Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread James Gilmour
Jameson Quinn   Sent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 2:00 AM
 If I'm right, the claim is that voters, and especially 
 politicians, are intuitively concerned with the possibility 
 of someone winning with broad but shallow support. In 
 Approval, Condorcet, Majority Judgment, or Range, a 
 relatively-unknown centrist could theoretically win a contest 
 against two high-profile ideologically-opposed candidates. 
 The theory is that the electorate would be so polarized that 
 everyone would explicitly prefer the centrist to the other 
 extreme, but because the voters don't really expect the 
 low-profile centrist to win, they might miss some important 
 flaw in the centrist which actually makes her a poor winner.

I cannot comment on the quoted remark (cut) that prompted your post and I know 
nothing at all about the activities of anyone at
FairVote, but you have hit on a real problem in practical politics in your 
comment above  -  the problem of the weak Condorcet
winner.  This is a very real political problem, in terms of selling the voting 
system to partisan politicians (who are opposed to
any reform) and to a sceptical public.

For example, with 3 candidates and 100 voters (ignoring irritant preferences) 
we could have:
35 AC
34 BC
31 C
C is the Condorcet winner.  Despite the inevitable howls from FPTP 
supporters, I think we could sell such an outcome to the
electors.

But suppose the votes had been (again ignoring irrelevant preferences):
48 AC
47 BC
 5 C
C is still the Condorcet winner - no question about that.  But I doubt 
whether anyone could successfully sell such a result to the
electorate, at least, not here in the UK.

And I have severe doubts about how effective such a winner could be in office. 
Quite apart from the sceptical electorate, the
politicians of Party A and of Party B would be hounding such an office-holder 
daily.  And the media would be no help  -  they would
just pour fuel on the flames.  The result would be political chaos and totally 
ineffective government.

The flaw in IRV is that it can, sometimes, fail to elect the Condorcet winner.  
But IRV avoids the political problem of the weak
Condorcet winner.  I suspect that's why IRV has been accepted for many public 
and semi-public elections despite the Condorcet flaw.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread Peter Zbornik
Dear all,

I agree with James, and that was why I proposed that election reform
took the path through added election rounds.

Reform of FPTP would thus add a second election round where the
Condorcet winner would meet the FPTP winner. Who in the UK would
object to that?

I described also how to add a third election round the run-off
elections while the voters would not have to go to the voting booth
more than two times.

If the two systems above are considered as beeing too simple for the
experts and enthousiasts on this list, why not reform the FPTP to a
three round system (although politically it might be a more difficult
task to sell than a a two round system as a reform path from FPTP)

Round 1: The FPTP, Condorcet and Bucklin Winners are elected (for example).
Round 2: The voter Choses between the Condorcet and the Majority
judgement (Bucklin) winner
Round 3: The FPTP winner meets the winner from round two (i.e. the
voter writer if he prefers the Condorcet winner to the FPTP winner and
the Bucklin winner to the FPTP winner).

Rounds 2 and 3 could take place at the sametime (i.e. not requiring
the voter to go to the voting booth an extra time after round 2.

So far there have been no objections to this reformpath.

I see the weaknesses as the following:
1) increased election costs
2) risk of lower turn-out in the second round

I see the advantages as the following:
1) The weaknesses of each method are greatly diminished by combining
different methods and letting the voter chose the most preferred
winner from the methods.
2) A second round allows for more deliberation from the side of the
voters on the candidates
3) Voters actually like being granted more power through the extra
round and voter who don't care enough to go to the voting booth a
second time will not affect the election outcome
4) Multiple round systems where the old election system is combined
with a new one is able to gather political support from those voters,
who think the old system works well, and do not want to abandon it
entirely, but are open to improvements. This might be crucial in order
to gather the required political support for election reform.
5) The voter is in control of the extent of the voting reform, i.e.
the multiple round system allows the voters to chose their preferred
voting system according to its result. A voter who is a FPTP fanatic
may always vote for the FPTP winner in the second round, same for the
Condorcet/Majority judgement/score/approval fanatic, and then there is
the voter who simply will vote according to his/her preference
ordering in the second round.

I think the multiple round path to election reform is a bit neglected
as I consider it to be very powerful in its simplicity.

Best regards
Peter Zborník

On Thu, Sep 22, 2011 at 6:40 PM, James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk wrote:
 Jameson Quinn   Sent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 2:00 AM
 If I'm right, the claim is that voters, and especially
 politicians, are intuitively concerned with the possibility
 of someone winning with broad but shallow support. In
 Approval, Condorcet, Majority Judgment, or Range, a
 relatively-unknown centrist could theoretically win a contest
 against two high-profile ideologically-opposed candidates.
 The theory is that the electorate would be so polarized that
 everyone would explicitly prefer the centrist to the other
 extreme, but because the voters don't really expect the
 low-profile centrist to win, they might miss some important
 flaw in the centrist which actually makes her a poor winner.

 I cannot comment on the quoted remark (cut) that prompted your post and I 
 know nothing at all about the activities of anyone at
 FairVote, but you have hit on a real problem in practical politics in your 
 comment above  -  the problem of the weak Condorcet
 winner.  This is a very real political problem, in terms of selling the 
 voting system to partisan politicians (who are opposed to
 any reform) and to a sceptical public.

 For example, with 3 candidates and 100 voters (ignoring irritant preferences) 
 we could have:
        35 AC
        34 BC
        31 C
 C is the Condorcet winner.  Despite the inevitable howls from FPTP 
 supporters, I think we could sell such an outcome to the
 electors.

 But suppose the votes had been (again ignoring irrelevant preferences):
        48 AC
        47 BC
         5 C
 C is still the Condorcet winner - no question about that.  But I doubt 
 whether anyone could successfully sell such a result to the
 electorate, at least, not here in the UK.

 And I have severe doubts about how effective such a winner could be in 
 office. Quite apart from the sceptical electorate, the
 politicians of Party A and of Party B would be hounding such an office-holder 
 daily.  And the media would be no help  -  they would
 just pour fuel on the flames.  The result would be political chaos and 
 totally ineffective government.

 The flaw in IRV is that it can, sometimes, fail to elect the Condorcet 
 

Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread robert bristow-johnson

On 9/22/11 12:40 PM, James Gilmour wrote:
I cannot comment on the quoted remark (cut) that prompted your post 
and I know nothing at all about the activities of anyone at FairVote, 
but you have hit on a real problem in practical politics in your 
comment above  -  the problem of the weak Condorcet winner.  This is a 
very real political problem, in terms of selling the voting system to 
partisan politicians (who are opposed to any reform) and to a 
sceptical public.


i remember Rob Ritchie arguing this case to me in 2009 (why sometimes 
IRV is better than Condorcet).


For example, with 3 candidates and 100 voters (ignoring irritant 
preferences) we could have:

35 AC
34 BC
31 C
C is the Condorcet winner.  Despite the inevitable howls from FPTP 
supporters, I think we could sell such an outcome to the electors.


But suppose the votes had been (again ignoring irrelevant preferences):
48 AC
47 BC
 5 C
C is still the Condorcet winner - no question about that.  But I 
doubt whether anyone could successfully sell such a result to the 
electorate, at least, not here in the UK.




even though there were 48 voters who preferred C over B, 47 that 
preferred C over A, along with the 5 that preferred C over both A and B.


that does not appear to me to be such a bad result.

And I have severe doubts about how effective such a winner could be in 
office. Quite apart from the sceptical electorate, the politicians of 
Party A and of Party B would be hounding such an office-holder daily.  
And the media would be no help  -  they would just pour fuel on the 
flames.  The result would be political chaos and totally ineffective 
government.


The flaw in IRV is that it can, sometimes, fail to elect the Condorcet 
winner.
and even if that is the root to the problem, the complainers will 
*still* revert to FPTP which has even less of a chance of electing the CW.


   But IRV avoids the political problem of the weak Condorcet 
winner.  I suspect that's why IRV has been accepted for many public 
and semi-public elections despite the Condorcet flaw.
i believe the reason why IRV has been sold to some jurisdictions is a 
decision, early on by FairVote, that its simplicity is more saleable 
than Condorcet.  the concept of the transferred votes is an easy one.


and that IRV can well take care of the spoiler problem (and the burden 
of strategic voting motivated by a spoiled election) when the spoiler is 
like Nader, having no chance of winning, but gets sufficient votes to 
change the outcome.  we found out in Burlington in 2009, that while IRV 
relieved the liberal majority in town of the burden of strategic voting 
(we didn't have to make a painful choice between the Dem and the Prog), 
it actually placed a burden of strategic voting upon the GOP 
prog-haters.  those folks found out that by marking their guy as #1, 
they ended up *causing* the election of the candidate they disliked the 
most.  that's gotta make some people mad.  and if IRV had survived the 
repeal (it didn't), these folks would have to be thinking in 2012: In 
this town full of liberals, I gotta choose between Liberal and More 
Liberal, because if I vote for the guy I really like, then More Liberal 
gets elected.  So IRV transferred the burden of strategic voting from 
the liberal majority to the conservative minority.


then FairVote deliberately conflates the ranked ballot with IRV, 
essentially presenting to lawmakers and the public that there is no 
other method of tabulating the ranked ballots other than the 
single-transferable vote (based *only* on the amount of support in first 
preference rank, IRV is opaque to one's second choice until the first 
choice is eliminated).


i think politicians or the voting public that can understand the concept 
of a Round-Robin tournament can understand Condorcet.  but if they 
believe religiously that only the simple mark only one ballot (the 
term they used here was the single affirmative vote), there is no 
convincing.  i think that they believe that electing the candidate who 
benefits from the presence of a spoiler is appropriate.  they may say 
that the people who get burned by a spoiler need to wise up and combine 
their forces in order to win elections.  that, essentially, means that 
we have no viable third parties or viable independent candidates and 
reinforces the two-party system.


--

r b-j r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread Toby Pereira



From: James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk

I don't think I would have a problem with C winning here, if the votes were all 
sincere. But that's the problem. They might not be. A and B supporters might 
just be putting C ahead of their perceived main rival. I suppose this is 
similar to the DH3 problem - http://rangevoting.org/DH3.html - except with 
two main rivals instead of three. As far as I understand, range, approval and 
Majority Judgement should do OK here (and not forgetting SODA of course).

But in the sincere case, every voter has ranked C above one of A or B, and if 
it happened that C and only one of A and B were running, then C would win and 
no-one would be bothered at all.

Toby
But suppose the votes had been (again ignoring irrelevant preferences):
   48 AC
    47 BC
    5 C    
C is still the Condorcet winner - no question about that.  But I doubt 
whether anyone could successfully sell such a result to the
electorate, at least, not here in the UK.

And I have severe doubts about how effective such a winner could be in office. 
Quite apart from the sceptical electorate, the
politicians of Party A and of Party B would be hounding such an office-holder 
daily.  And the media would be no help  -  they would
just pour fuel on the flames.  The result would be political chaos and totally 
ineffective government.

The flaw in IRV is that it can, sometimes, fail to elect the Condorcet 
winner.  But IRV avoids the political problem of the weak
Condorcet winner.  I suspect that's why IRV has been accepted for many public 
and semi-public elections despite the Condorcet flaw.

James Gilmour

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread James Gilmour
Peter Zbornik  Sent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 6:41 PM
 I agree with James, and that was why I proposed that election 
 reform took the path through added election rounds.
 
 Reform of FPTP would thus add a second election round where 
 the Condorcet winner would meet the FPTP winner. Who in the 
 UK would object to that?

I cannot think of ANYONE in the UK who would support a proposal for any form of 
two-round voting for public elections.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 7:00 PM
  On 9/22/11 12:40 PM, James Gilmour wrote:
  But suppose the votes had been (again ignoring irrelevant 
 preferences):
  48 AC
  47 BC
   5 C
  C is still the Condorcet winner - no question about that.  But I
  doubt whether anyone could successfully sell such a result to the 
  electorate, at least, not here in the UK.
 
 even though there were 48 voters who preferred C over B, 47 that 
 preferred C over A, along with the 5 that preferred C over 
 both A and B.
 
 that does not appear to me to be such a bad result.

But you are missing the point.  It is not how the Condorcet winner appears to 
you or to me  -  it is how that winner, with only 5%
of the first preferences, is seen by ordinary electors and by hostile partisan 
politicians of Party A and Party B.  I think I know
how that result would be received in the UK (total rejection), and I would 
expect a similar reaction in the USA or Canada, judging
by what I have read in their on-line newspapers.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread James Gilmour
Toby PereiraSent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 8:11 PM
  From: James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk
 But suppose the votes had been (again ignoring irrelevant preferences):
48 AC
 47 BC
 5 C
  C is still the Condorcet winner - no question about that.  But I 
 doubt whether anyone could successfully sell such a result to the 
 electorate, at least, not here in the UK.
 
 And I have severe doubts about how effective such a winner could be in 
 office. Quite apart from the sceptical electorate, the politicians of 
 Party A and of Party B would be hounding such an office-holder daily.  
 And the media would be no help  -  they would just pour fuel on the 
 flames.  The result would be political chaos and totally ineffective 
 government.
 
 The flaw in IRV is that it can, sometimes, fail to elect the Condorcet 
 winner.  But IRV avoids the political problem of the weak Condorcet 
 winner.  I suspect that's why IRV has been accepted for many public and 
 semi-public elections despite the Condorcet flaw.

 I don't think I would have a problem with C winning here, if 
 the votes were all sincere.

Even if all the votes are sincere, it is irrelevant what you or I think.  It is 
what ordinary electors would think about such a
winner, with only 5% of the first preferences.  And those electors would not be 
left in peace to reflect quietly on the potential of
their (weak) Condorcet winner.  Their views would be whipped up by partisan 
politicians and by a hostile press and media.  That
Condorcet winner would still be the Condorcet winner, but that's not how such 
an outcome would be portrayed.  The world of real
politics is a very brutal, nasty and dirty place, but that's where practical 
electoral reformers have to work (at least for the time
being) if they really want to change anything.

James Gilmour





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-21 Thread Jameson Quinn
On the center for election science mailing list, someone just forwarded a
comment from a prominent member of FairVote. Stripped of the extremely rude
ad-hominem attacks, this is the actual content of what he had to say:

... in the process of trying to pass your preferred system somewhere, you
 will discover why IRV is superior to those systems.


So, according to this person, IRV has some secret advantage over all other
systems, which is obvious to anyone who's done real-world activism, but not
obvious from a theoretical perspective. In fact, it's apparently so
theoretically non-obvious that it can't even be stated coherently to someone
who hasn't done real-world activism.

This argument seems designed more to end the conversation than to actually
convince anyone. But despite the pathetic rudeness with which it's stated, I
suspect that there is actually some content here, something which deserves
discussion. I can guess what the secret advantage is, partly from having
read some of this person's other statements in Gaming the Vote.

If I'm right, the claim is that voters, and especially politicians, are
intuitively concerned with the possibility of someone winning with broad but
shallow support. In Approval, Condorcet, Majority Judgment, or Range, a
relatively-unknown centrist could theoretically win a contest against two
high-profile ideologically-opposed candidates. The theory is that the
electorate would be so polarized that everyone would explicitly prefer the
centrist to the other extreme, but because the voters don't really expect
the low-profile centrist to win, they might miss some important flaw in the
centrist which actually makes her a poor winner.

If I'm right that this is IRV's secret, unanswerable advantage... then I
must say I'm not too impressed. This concern from the voters, or even from
the candidates, is probably irrational; IRV has pathologies which will
probably be much more common in practice. But OK; people are sometimes
irrational, and it is certainly possible that this kind of result, which is
impossible under plurality, seems scarier to people than Plurality's
familiar pathologies which are reproduced in IRV.

So OK, say people really have an outsized fear of this problem. Does that
mean that IRV is the only good voting reform which actually has a chance of
passing? Well, given how IRV advocates often use dishonest arguments, and
especially how they often lose anyway --- even in high-profile battles where
they start out with an advantage, such as the AV referendum in the UK ---
I'd say that claim is very dubious.

Still, I'd agree, advocates of other systems should have very clear talking
points to respond to the mushy-centrist argument. There should be a single
sentence which people can repeat every time they're faced with the argument.
If each of us is reinventing a new counterargument every time this issue is
raised, then voters will not get a coherent message they can understand.

Here are my responses to mushy centrist concerns (which can also be cast
as majority criterion concerns), for my two favorite systems:

A mushy centrist doesn't have an unfair advantage under Majority Judgment,
as Balinski and Laraki have shown (centrists and extremists have more
balanced chances under MJ than under any other system in their empirical
study of real voter behavior). And in SODA, it is 100% impossible to
accidentally elect an unknown centrist; the centrist can't win unless some
other candidate explicitly decides that she should.

Jameson Quinn

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info