> ----------
FYI
> From:         stu[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
> 
> DOWN AMONG THE ECONOMISTS 
> by Jonathon Rowe 
> Of the organized belief systems in America today, economics is surely
> among 
> the strangest - and economists themselves are even stranger. How such
> agile 
> and ambitious minds could drift so far out of touch with daily reality, is
> a 
> question which merits the attentions of our most astute psychologists. The
> 
> profession is like a cult of the highly IQd, and I've always wondered
> about 
> the strange rites and rituals that could enable their beliefs to persist. 
> So last winter, when I heard that the American Economic Association was 
> holding its annual meeting around the corner from my office, I felt a
> little 
> like an anthropologist who finds an encampment of aborigines in his back 
> yard. Would anyone raise questions about basic premises, as opposed to the
> 
> arcane mathematics of hypothetical markets and pecuniary gain? Would they 
> talk about the actual experience of ordinary Americans, or only
> abstractions 
> like "productivity" and "growth?" I never imagined they'd be talking about
> 
> me. Several months before, the Atlantic Monthly had published an article
> by 
> myself and two colleagues, Cliff Cobb and Ted Halstead, called "If the 
> economy is up, why is America down?" The article explored the paradox that
> 
> had befuddled the nation's policy establishment during the 1992 
> Congressional campaigns. The economy was doing well, by the conventional 
> reckonings - the GDP was up: people were supposed to be happy and
> fulfilled. 
> But they weren't. 
> In fact they were feeling pretty crummy. Alan Greenspan, America's
> economic 
> pontiff, expressed the high-level headscratching in a speech to a business
> 
> audience in San Francisco. Despite the economy's robust performance
> (again, 
> as economists define it) he said, "there seemingly inexplicably remains an
> 
> extraordinarily deep-rooted foreboding about the [economic] outlook" among
> 
> the populace. 
> What was really "inexplicable," we argued in the Atlantic article, was
> that 
> Greenspan and other economists can't see the obvious. Their reckonings are
> 
> archaic; and their very language tends to barricade their minds against
> what 
> is actually happening in the world. Prime evidence is how they measure 
> economic well-being: the gross domestic product or GDP. As have countless 
> others before us, we pointed out that the GDP is a Mad Hatter's accounting
> 
> system which adds but never subtracts. It lumps together just about 
> everything that happens in the economy (the monetized portion, at least) 
> under the archaic assumption that people become happier and better off 
> whenever money changes hands. If you have been maimed in a multicar wreck,
> 
> or gone through a grueling and costly divorce, or installed water filters
> in 
> your home because the water supply is so bad, then please take a bow. You 
> have caused economists to smile, and made your contribution to the GDP. 
> These people can't tell misery from well-being, only more from less. And
> on 
> top of that, we observed, economists can't even see the informal economies
> 
> of family and community at all, because no money changes hands. The
> kitchen 
> table becomes McDonald's, the watchful eyes of neighbors become burglar 
> alarms and police - the more the informal economy breaks down, and a 
> monetized "service sector" takes its place, the more the GDP goes up. 
> Meanwhile, society is literally falling apart. 
> We suggested that the American economy is approaching a turning point, if 
> it hasn't gotten there already. Increasingly the negative, or "illth,"
> side 
> of GDP seems to be outweighing the wealth. The fastest growing portions of
> 
> the US economy today include such things as crime and prisons, gambling, 
> disease, and entertainment. Is it any wonder, then, that "growth" doesn't 
> always leave people feeling that life is getting better? Yet economists 
> don't even have a language by which they can acknowledge - let alone
> measure 
> - this fact, which is obvious to just about everyone else. 
> There are economists who realize that the conventional belief system is 
> crumbling. Several purchased bulk copies of the Atlantic article for their
> 
> classes; one told us it prompted more class discussion than anything else
> on 
> the reading list. But all were not pleased, especially at the upper levels
> 
> of the profession, where stature and acclaim are bound up in the
> orthodoxies 
> we had questioned. Or so I gathered at the AEA session I dropped in on
> that 
> Saturday morning. 
> The session was called "Covering the Economy," and featured a panel of 
> reporters and the economists they often quote. 
> It got off to a promising start. Louis Uchitelle of the New York Times
> said 
> that journalists should endeavor to find out how people are actually
> faring 
> in the economy, as opposed to what economists are saying. More, he
> wondered 
> why reporters regularly quote Wall Street analysts without mentioning the 
> financial interests of the firms they work for. Brokerage houses spin the 
> economic news the way Newt Gingrich or the White House spin today's 
> Washington doings. Yet reporters treat them with a hushed and reverential
> awe. 
> Good question, I thought. I tried to imagine a story on energy in the 
> business section of the Washington Post: one of those ubiquitous Wall
> Street 
> "analysts" would be identified as, "affiliated with a brokerage house that
> 
> recently shorted utility stocks." That would rattle a few cages, I thought
> - 
> as well as tell us readers the truth for a change. I started to think this
> 
> session could get interesting, but not for long. A couple of other 
> journalists spoke, less pointedly than Uchitelle. Then it was Paul
> Krugman's 
> turn. 
> Krugman is an economist at Stanford University who is generally touted as 
> one of the new stars of the field. Newsweek cast him recently in an
> adoring 
> profile as a "great debunker" and "Nobel-bound." (The Nobel in economics 
> isn't really a Nobel; it was created by the Central Bank of Sweden to
> sound 
> like one.) Krugman is known as one who does not always suffer others
> gladly. 
> But with his restless mind and iconoclastic bent, I thought he'd be among 
> the first to want to turn the orthodoxies inside out. Instead, totally out
> 
> of the blue, he launched into a bilious tirade against the Atlantic piece,
> 
> the magazine itself and journalists generally. 
> The strangest part was the reason Krugman gave for regarding us as 
> "incompetents." He didn't address the major assumptions we challenged; for
> 
> example, that more monetary transactions and more stuff sold automatically
> 
> mean that people are better off, regardless what that stuff consists of
> and 
> its effects on peoples lives. He didn't try to explain why economists
> assume 
> that more driving, say, counts as economic advance but more walking does 
> not; that sales of white noise machines counts, but the serenity provided
> by 
> parks and open spaces does not. 
> Instead, he took issue with a point of methodology, in our rough-cut 
> alternative to the GDP: the way we had computed increasing inequity in the
> 
> distribution of income. Geez, I thought, is this the way the profession 
> works? Get into such a lather over one another's methodology that you
> forget 
> how to ask the basic questions? We never pretended that our draft 
> alternative to the GDP - the Genuine Progress Indicator or GPI - was 
> perfect. To the contrary, we said it was a first stab at trying to correct
> 
> the egregious deficiencies of the GDP. Weren't those worth at least
> talking 
> about? 
> Economists may preach the rigors of competition and open markets for the 
> rest of us. But they run their own profession more like a medieval guild. 
> They determine which articles get published in the prestigious journals. 
> They pass judgement on PhD and tenure candidates, and therefore decide who
> 
> gets to teach. It's a stitch listening to these people denounce 
> "protectionism," from the protected enclaves of their subsidized
> think-tanks 
> and tenured chairs, in a profession that makes the Japanese retail market 
> seem an exemplar of free trade by comparison. 
> Same thing with change. Economists may rhapsodize about its bracing winds 
> and creative destructions. But their own conceptual apparatus is stuck 
> deeper in the mud than a state-owned factory in the former Soviet Union.
> Few 
> fields that call themselves sciences have changed as little in their basic
> 
> premises. Krugman chastised the media for accepting our analysis 
> uncritically, the New York Times in particular. But that wasn't true. A 
> prominent Times business page columnist had raised a large eyebrow
> regarding 
> our GPI, quoting a Harvard economist. The piece that riled Krugman was by 
> Robert Hersey, an economics reporter, who went to Baltimore to see how the
> 
> assumptions underlying the GDP actually play out in peoples' lives. He
> found 
> people doing important work that isn't counted in the GDP because it's 
> unpaid; and others doing less important work in the monetized economy, who
> 
> do get counted in the reckoning of progress and growth. 
> Wouldn't it be something, I thought, if economists did that once in a 
> while; that is, tested their assumptions by looking at the lives of
> ordinary 
> people? Instead of just dumping on reporters. 
> A bit later, Lawrence Summers weighed in on Krugman's side. Summers is a 
> Harvard professor and an undersecretary at the US Treasury Department, and
> 
> he gave the conventional wisdom case a revealing twist. The situation in 
> economics today is much like that in medicine, he said. There are real 
> doctors, and then there are "quacks," and the media should do more to 
> distinguish the one from the other. The Atlantic had become a particular 
> fount of quackery, he said (though this might have been Krugman). 
> This crack was aimed not just at our piece, but also at previous ones by 
> James Fallows. Fallows, who has a degree in economics from Oxford, spent 
> several years in Southeast Asia studying the economies there. He came to
> the 
> conclusion that to chastise Japan and other Asian nations for violating
> the 
> principles of "free trade," misses the point entirely. People there simply
> 
> don't recognize the belief system called "free trade" - or the dogmas that
> 
> underlie it - as moral or scientific principle, he said. 
> Fallows went further. What American writers glibly refer to as
> "economics," 
> he observed, is really just Anglo-American economics. Elsewhere in the
> world 
> people do not regard Adam Smith and his intellectual successors as the 
> fountain of economic truth. They are disposed to ask, "What will work for 
> our nation?" rather than, "What did some dead British economist say?" 
> Fallows was doing to conventional economics what anthropologists and 
> sociologists did to Freudian psychiatry decades ago; he was showing that
> it 
> is a product of a particular time and culture, rather than universal and 
> irrefutable truth. This did not please the economics establishment; and 
> Fallows took a pounding. 
> But back to Summers. The medical profession was an odd choice for 
> comparison, I thought. The conventional medical paradigm of high-tech 
> "intervention" isn't exactly without critics these days - including 
> increasing numbers of MDs themselves. It is becoming a mounting financial 
> burden with no end in sight. Is that the best model for economics? Or is
> it 
> really the social status of doctors that economists find appealing? 
> Then it struck me: the road to this particular poorhouse is paved with 
> "GDP." Coronary bypass surgeries add significantly to the GDP, compared to
> 
> the simple diets and healthful living that help prevent them. Prozac adds
> to 
> the GDP, while eliminating the sources of depression in our lives might
> not. 
> It's understandable that economists would like a system like that; it is
> the 
> mirror image of their own assumptions. 
> By the same token, some of the most promising advances in healing have
> been 
> outside the conventional paradigm - and not coincidentally, also outside
> the 
> GDP. The evidence is growing for example, that nonphysical factors weigh 
> heavily in what people experience as bodily health - and especially 
> relationships with other people. Study after study has shown that people
> who 
> care about others, have good marriages, get involved in their communities 
> and the like, tend to live longer and experience less disease. 
> Dean Ornish, a prominent heart specialist at UCLA, instructs his patients 
> to do acts of kindness for one another. To restore a healthy heart, in
> other 
> words, they should strive to live in a good-hearted way. "Anything that 
> promotes a sense of isolation leads to chronic stress and often, to 
> illnesses like heart disease," Ornish has written. "Conversely, anything 
> that leads to real intimacy and feelings of connection can be healing in
> the 
> real sense of the word: to bring together, to make whole." 
> Consider that in relation to the conventional economic model. The 
> good-heartedness and sense of community that are crucial to health, barely
> 
> exist in mainstream economic thought. The basic molecule of that thinking
> is 
> homo economicus, the isolated little integer of self-seeking, who strives
> to 
> get as much as possible and give as little in return. What is called
> "market 
> economics" is really just the study of transactions between such 
> hypothetical integers - that is, between selfish strangers - for money. It
> 
> is the study of the kind of behavior which, if people like Ornish are
> right, 
> tends towards disease. 
> As Margaret Thatcher put it famously, expressing the fundamentalist market
> 
> view, society "does not exist." She really meant should not exist, because
> 
> people who don't relate as strangers, concerned only for their own
> personal 
> gain, impede efficiency and economic advance, as conventionally reckoned. 
> When Summers compared economics to medicine, I thought he was revealing a 
> lot more than he intended. The conventional economic model turns a 
> description of a hypothetical state of affairs into a prescription for an 
> actual one. It encourages a society in which people deal with one another 
> increasingly in this very way. The social cohesion of Main Street gives
> way 
> to the isolated consumerism of the Mall. The sense of connection between 
> locally owned firms and their communities gives way to the abstracted 
> calculations of global corporations. Shared civic spaces turn into the 
> solipsistic enclosures of television. Loneliness becomes epidemic in an
> era 
> that provides more means of supposed "communication" than any in history. 
> And loneliness makes people buy. Most people don't go to malls to buy 
> particular items; they go because it's a way of "alleviating loneliness," 
> "dispelling boredom," and "relieving depression," according to a survey of
> 
> studies in the Wall Street Journal. Economics becomes the means of
> creating 
> the hunger that cannot be filled; and economists, the ideological
> apologists 
> for this process. 
> Could it be that in industrial societies, human distress is increasingly a
> 
> form of iatrogenic disease - the doctors in this case being economists? 
> Could it be that the growth engine that pulls nations out of poverty, can 
> start to turn on itself and create new problems? Has the whole enterprise
> of 
> economics become a rigid calculus for solving yesterday's problems in a
> way 
> that helps create tomorrow's? 
> New problems, such as those of affluence, require a new calculus and
> higher 
> goals. Just maybe, I thought, economists are going to do some changing, 
> along with the rest of us. As the need for more stuff becomes less urgent 
> and the need for qualities such as stability and social cohesion become 
> greater, economists are going to have to outgrow their obsession with 
> pecuniary accretion - just as the factory workers they preach to will need
> 
> to learn new skills. 
> Edward Luttwak of the Center for Strategic and International Studies, a 
> conservative think-tank, broached this point recently in a panel
> discussion 
> in Harper's. "When a country is as rich in GNP and as poor in social 
> tranquillity as the United States," Luttwak said, "it makes no sense to 
> purchase more GNP through deregulation and increased efficiency, at the 
> expense of tranquillity. It's like a man with 24 ties and no shoes buying 
> himself another tie." 
> I sat there in the audience trying to formulate a reply along these lines.
> 
> But it was a large ballroom, with no mikes on the floor. It would have
> been 
> difficult to get a single point across, let alone a whole argument. So I 
> approached Krugman afterwards - taking a certain delight, I'll admit, in 
> introducing myself as one of the "incompetents" he had spoken of. (He
> didn't 
> know I was there.) "Well, I'm sorry," he said, in a way that made me
> wonder. 
> "But it's true." I tried to engage him in discussion, but he hurried off. 
> "I'm sorry, but I have to go to an interview," he said. 
> Jonathan Rowe is policy director of Redefining Progress in San Francisco 
> and a contributing editor of the Washington Monthly. 
> ================================================================== 
> 

Reply via email to