I've taken the liberty to forward this article,
it is interesting for those on this list, who think
a reform in land-price could solve all our problems,
and also some critique of the Malthusian crowds.
Eva


------- Forwarded Message Follows -------
Date:          Mon, 23 Mar 1998 21:13:23 +0200
Reply-to:      [EMAIL PROTECTED]
From:          [EMAIL PROTECTED] (Louis Proyect)
To:            Multiple recipients of list <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
Subject:       Karl Marx's contribution to ecological thought

Status:   

John Bellamy Foster has been doing some very interesting research into
the question of whether Marx was an ecological thinker. He gave a
presentation on his findings at the Socialist Scholars Conference this
weekend at a panel titled "Marx's Contribution to Ecological Theory."
What follows is a report on John's talk, peppered with my own
observations.

There are 3 takes on this question. Some view Marx as explicitly
anti-ecological. This is the case for social ecologists like John
Clark and certain "brown Marxists." Others think that Marx had some
interesting observations on environmental questions, but they were
sidebars rather than essential features of his thought. Finally, there
are people like Michael Perelman and John Foster who make the case
that the ecological dimension to Marx's thought is central.

The attempt to bring Marx's ecological dimensions into the foreground
have only gathered momentum over the past five years or so. When the
modern ecology movement first took shape in the late 1960s, the
analysis tended to be of a "post-materialist" character. It saw the
ecological crisis in the framework of the "affluent society." This is
understandable since the long boom of the post-WWII period tended to
accentuate problems of this nature. Pollution was related to the
indulgences of a consumer society and the eco-socialist critique--such
as it was--had a strong Frankfurt orientation. The solution was to
moderate the out-of-control growth of consumerist societies rather
than to address underlying questions of political economy. Also, the
debate was framed in terms of anthropocentrism versus eco-centrism.
Marx, it was argued, erred in the direction of anthropocentrism.

Since the 1980s, the classical Marxist approach has taken the
offensive. This has meant that economics plays much more of a role.
The accumulation of capital rather than cultural questions is central.
It has also meant that the problem is seen in global terms rather than
one isolated to affluent societies. The overarching concern is to
discover a form of sustainable development that takes environmental
justice into account. Poor nations should not make sacrifices on
behalf of rich nations. In rich nations, the poor and the racial
minorities should not bear the brunt of toxic dumping, etc. The only
solution, needless to say, is socialism which will bring economic
development under the rational control of the producers themselves.

The ecological crisis has prompted nearly every school of thought to
return to its ideological foundations in order to come up with a
solution. For neo-Classical economists, this means trying to bring
nature into the sphere of commodities. They argue that the problem is
that natural resources like soil and water are not properly priced. If
the same market laws that dictate the price of manufactured goods
operated in realm of nature, then the "invisible hand" would protect
such precious commodities as the soil and water.

For Marxists, an analogous effort has taken place, which seeks to
discover either explicit or implicit concerns with nature in the
central body of Marx's work. Foster has come up with some very
interesting insights into the rather explicit concern that Marx had
with the central ecological crisis of the 19th century: soil
fertility.

There is actually a long tradition of Marxist research into agrarian
questions going back to Marx and Engels. Lenin and Kautsky also wrote
important articles on the question. Michael Perelman, the moderator of
PEN-L, has also written on the topic: "Farming For Profit In A Hungry
World: Capital And The Crisis In Agriculture." I plan to read and
report on this book before long.

The context for Marx's examination of the agrarian question was the
general crisis of soil fertility in the period from 1830 to 1870. The
depletion of soil nutrients was being felt everywhere, as capitalist
agriculture broke down the old organic interaction that took place on
small, family farms. When a peasant plowed a field with ox or
horse-drawn plows, used an outhouse, accumulated compost piles, etc.,
the soil's nutrients were replenished naturally. As capitalist
agriculture turned the peasant into an urban proletariat, segregated
livestock production from grain and food production, the organic cycle
was broken and the soil gradually lost its fertility.

The need to artificially replenish the soil's nutrients led to
scientific research into the problem. Justin Von Liebeg was one of the
most important thinkers of the day and he was the first to posit the
problem in terms of the separation between the city and the
countryside.

While the research proceeded, the various capitalist powers sought to
gain control over new sources of fertilizers. This explains "guano
imperialism," which I referred to in my post on Peru the other day.
England brought Peru into its neocolonial orbit because it was the
most naturally endowed supplier of bird dung in the world. In 1847,
227 thousand tons of guano were imported from Peru into England. This
commodity was as important to England's economy as silver and gold
were in previous centuries.

There was also a desperate search for bones. Over a ten year period,
the value of English imports rose from 14,000 pound sterling to
254,000. Raiding parties were dispatched to battlefields to scavenge
bodies of dead soldiers. Their bones were desperately needed to
replenish sterile soil.

The United States followed suit. There had been a big crisis in
upstate NY and the mid-Atlantic states in the mid 1800s. This prompted
Congress to pass the "Guano Act" of 1856, which eventually led to the
seizure of 94 islands in the Pacific Ocean, rich sources of guano.

Von Liebeg theorized that such measures would eventually fall short.
Even with such substitutes, the soil tended to lose its nutrient
properties so long as the artificial divide between town and
countryside was maintained. Not only was the countryside losing its
productivity, the town was being swamped with human waste which was no
longer being recycled. London had such a terrible problem with open
sewers that Parliament was forced to relocate to a location outside
the city during the summer months. The stench was unbearable.

The neo-Classical economists tended to view soil fertility as a given,
like some kind of natural law. Ricardo and Malthus both regarded it as
an exhaustible resource. Thus, the problem of overpopulation was
tightly coupled to the existing practices of capitalist agriculture,
which was to exploit the soil and then abandon it when it lost its
fertility. This has been the main character of Malthusianism until the
modern era. It accepts the limits imposed by the capitalist mode of
production as eternal.

Scientists like Von Liebeg, on the other hand, supported the notion of
soil improvement. This meant looking at the relationship between
society and nature in ecological terms. The solution to the problem
was the reintegration of the town and country. This overlapped with
Marx's own exploration of the problems in Capital. In volume three of
Capital, the discussion of farming is framed within this general
dialectic. Soil fertility could only be ensured over the long run
through the abolition of the capitalist system, which would allow food
production to take place along sound, ecological guidelines.

The concluding paragraphs of the chapter on "The Transformation of
Surplus Profit into Ground-Rent" in V. 3 of Capital are a succinct
description of the problematic:

"All criticism of small-scale landownership is ultimately reducible to
criticism of private property as a barrier and obstacle to
agriculture. So too is all counter-criticism of large landed property.
Secondary political considerations are of course left aside here in
both cases. It is simply that this barrier and obstacle which all
private property in land places to agricultural production and the
rational treatment, maintenance and improvement of the land itself,
develops in various forms, and in quarreling over these specific forms
of the evil its ultimate root is forgotten.

"Small-scale landownership presupposes that the overwhelming majority
of the population is agricultural and that isolated labour
predominates over social; wealth and the development of reproduction,
therefore, both in its material and intellectual aspects, is ruled out
under these circumstances, and with this also the conditions for a
rational agriculture. On the other hand, large landed property reduces
the agricultural population to an ever decreasing minimum and
confronts it with an every growing industrial population crammed
together in large towns; in this way it produces conditions that
provoke an irreparable rift in the interdependent process of social
metabolism, a metabolism prescribed by the natural laws of life
itself. The result of this is a squandering of the vitality of the
soil, which is carried by trade far beyond the bounds of a single
country.

"If small-scale landownership creates a class of barbarians standing
half outside society, combining all the crudity of primitive social
forms with all the torments and misery of civilized countries, large
landed property undermines labor-power in the final sphere to which
its indigenous energy flees, and where it is stored up as a reserve
fund for renewing the vital power of the nation, on the land itself.
Large-scale industry and industrially pursued large-scale agriculture
have the same effect. If they are originally distinguished by the fact
that the former lays waste and ruins labour-power and thus the natural
power of man, whereas the latter does the same to the natural power of
the soil, they link up in the later course of development, since the
industrial system applied to agriculture also enervates the workers
there, while industry and trade for their part provide agriculture
with the means of exhausting the soil."

Louis Proyect

(John Bellamy Foster has launched a new journal called "Organization
and Environment" where many of these themes will be explored. I have
taken out a subscription and urge others to do so. Information on the
journal, including subscription rates, is at
www.sagepub.co.uk/journals/usdetails/j0151.html)



[EMAIL PROTECTED]

Reply via email to