We have Karen to thank for bringing the following to our
attention. In my view it is quite the most interesting and thoughtful
economic discussion I have read in a long while -- a conversation ably
transcribed into readable form by Erika Kinetz (a difficult job, as
anybody who has done this will know!).
The interlocutors had enough on their plates in talking about the jobs
that are now leaving America and Europe for Asia to talk of other deeper
factors. In a way, China, India and the other south east Asian countries
have an easy job because they're playing catch-up. All they need to do
essentially is to produce orthodox goods and services for the West more
cheaply than we can make them and then supply their own consumer markets
which, being much larger than ours, will produce a new super-large brand
of multinational. Initially, as pointed out below, most of these will
remain headquartered in American and European countries (hopefully
swelling the funds of investors and pensions institutions over here) but
increasingly they will become indigenous.
Quite apart from the probability that all the developed and the
neo-developed countries will be draining the existing energy resources of
the world, there are two more big questions. The first is: Once the Asian
countries have caught up, will they have the innovative ability to start
supplying a new generation of consumer products? (We must remember that
America's economic success in the last century -- to a very considerable
extent -- has been due to being able to recruit the best brains of Europe
and, in recent decades, Asia. The former brain drain will undoubtedly
continue, but the latter will probably dry up in the coming years as
their own countries supply sufficient opportunities for research and
development.)
The second question is: "Can we be sure that developed societies
have the structural capacity to absorb further goods?" A corollary
to this is: "Will the initiatory class (the middle-class consumer
market with sufficient disposable incomes not in hock to the credit card
companies) have the time, energy or inclination to absorb more consumer
goods in their daily lives and thus set off another wave of
consumption?
Keith Hudson
<<<<
WHO WINS AND WHO LOSES AS JOBS MOVE OVERSEAS?
Erika Kinetz
The outsourcing of jobs to China and India is not new, but lately it has
earned a chilling new adjective -- professional. Advances in
communications technology have enabled white-collar jobs to be shipped
from the United States and Europe as never before, and the outcry from
workers who once considered themselves invulnerable is creating a potent
political force.
After falling by 2.8 million jobs since early 2001, employment has risen
by 240,000 jobs since August. That gain, less than some expected, has not
resolved whether the nation is suffering cyclical losses or permanent job
destruction.
Last month, The International Herald Tribune convened a roundtable
at the Algonquin Hotel in Manhattan to discuss how job migration is
changing the landscape.
The participants were Josh Bivens, an economist with the Economic Policy
Institute, a nonprofit research group in Washington that receives a third
of its financing from labor unions; Diana Farrell, the director of the
McKinsey Global Institute, which is McKinsey & Company's internal
economics research group; Edmund Harriss, the portfolio manager of the
Guinness Atkinson China and Hong Kong fund and the Guinness Atkinson Asia
Focus fund; M. Eric Johnson, director of Tuck's Glassmeyer/McNamee Center
for Digital Strategies at the Tuck School of Business, Dartmouth College;
and, via conference call from Singapore, Stephen S. Roach, managing
director and chief economist of Morgan Stanley . Following are excerpts
from their conversation.
Q. How big an issue is job migration?
MR. ROACH: Offshore outsourcing is a huge deal. We do not have a data
series called jobs lost to offshore outsourcing, but 23 months into the
recovery, private sector jobs are running nearly seven million workers
below the norm of the typical hiring cycle. Something new is going on.
America is short of jobs as never before, and the major candidates for
our offshore outsourcing are ramping up employment as never before. So
yes, I think two and two is four.
MS. FARRELL: This is a big deal in the sense that we see something
structural happening. But I would react to the notion that it is a big
deal that we should try to stop or recognize as anything other than the
economic process of change. I think the bigger deal is the fact that we
are going to have very serious curtailment of the working age
population.
MR. BIVENS: I'm curious about Steve's assertion that outsourcing
can explain the sluggish employment situation. If you just look at slow
growth plus fast productivity, you've got the sluggish labor market right
there.
MR. ROACH: A pick-up in productivity does not have to be
accompanied by sluggish employment. There are countless examples, like
the 1960s and again the 1990s, of rapid productivity growth accompanied
by rapid employment.
The point is that the relationship between aggregate demand and
employment growth looks to me as if it has broken down. That breakdown
reflects not just the rapid growth and maturation of outsourcing
platforms in places like China and India, but also the accelerated pace
by which these platforms can now be connected to the developed world
through the Internet. These are brand-new developments. This is a huge
challenge for service-based economies, like the United States.
MR. BIVENS: How much of the insecurity that people think is caused
by service sector outsourcing is in fact just the business cycle as
usual? Every time there's a recession people want to blame it on some
underlying structural factor, when sometimes recessions are just
recessions, shortfalls in demand that work themselves out.
MR. ROACH: Over the September to November period, employment has
turned up, but many of those jobs came from the temporary hiring
industry. These are service jobs, contingent workers without benefits and
significantly lower pay scales. We're getting the GDP growth, and by now
any recovery in the past would be flashing green on the hiring front.
This one isn't. With all due respect, I don't know what you guys are
talking about. This is a profoundly different relationship between hiring
and the business cycle. And I think these jobs are, by in large, lost
forever.
Q. Who wins in offshoring and who loses?
MS. FARRELL: There is an assumption by protectionists that these jobs
are going somewhere else, and all this money has been pocketed by CEOs
who take it home. A little more sophisticated version is: It's being
pocketed by companies in the form of profits. One step further and you
say those profits are either going to go as returns to the investors in
those companies, or they're going to go into new investment by those
companies. Those savings enable me, if I am an investor, to consume more
and therefore contribute to job recreation, and if I am a company, to
re-invest and create jobs. That's important because I agree that we are
migrating jobs away, some of which will never return, nor should
they.
MR. BIVENS: Within nations, trade tends to redistribute a lot of
income. The gains get pretty concentrated in the pockets of capital
owners. The people who lose out are the blue-collar workers. Now you've
got this class of white-collar workers who are much more insecure about
their job prospects, and their labor market bargaining power is being
undermined. It doesn't mean we need walls all around the economy, but it
does mean we need to get really serious about making sure all these gains
are distributed.
MR. HARRISS: Look at what's gone on in China over the last 10
years There are 300 million people in those eastern coastal provinces who
have seen an extraordinary pickup in their standard of living. And you're
seeing an economy that is just about to take wing because you now have
consumers who were never able to participate in the economy before. Now
it is people in the developed world who are being left behind. That is
very difficult to resolve.
Q. One key piece of the win-win theory seems to be that displaced
workers do find new jobs. What does history teach us about how well
displaced manufacturing workers have been reintegrated into the work
force?
MR. BIVENS: The best research on what happens to people displaced
from manufacturing is that they eventually find a new job, but they take
an average wage cut of 13 to 14 percent. The people who are hit hardest
are older workers. Also, it's not just the worker who is directly
displaced from a sector that is hurt by international trade, it is also
every other worker in the economy who has a similar skills
profile.
Q. For labor, is outsourcing a race to the bottom?
MR. ROACH: It's a race to the bottom if we spend all our energy
trying to protect existing sources of job creation, as the politicians in
the U.S. Congress are inclined to do. The problem is that globalization
is growing asymmetrically, so initially it creates more supply than
demand. We're living through that asymmetry right now, and that has
caused a potentially dangerous political backlash. The Chinese, for
example, are reluctant to transform their habits from savers to consumers
because they're losing jobs through the reform of their own economy, and
they don't have social security or retirement. Over time there is a
rising tide. But the political process is not that patient.
Q. If protectionism is the wrong answer, explain how the market will
solve this. Does government need to intervene at all?
MR. ROACH: This is classic election-year posturing by a Congress that
is basically responsible for the problem itself and doesn't want to admit
it. We have trade deficits with China and Japan because Washington is
running the most reckless fiscal policy we've seen in the United States
since the late 1960s. They are the problem. It's not the Chinas and
Japans and Indias of the world. Moreover, there are a lot of assumptions
being made, especially by political leaders, that the rapid growth of
Chinese exports and production is the smoking gun of the threat to
traditional sources of job creation. About two-thirds of the export
growth China has realized over the last 10 years has come from Chinese
subsidiaries of multinational corporations headquartered in Japan, the
U.S. and Europe and their joint venture partners. These are our
companies. It's us; it's not necessarily them.
MR. JOHNSON: It's all about innovation and productivity. As long
as we maintain those two engines, we'll continue to have a very high
standard of living. Out in the Bay Area there are plenty of folks who
would love to create a little bit of protectionism around their IT jobs,
but we are far better off letting a lot of those jobs go. Low-skill jobs
like coding are moving offshore and what's left in their place are more
advanced project management jobs.
MS. FARRELL: We will require different services, medical devices,
all kinds of things to support an aging population. Fifteen years ago,
you would not have been able to fathom many of the jobs that exist
today.
MR. HARRISS: There is not much new radical innovation in Asia of
the kind we're looking at to create jobs in the U.S. Apart from a very
few exceptions, what Asia does well is take the latest innovations and
production techniques, invest in the most recent equipment and then bring
in their powerful advantages in low-cost labor, and start to produce. For
the most part, the benefits to Asia are just going to come with more
people coming off the poverty line and into the global economy.
Q. What happens when China ceases to be an endless pit of
poverty?
MR. ROACH: China for all practical purposes has an infinite supply of
labor 400 million in its urban population and another 900 million in the
rural area. The average wage of a Chinese worker is still 2.5 to 3
percent of the counterpart in the developed world. Those are disparities
that will be around for a long time.
Q. Can China keep labor costs so low and still grow a critical mass of
domestic consumers?
MS. FARRELL: You are still talking about a pretty significant
critical mass of people who are now entering consumption level incomes
$7,000 to $10,000 GDP per capita. Car sales in China are growing at 26 to
30 percent compound annual growth rates. Televisions, refrigerators,
mobile handsets all have the same kind of J-curve. You only need 10
percent of the population to have a critical mass of income.
Q. What do you see in the future?
MR. BIVENS: Globalization is good at increasing the productive
capacity of the world, but to make sure there are enough jobs for
everybody, you need demand to keep pace with that increase in supply.
That's where globalization presents a real challenge. Government's big
roles in the future are to make sure global demand matches supply, and to
provide social insurance schemes to make sure the living standards of the
workers being left behind aren't sacrificed on the altar of global
progress.
MR. ROACH: In the future there are two roads. One is to look
backward and hang on to what we think we're entitled to. The other is to
recognize what has made America. Our virtues lie in a flexible and open,
technology friendly, risk-taking, entrepreneurial, market-driven system.
This is exactly the same type of challenge farmers went through in the
late 1800s, sweatshop workers went through in the early 1900s, and
manufacturing workers did in the first half of the 80s. We've got to
focus on setting in motion a debate that pushes us into new sources of
job creation rather than bemoaning the loss. There are Republicans and
Democrats alike who are involved in this protectionist backlash. They're
very vocal right now, and they need to be challenged.
New York Times -- 7 December 2003
>>>>
Keith Hudson, Bath, England,
<www.evolutionary-economics.org>
- RE: [Futurework] What happens when Asia has caught up? Keith Hudson
- RE: [Futurework] What happens when Asia has caught u... Cordell . Arthur