Click Image for Volume 18

http://www.acsu.buffalo.edu/~zarembka/Marx.htm

Research in Political Economy
Volume 18
Copyright: JAI/Elsevier Science,
Amsterdam and New York,
2000, pp. 3-39 (web publication
with publisher's permission)

VALUE, PRICE, AND PROFIT (Abridged):
An Introduction to the Theory of Capitalism
By Karl Marx (1865)
Edited by his daughter Eleanor Marx Aveling, abridged by Paul Zarembka[‡]


Abstract: Marx's 1865 lectures offer an easily accessible summary of
his theory, addressed to an English-speaking audience.  However, one
weakness preventing common usage (including classroom use) is the
dialogue in the first twenty pages with one John Weston.  This
abridged version stays with the exact words used by Marx, while
eliminating almost all reference to the dialogue with Weston.  The
currency of that time in its division into three units is also
decimalized into its modern form.  The result is more readable and
modern, yet completely faithful to Marx's presentation.



Table of Contents:

Preface, by Paul Zarembka
(Sections through Section V, abridged)
VI. Value and Labor
VII. Laboring Power
VIII. Production of Surplus Value
IX. Value of Labor
X. Profit is made by Selling a Commodity at its Value
XI. The Different Parts into which Surplus Value is Decomposed
XII. General Relation of Profits, Wages, and Prices
XIII. Main Cases of Attempts at Raising Wages or Resisting Their Fall
XIV. The Struggle between Capital and Labor and its Results
Typos in Printed Version

Preface
In June 1865, Marx gave two lectures which included many of the
theoretical propositions to be published two years later in Capital,
Volume 1.  These lectures were given in London in English but  not
published in Marx's lifetime.  In April of 1897, the text was found
among his papers by his daughter Eleanor Marx Aveling.  She felt that
it offered an easily accessible summary of Marx's theory which would
"make a very popular pamphlet" (letter to Karl Kautsky), and edited it
for publication.  However, she died shortly before its appearance.
Her husband Edward Aveling, an important socialist, provided a
"Preface" and indicated his own minor role of numbering and titling of
sections.  He had it published in London in 1898.

Aveling's "Preface" noted that the lectures demonstrate Marx's
"patient willingness to make the meaning of his ideas plain to the
humblest student, and the extraordinary clearness of those ideas."  He
also noted that "in a partial sense the present volume is an epitome
of the first volume of Capital.  More than one of us have attempted to
analyze and simplify that volume, with not too much success perhaps."
The text has, furthermore, the advantage of being written in English
so there are no issues concerning translation.

Nevertheless, two weaknesses have kept "Value, Price, and Profit" from
widely serving as an introduction to Marx's thought (including
classroom use).  First, the opening twenty some pages are written as a
polemic against the arguments of a specific individual, one John
Weston.  It takes some work to get past that dialogue.  Second, the
examples use the British currency of that time with its division into
three units: Pounds, shillings, and pence.  One partial solution is
simply to begin reading after the sections debating with Weston, the
solution chosen by Eugene Kamenka in his The Portable Marx.  But
earlier passages helping the context come alive and providing insight
into Marx's use of data are thereby excised.  And the difficulty
experienced by the modern reader with use of the old currency is
ignored.

I am offering an abridged version of Marx's text which stays with the
exact words used by Marx,  while eliminating almost all reference to
the debate with Weston.  For the examples in the text, the currency is
 modernized to its decimal equivalent, as mandated in February 1971 by
the British government.  The title has had added to it the words "An
Introduction to the Theory of Capitalism" to reflect the purpose of
this abridged edition.

Excised material is indicated by [...] and represents about 63% of the
first five sections.  From the Section VI beginning with "Citizens, I
have now arrived at a point where I must enter upon the real
development of the question" to the end of the text, no cuts have been
made.  The prior material is driven by the dialogue with Weston.  Yet
some passages here aid understanding and are kept. The subsequent
material  summarizes Marx's theory.  The latter is the part to which
Marx himself referred in writing Frederick Engels on June 24, 1865: it
"contains many new things in its second part -- in particularly
condensed, but relatively popular form -- which anticipates my book".

Where shillings and pence are used as subdivisions of the British
Pound, they are decimalized in accordance with the 1971 currency
change.  Twenty shillings had been one Pound and twelve pence had been
a shilling.  Afterwards, the shilling was eliminated and one hundred
new pence comprised a Pound (rather than 240 old pence for a Pound).1

Since "Value, Price, and Profit" has been widely republished in
slightly differing versions (even use of "Wages, Price and Profit" as
the title), we should note that the actual text drawn upon here is the
original edition published in London in 1898 by Swan Sonnenschein &
Co.  Our transcription of the text begins from a transcription of a
later edition done for the internet by Mike Ballard, May 5, 1995. That
transcription is compared to the 1898 London edition, errors  are
corrected (some not so obvious) and original paragraphing and original
capitalizations restored (e.g., "Value of Labor", rather than "value
of labor").  The two footnotes at the very beginning and the one
footnote at the beginning of Section VII are retained as in the
original.  Our few footnotes use 1, 2, 3, etc..

In the text, there are places where Marx uses "men" to refer to
working people.  Although today we would say "workers", or "working
women and men", it would be a stretch to rephrase Marx's usage.
"Addressed to working men" is omited from underneath Marx's name as it
had appeared on the title page of the original, 1898 edition (an
omission also made by other publishers).  Consistent with modern
usage, the two phrases, wages labor and wages system, are replaced by
wage labor and wage system, respectively.

Marx indicates fifteen pence (new currency) for one day of labor of
twelve hours.  Two years later, in Capital, Volume 1, in the first
chapter of his Part on "Wages", Marx repeats this same reference wage
rate.  This value amounts to ninety pence per the then workweek of six
days, that is, £46.80 for a 52-week work year if fully employed.  Some
occupations, particularly female, could earn much less and Marx
provides a couple of examples in his chapter on "Time Wages" (i.e.,
about sixty-five pence weekly on 13+-hour workdays in Scottish
bleaching works; twenty-five pence weekly on 15-hour workdays for
female hand nail-makers).

What does £46.80 per year in 1865 mean today when an "eight"-hour
workday, five-day workweek might yield £10,000 yearly in Britain
($15,000 in the United States) for the lower end, but not lowest end,
worker?  A House of Commons Library report, "Inflation: the Value of
the Pound 1750-1998" (prepared by Robert Twigger, Economic Policy and
Statistics Section, Research Paper 99/20,  February 23, 1999)
calculates a price index of 592.3 for 1998 compared with 8.8 for 1865.
 This price increase represents a rise by a multiple of 67.3 over the
period!  Of course, there are many problems with such long-term
price-index calculations, centering around the changing lists of items
being consumed and the changing qualities of goods consumed (for
better or worse).  Nevertheless, if we use that factor of 67.3, £46.80
in 1865 corresponds to £3150 in 1998 prices.  And the workday is now
shorter (although the workday now often excludes mealtimes when in
1865 mealtimes were often included, and time of transportation
getting home now is much longer).  A real improvement in material
standards of living in Britain seems therefore to have taken place.
Comparing it to productivity, however, it may well represent a fall,
not rise, relative to the productive capacity of those doing the work
-- the workers.  For example, a productivity increase of just 1.5%
yearly represents, over 133 years, an increase by a factor of 7.2 --
far more than a tripling of real earnings suggested by comparing
£10,000 to £3150.  Or consider workers today in India, Brazil, Kenya,
etc., who earn much less yearly than the equivalent of £3150.

I hope that the text below provides an introduction to Marx's theory
that is accessible to as wide an English speaking audience as
possible, using Marx's own words.  It has, I believe, a contemporary
sense that makes Marxist theory as relevant now, in a world even more
capitalist, as it was in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries.



Paul Zarembka

_______________________________________________
Marxism-Thaxis mailing list
Marxism-Thaxis@lists.econ.utah.edu
To change your options or unsubscribe go to:
http://lists.econ.utah.edu/mailman/listinfo/marxism-thaxis

Reply via email to