wouldn't have proven necessary if they 
had really used the authority they had to rein in the bubble.

KB: You write about how achieving low inflation - the reason the Fed 
raises interest rates - leads to greater unemployment. And while 
financiers would prefer to have lower inflation so the value of their 
assets doesn't depreciate, why is it that regular working people seem 
to support lower inflation in surveys, even if that means higher 
unemployment? Does this imply a need to better educate the public on 
this matter?

DB: Asking people what they think about inflation abstractly won't 
likely give you well-informed answers. People think of inflation as 
eating away at their wages. So if you ask, "Suppose you have 5% 
inflation but your wages grow 5% a year," people don't really 
conceptualize that.

What we can do is look at what actually happens in economies where 
wages are rising substantially and there's substantial inflation. And 
in those cases, incumbent parties tend to get reelected, which would 
suggest that they're not that upset about inflation. Most people 
don't have their nose in the books; they're not thinking carefully 
about all prices and wages rising together. They're just thinking, 
"I'll have to pay 5% for gas, food and rent," and that sounds really 
bad. So there are serious limitations to doing surveys in that way.

This has been less of an issue lately, in terms of the Fed keeping 
the unemployment rate high, because we haven't had occasion. Bernanke 
has at least done the right thing - not as aggressively as he should 
- but he has been trying to spur growth. I wish he did a lot more but 
at least he's going in the right direction. But if you go back to 
1994, we literally did have this case. The unemployment rate fell to 
6% and that was almost universally seen as close to the floor that 
unemployment rate could hit without kicking off inflation. And they 
started to raise rates - the short-term interest rate rose from 3% to 
6% over the course of the year. And it absolutely slowed the economy. 
It was striking how little attention was paid to this effort, 
basically, to raise the unemployment rate, which is exactly what it 
was.

This is an example where a lot of people at the time were saying, "We 
have a great jobs program, we want to do this project and that one." 
But if Alan Greenspan has his foot on the brake, it doesn't matter 
how great your jobs program is. It might create jobs for those 
people, but that's at the cost to someone else, because Greenspan 
wants to see the overall unemployment rate at 6%. So you can help one 
group of people and it's good for them. But you won't bring down the 
unemployment rate as long as the Fed has a policy of making sure 
unemployment doesn't go below 6%.

To Greenspan's great credit, this is the one thing that he did that 
was 100 percent correct and against the consensus in the economics 
profession at the time: After he raised interest rates from 3% to 6%, 
the unemployment rate was still around 5.6% to 5.7% in the summer of 
1995. But the economy was very weak and was experiencing slow growth. 
And Greenspan lowered interest rates and had big arguments with 
Clinton appointees - good, smart economists like Janet Yellen and 
Larry Meyer, both Democrats - who argued that there would be too much 
inflation. They were both giving the absolute dogma of the profession 
and no one disputes this; I think all three have written about it. In 
the end, Greenspan carried the day because he was the Fed's chair and 
had a lot of standing and said, "I don't see inflation." He was 100 
percent right, he allowed the unemployment rate to fall not just to 
5%, but eventually to 4% and millions of people had jobs who wouldn't 
have had them otherwise. It was the only time since the early 1970s 
that the US experienced robust wage growth up and down the income 
ladder. But he went against the dogma within his profession and had 
you not had this quirky character - because whatever you say about 
Greenspan, he's not a mainstream economist - you wouldn't have seen 
this strong wage growth in the 1990s.

KB: You're one of a few Ph.D. economists who dismiss the nostrum that 
unemployment must be kept at some specified level, or inflation will 
ensue. You even say that economists don't even really understand the 
process by which inflation becomes a problem. Your colleague Ha-Joon 
Chang has also talked about how Asian countries, in developing into 
advanced economies, dealt with 20 percent inflation rates, which is 
just unfathomable within the economic orthodoxy. So, the Greenspan 
example is a case of competing priorities - basically a political 
choice about how many people should have jobs - and, therefore, it 
should be open to greater public debate and input.

DB: I would certainly think that it argues for that. And there's very 
little owning up in the profession that they had really blown it. 
Greenspan's view was certainly in the minority and liberal Democrats 
took issue with it. Paul Krugman has changed a lot today, but he 
wrote a piece in 1995 denouncing those skeptical of a predetermined 
point in unemployment - like, say, 5% - where going below that causes 
inflation. He called them "politically motivated hacks." He's moved 
to the left since then, but even back then, he was left of center in 
the profession. At the very least, that point where inflation rises 
is not stable, because we got the unemployment to 4% with little 
acceleration of inflation. There eventually was an uptick in 
inflation in 2000, but it was due to commodity prices in world 
markets; this had little to do with the unemployment rate in the US

As you try to look for evidence of higher inflation slowing growth, 
it's actually fairly weak. And given the deepness with which this 
view of maintaining 2% inflation is held, you'd think that there 
would be a large body of research that showed that things get really 
bad when inflation goes to 3% or 4%, because that's how central banks 
look at it. If the relationship were really so unambiguous that 
inflation at 5% is so bad - leaving aside Ha-Joon's example of 20% - 
it should be easy to show and the fact is, it's not. That doesn't 
rule out any negative effect, but it can't be nearly as bad as these 
people are claiming.

KB: In the book, you note that the Federal Reserve Transparency Act 
passed with a majority of Republican votes, but only a third of 
Democrats supporting it. Is this an example of loser liberalism?

DB: I think you have a lot of Democrats who buy into this idea that 
we should leave the operations of the economy alone and then, because 
we're good people, we'll redistribute some from the winners to the 
losers. That's my idea of loser liberalism: liberals help out the 
"losers." And in my book, I argue that it's really bad policy for a 
lot of reasons that conservatives raise: government programs tend to 
be bureaucratic, inefficient and prone to fraud. It's not the best 
thing to allow the market to generate extreme inequality and deal 
with poverty and ensuring health care to pick up the pieces after the 
fact.

And it's horrible politics. It creates this idea that the people who 
work hard are taxed to help the people who don't work hard and aren't 
successful. And I recognize that it's not the real story, but the 
point is that you're easily stereotyped and basically asking to be 
caricatured if you say, "We let the markets work and pick up the 
pieces afterward."

KB: You mention some very interesting examples of the economic crisis 
provoking a bit of a shake-up within the profession. The 
International Monetary Fund's (IMF) chief economist, Olivier 
Blanchard, has advocated targeting inflation at 4 percent. In your 
book, you say that finance nowadays "is not about allocating capital 
to its best uses or making savings more secure, it's about finding 
clever ways to rip off taxpayers, productive businesses and other 
actors. The economy will benefit from having less of this sort of 
inefficient rent seeking behavior. While this may have seemed like a 
radical assessment a decade ago, even the IMF now recognizes that ... 
governments should adopt policies to reduce the sector's size."

Even more fascinating is a study you cite by the Organization for 
Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), which found that in 
wealthy countries, "the number of patents per capita was the most 
important factor determining the extent to which income was 
redistributed upward from those at the middle and bottom to those at 
the top over the last three decades." This flies in the face of all 
the narratives of US inequality resulting from stiff global 
competition, which even President Obama has asserted.

DB: Olivier Blanchard has always been a very good economist and while 
he's certainly within the center of the profession, he's a creative 
thinker. What's surprising is that he says this as chief economist of 
the IMF. Not to say that it's been totally accepted - how many people 
within the mainstream of the profession have criticized the European 
Central Bank for raising interest rates during a downturn? They 
should have, but if they did, they did it very quietly, despite vocal 
criticism for other things.

It's great to get those voices out there, though. The IMF and other 
mainstream people are saying that there's a lot of rent seeking going 
on in the financial sector and we want it to be smaller. To my mind 
it's just common sense: finance is about directing capital from those 
who want to save to those who want to invest. You want a small sector 
- that's an efficient sector. So when it gets very big, there's a 
prima facie case that it's not efficient. What are they doing better 
to allocate capital? You'd be very hard-pressed to say that.

On the OECD, I should actually point out - and this is kind of fun 
because this is typical of economists - that their reason for 
correlating patents per person with inequality was actually to use it 
as a measure of technology. So it's one of these great stories where 
what they were saying was, "There's a very strong correlation between 
technological progress and inequality, so it's really technology to 
blame." Well, patents are most immediately a measure of ... patents. 
And presumably patent rents. So it may or may not have anything to do 
with technology, and I, of course, would be very skeptical, because 
at the end of the day, technology doesn't depend on patents - it 
depends on your ability to increase productivity. So why not just use 
a direct measure like productivity or multifactor productivity? My 
guess is they didn't use them because it didn't show the results they 
wanted and neither of those measures appears in their regressions. So 
in any case, I was very struck by the result but they weren't 
interpreting the result the same way I was.

KB: Why is it that so many academics in the profession - experts in 
labor and macroeconomics - insist on cutting social programs despite 
the economic contraction that will inevitably result? The former 
Chair of the Council of Economic Advisers to Obama, Christina Romer, 
was considered the progressive end of the spectrum during her tenure 
there. But she strongly agreed with the Bowles-Simpson proposal, 
which would cut Social Security, a program that is legally prevented 
from having any impact on the budget deficit.

DB: She was playing the progressive role in the administration, but 
it's a deeply held view among economists. She's very much a consensus 
figure. There's a sloppiness there and you'd think that someone like 
Romer would know better, but when you lump Social Security together 
with Medicare and they're totally different stories. The numbers are 
unambiguous: Medicare goes through the roof because of health care 
costs and for those who say it's unsustainable, of course it is. The 
answer is we have to fix health care. If you were to privatize health 
care and leave the system as is, you'd be telling tens of millions of 
people that they're not getting health care. The Congressional Budget 
Office estimated that the Paul Ryan plan, which proposed that, would 
add $34 trillion to the cost of Medicare over their 75-year planning 
horizon in 2011 dollars. That's real money, about 6% of GDP over this 
period.

Social Security goes from 4% of GDP to 6% of GDP - it's hard to see 
that as an intolerable burden, considering that we increased defense 
spending by that much from 2000 to 2003 when we had peak wartime 
spending and we're still at that level. I won't say that it had no 
impact on the economy, but I don't think anyone with a straight face 
can say it devastated the economy. The cost increases that are 
associated with aging are easily manageable - not trivial - but 
easily manageable. The costs associated with health care are 
enormous, but that's a different issue.

KB: Can you explain how our privatized medical system, which costs 
twice as much as those of other advanced countries and performs worse 
on basic health indicators, ends up affecting the public budget?

DB: In the US, there is a very small public health care system - the 
Veterans Administration and some public hospitals - but the vast 
majority of our health care system is private. So when we look at the 
big public sector programs, Medicare and Medicaid, the vast majority 
of what they pay is to private providers. So if they have to pay more 
to doctors and pay more for various medical tests and drugs, all that 
goes to the private sector. So the story is that there are massive 
run-ups in private sector costs and at this point a little more than 
half of all health care is paid for through the public sector, so 
it's a huge burden on the budget. But again, it's the private sector 
that's driving that, because they're buying health care in the 
private sector.

KB: In your book, you write that "as the debate over President 
Obama's health care reform bill made clear, there is no realistic 
prospect of fixing the domestic health care system given the current 
distribution of power in the United States." You outline a detailed 
proposal that uses free trade in medical services to lower the 
bloated costs in the US, instead of advocating an efficient 
single-payer system found most everywhere else. So, are you fleshing 
out your model that thoroughly so that progressives adopt it at some 
point, or just to better illustrate the hypocrisy in market-oriented 
ideology?

DB: First and foremost, it's to illustrate the hypocrisy, because 
people have to get over the idea that somehow the winners won because 
they're smart, work hard and so on. That could well be true - I'm 
sure most doctors are smart and do work hard - but that's not why 
they came out ahead. It's because they cheated. So we have to make 
that really clear: they're not free traders, they're protectionists. 
There's no doubt about that.

That said, there are ways to take advantage of this. So medical trade 
is an example. People are already doing this and they'll continue, 
given the alternative. It's not ideal, but if you have a medical 
procedure that costs $200,000 in the United States and you can go to 
a modern facility in India or Thailand and have it done for $20,000 
or $30,000, that's great. It's a horrible way to get health care - 
it's absurd - but that's the world we live in. That's a great way to 
put it in peoples' faces: picture a lot of people who go overseas to 
get their care receiving $50,000 from their insurance policy, because 
their insurance company shares the savings with them. That rubs it in 
your face that we don't have the best health care system in the world 
because people are voting with their feet. So we have to try to find 
ways to create openings.

Back in the mid-1990s, there were complaints that we were getting too 
many foreign physicians practicing in the country and it was driving 
down the wages of doctors. There were a few pieces about it in the 
New York Times and the Washington Post and I'm sure others. And what 
was fascinating were the two sides of the debate. One side said they 
were driving down the wages of doctors and the other side said, "No, 
no, these foreign doctors are serving inner-city areas, rural areas 
and places native-born doctors don't want to go to." There was no one 
making the economist's argument: "Yeah, they're driving down the 
wages of doctors and that's good! It lowers costs for everyone." 
What's funny is, I've raised this with trade economists and 
invariably, they look at me and ask me, "What are you talking about? 
That has nothing to do with me." That speaks volumes about the 
profession, because if I were talking about a tariff on steel, they 
would know it inside out. Well, we spend a hell of a lot more money 
on doctors than on steel. So you would think they would want to know 
about that. 

KB: One of the other proposals that you outline in the book - 
eliminating pharmaceutical companies' temporary monopolies on drugs - 
would save $3.4 trillion over a decade, while repealing the Bush tax 
cuts for the rich would provide only $680 million during the same 
timeframe. While accepting your point about the need to correct the 
rigged outcomes of the economy that happen before taxes and 
redistribution, why not also advocate for the higher marginal tax 
rates of the Nixon or Eisenhower eras, especially if the alternative 
right now is borrowing from rich investors and paying them interest?

DB: As long as we're in a serious downturn, it's pretty hard to 
design taxes that are only going to hit people that aren't going to 
spend it. So you're almost certainly cutting into spending some. It 
matters much less if you tax Bill Gates and affect his spending as 
opposed to someone earning $100,000 a year. But it's very hard to 
design taxes where you're just going to hit Bill Gates. Because if 
it's just hitting Bill Gates, he'll move it. It's hard to have 
confiscatory taxes because you run into Constitutional issues, but 
also practical issues: at some point, Bill Gates will leave the 
country and his money will go with him, so you're not going to get it.

The other thing is, on the politics, I want to change the structures 
that allow these people to accumulate such enormous wealth. Bill 
Gates got to be enormously wealthy because we gave him the green 
light to make a mockery of antitrust law.

I remember when I first came to Washington, D.C., I was working at 
the Economic Policy Institute and got a call from a reporter who 
wanted to write a piece about an antitrust investigation on Gates. 
And the way this reporter described the issues to me, I said, "That 
can't be right." She said that Gates had been signing agreements with 
Compaq and Hewlett-Packard, the major computer companies at the time, 
where they would agree to pay him for every computer they shipped, 
whether or not it used DOS, the precursor to Windows. When I taught 
antitrust to undergraduates, the classic example was how John D. 
Rockefeller had the railroads pay him for every barrel of a 
competitor's oil that they shipped. People dispute whether it's true, 
but this was basically the same story: I was told that Bill Gates was 
having Compaq pay him for each computer that they shipped that had 
one of his competitors' software systems. I didn't believe it, but 
she said, "No, this is true," and she sent me all the documents on 
it. And it was in fact right.

They didn't end up bringing the case, they ended up dropping it and 
they got a settlement where Microsoft agreed to stop doing it. At 
this point, Bill Gates controls 90% of the computer market. So you 
just let this guy do the most blatant violation of antitrust law 
imaginable, secure a monopoly for all practical purposes and tell him 
not to do it again. I mean, come on, these are blatantly 
anticompetitive practices. You're much better off not letting the 
monopoly develop than thinking, "we've let the monopoly develop, now 
let's figure out a way to tax it."

KB: You attribute a lot of the problems that working people face in 
the US to "stupid policy" that's "self-inflicted." But stagnation, 
high unemployment and the destruction of social programs are welcomed 
by elite sectors, as long as corporate profits stay strong and wages 
stay low. There's no reason for them to worry about the lack of 
demand for their products and services as a whole, at least not yet. 
And as long as there's elite control over the political system, it's 
hard to see how all of this is "stupid" instead of intentional.

DB: Obviously there are powerful forces for these policies and people 
stand to gain. In the case of antitrust, Bill Gates gained enormously 
and was prepared to use whatever power he had. There are real forces 
behind this - no doubt about it. But it's important to understand 
where the points of vulnerability are. I don't expect to appeal to 
Bill Gates and have him say, "I'm a bad guy, I'm going to give up 
everything," but where we have force, we should use it in a way to 
make the most impact. I'm an economist down in D.C. and I didn't know 
that Bill Gates was using every slimy hook and crook in the world to 
build an illegal monopoly - not a clue.

And I can go on with a long list of things, so we can talk about 
NAFTA [North American Free Trade Agreement]. NAFTA and CAFTA [Central 
American Free Trade Agreement] were bad, I agree. They're about 
securing higher profits, not creating jobs - that's a joke and 
everyone knows it's a joke. But why not talk about lowering the value 
of the dollar? Insofar as we have power, we should focus on where we 
would expect to have a much bigger impact, if we got anywhere.

And some cases are so much more unambiguous: the Federal Reserve 
Board bailing out the big banks, for example. While we didn't want 
the financial system to collapse, why didn't we make these guys run 
around naked with their underpants over their heads? We could have 
kept Citigroup alive so we didn't have the cascade of collapses. But 
we could've said, "You're not going to be Citigroup anymore." And I 
don't mean changing the name, I mean changing the way it operated. We 
should have said, "You're not going to give your executives millions 
or tens of millions of dollars, you're not going to engage in 
speculation, we're restructuring you guys, and your choice is to take 
the money and do what we tell you, or go out of business and tell 
your shareholders why you cost them every last penny." And the 
shareholders won't be pleased because it's almost criminal.

We have to find where the pressure points are - it doesn't mean 
you'll win them, but at least if you do win them, you'll have done 
something. Whereas in other cases, we can defeat CAFTA and celebrate 
that - I think that would be a good thing; it's probably not good for 
us and more importantly, for Central America - but it's not going to 
accomplish very much.

KB: One of the points you've made for years and reiterate in this 
book, is the government's use of coercion to infringe on the liberty 
of workers to support one another. You write: "If the workers at a 
restaurant go on strike and then arrange for the Teamsters to refuse 
to deliver food to honor the strike, the restaurant can enlist the 
government to deliver injunctions and impose fines against the 
Teamsters. If Teamsters officials ignore the injunction (e.g., they 
don't tell their members that they cannot refuse to deliver food to 
the restaurant), they can face imprisonment."

As you lay out long-term proposals despite the current political 
obstacles to their implementation, would you consider shifting 
control over economic decisions from CEOs and shareholders toward 
those who work in productive enterprises and the communities in which 
they are situated? Would you advocate for abolishing corporate 
personhood and limited liability?

DB: There are several different issues here. I don't have a problem 
with corporations, but even Justice William Rehnquist, a very 
conservative judge, said they're creations of the government and we 
can do whatever the hell we want with them. And that's always how I 
understood them - they are creations of the government.

You and I could form a partnership and if we did something harmful 
like poison our neighbors, they could sue us and take everything we 
own. Being able to form a corporation, so that we could say, "No, you 
can take the corporation but we're okay" - that's government 
involvement. The government is constitutionally obligated to endow 
something it creates with the same rights as an individual. That 
strikes me as pretty bizarre, so I think that's a really, really 
strange ruling that goes against a lot of conservative legal doctrine.

When I raised the issue of corporate governance in my book I didn't 
get too in-depth, because I'm not an expert on it. My point is that 
the issue of corporate governance should be understood as a problem 
of government. You allow CEOs to pick the people who will determine 
their pay and the CEOs give them $300,000 a year to be directors and 
come to meetings four times a year? Why aren't libertarians all over 
this? This is not the free market, this is incredible corruption.

And we don't let corporations do whatever they want - there are 
elaborate rules in corporate governance, most of them designed to 
protect minority shareholders. So we can't take over 50-plus-1 
percent of IBM and tell the other 49 percent that they're screwed. We 
don't allow a purely free market for obvious reasons. We want to 
maintain a sound capital market. You don't have nearly the same 
problem in East Asia or Europe of runaway executive salaries, but in 
the US, we've created this situation where you have this incredible 
bloat where basically the CEOs are running the show for their own 
benefit. That's a governance problem, not an issue of the free 
market, and that's how this issue should be understood.


_______________________________________________
Biofuel mailing list
Biofuel@sustainablelists.org
http://sustainablelists.org/mailman/listinfo/sustainablelorgbiofuel

Biofuel at Journey to Forever:
http://journeytoforever.org/biofuel.html

Search the combined Biofuel and Biofuels-biz list archives (70,000 messages):
http://www.mail-archive.com/biofuel@sustainablelists.org/

Reply via email to