Karen,

Once again, we owe you for posting yet another excellent article. (I've
reformatted it slightly for readability and corrected the strokes that
became hyphens.)

I never voted for Thatcher in any of her three terms as Prime Minister
simply because I've never voted Tory at any time of my life because I
regard many of the Conservative Party party as either buffoons or crooks --
just as I still regard many of them today, in fact. But the Conservative
Party is more realistic about human nature than the Labour Party and also,
strangely, there is always a small number of intellectuals of the highest
standard in the Tory Party cabinet or shadow cabinet. In Thatcher's day we
had Joseph and Ridley. Today we have Oliver Letwin, to mention just one,
whereas the present Tory leader, Ian Duncan-Smith, is almost as dim as
Bush. Intellectuals of the stature of Anthony Crossland or Dennis Healey
(the latter still alive) come and go in the Labour Party. Today we have
none such in the Labour cabinet (though some regard Gordon Brown, the
chancellor, as one such).

And this, of course, is why so many men hated Thatcher. She was the
intellectual superior of any of her critics -- whether political opponents,
batallions of academics, or members of her own government. As related below
by Tim Congdon (one of our most respected economists), she was able to
confound what appeared to be the strongest expert criticism that any prime
minister has ever had to deal with. (I have to declare an interest because
I am a chemist by training, and so was she. I like to think that chemistry
and economics are similar subjects. They both depend basically on
thermodynamics and they both involve equilibria between, often many,
different forces.)

Anyhow, what Thatcher mainly did was to restore monetarism. Not monetarism
as the be-all and end-all of economics, but as the corrective for the ideas
of Keynes which, if carried to excess, as they were up to Thatcher's time,
are demotivating and, as such, dangerous in the life of any nation. But
this has not only been an intellectual victory confined to the pages of
economics journals and text books (even the latest editions of Samuelson &
Nordhaus and Mankiw now acknowledge Friedman and monetarism) but as a
practical programme for governments.

And privatisations are far from over. Soon there will scarcely be any
manufacturing industry or utility owned and run by governments in the whole
world. Even social democrats now regard the idea of civil servants running
these things as laughable. But there's much further to go in order to
correct the Keynesian turn that economics and politics took in the last
century. Health, education and pensions schemes run by government are
failing badly in most developed countries and, well within the lifetime of
my grandchildren, will have to go private. They will do so either because
they have become unmanageable, in the case of health and education, or
because they are broke, in the case of state pensions (which they already
are, actuarially, in most developed countries). 

KSH


At 19:30 10/02/03 -0800, you wrote:
In the current online edition of Foreign Policy magazine:
<http://www.foreignpolicy.com/issue_janfeb_2003/gns2.html>
(bottom half of the page) - KWC

<<<<<
A RUSTPROOF IRON LADY

By Timothy Congdon
(Journal of the History of Economic Thought, , Vol. 24, No. 3, September
2002, London)

How will history judge former Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher's changes to
British public policy in the 1980s? It is already clear that 21st-century
commentators will be kinder than her contemporaries were. When the
Conservative Party lost the general election to the Labour Party in 1997,
The Independent newspaper carried the banner headline, "Everything has
changed." In fact, surprisingly little changed. 

Labour did not reverse Thatcher's most distinctive reforms: privatization,
reduction of trade unions' power, and elimination of subsidies to
inefficient industries. Neither did it reintroduce exchange-rate controls
or the price and incomes policies her government scrapped in 1979. Rather,
the Labour government maintained existing income tax rates and endorsed
Thatcher's macroeconomic framework, wherein both monetary policy and a
prudent fiscal policy were aimed at combating inflation.

Astonishingly, newspaper columnists now refer to Labour Prime Minister Tony
Blair as "Thatcher's heir," and he does not seem embarrassed by this
description. The September 2002 issue of the Journal of the History of
Economic Thought carries a set of articles on "the political economy of
Margaret Thatcher." Given the extent of acceptance by former Thatcher
opponents, the papers seem curiously dated and negative in tone. Roger
Backhouse, a Birmingham University economist, provides the least hostile
assessment.

Many British economists in the early 1980s thought both Thatcher and her
monetary approach to inflation were mad, and 364 of them wrote a letter to
The Times in 1981 saying as much. Backhouse is more balanced. He sees the
radical post-1979 changes as an intelligible response to the policy
failures and macroeconomic instability of the 1970s. He also welcomes the
increasing productivity of Britain's manufacturing sector during the 1980s.

But his discussion of monetary policy -- supposedly such a crucial area of
what Thatcher wrought -- is too close to the conventional wisdom. It is
therefore uninteresting and largely wrong. Backhouse argues that the
government abandoned money supply targets because of the difficulty in
hitting them.

This comment is reasonable, but he is quite wrong to say that "monetary
aggregates lost their significance." As Geoffrey Howe, Thatcher's first
chancellor of the exchequer, noted in his own memoirs, the money targets
were met in his last year as chancellor (1983), and inflation rates had
come down as planned. Unfortunately, when Nigel Lawson (Thatcher's second
chancellor) dropped the broad money target in late 1985, money supply
growth in the following year accelerated sharply. Thatcher famously
insisted that she was "not for turning." But the sad fact is that Thatcher
-- or, at any rate, her ministers -- did make a U-turn, allowing rapid
money supply growth and therefore stimulating a silly boom and causing
inflation to rise to 10 percent in 1990.

The tragedy of monetary mismanagement in the late 1980s can be seen as a
sequence of squabbles between Thatcher and Lawson. But it is better
interpreted as the revenge of the 364 -- that is, a complete lack of
understanding among British economists of how money supply and the economy
interact. Backhouse also misses this connection. 

In another article, Joel Krieger, a Wellesley College political scientist,
looks at Thatcherism from a sociological standpoint. Krieger seems
nostalgic for the representation of trade union and senior business people
in the high-level corporatist bargaining seen in Britain in the 1970s.
Perhaps he thinks that the centralized determination of prices and incomes
is the best way to bring down inflation. Someone needs to tell him that no
one of any political significance in Britain today -- including Blair --
shares this nostalgia. For all the problems of the 1980s, those years
proved Thatcher was right on one point. Monetary policy, not incomes
policy, is the right way to control inflation.
--------
Timothy Congdon is chief economist of Lombard Street Research and is
currently writing a monetary history of the United Kingdom from 1945 to 2001.
>>>>

----------------------------------------------------------------------------
------------

Keith Hudson, General Editor, Handlo Music, http://www.handlo.com
6 Upper Camden Place, Bath BA1 5HX, England
Tel: +44 1225 312622;  Fax: +44 1225 447727; mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
________________________________________________________________________
_______________________________________________
Futurework mailing list
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
http://scribe.uwaterloo.ca/mailman/listinfo/futurework

Reply via email to