Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread Jason DeBacker
Is there a significant difference in the returns to education for those 
who get schooling in top ranked programs?  I thought I remember a 
Newsweek a couple years back that had a story about SAT scores of 
successful people (two profiles were G.W. Bush and Gore so I guess it 
was around 2000), and the point they were trying to make was that those 
who make the most money generally have SATs in the 1200 and 1300s- good 
students, but not top students.  In addition, the book "The Millionaire 
Next Door" describes those that accumulate the most wealth as not 
necessarily being the top students or having degrees from prestigious 
universities- and, I believe the authors said that if you make $100,000 
per year or more, then years of education is negatively correlated with 
wealth.

Also, the argument that opportunity cost is the largest cost of college, 
is often used to encourage people to not worry about student loans and 
and look at more prestigious universities, but is this the case for 
those who are choosing a top school?  With tuitions at $35K + per year, 
do you make back your investment with a higher expected salary as 
compared to a school on a lower tier?

Jason DeBacker






RE: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread Grey Thomas
Data that includes going to college almost certainly includes SAT scores.
(I also think they correlate strongly with IQ, but haven't looked for that
data).
I'm "sure" that the effect of more schooling is higher on those with higher
SAT scores.

In addition, I'd guess the data includes average, rather than median, income
increases, so it is more easily skewed upward by those achieving super-rich
status (those overpaid CEOs  -- yes, I do think overpaid -- for instance).

Tom Grey

PS. part of the great benefit of this list is that, often, asking a good
question allows somebody else to answer it who has already researched it, or
part of it ... so that I don't have to.  I'm probably not too much of a free
rider.


>>>

Now I won't argue that some people who get two years of college and then
drop out without a degree might not have been better off getting a two year
degree of certification, but the first order effect is something like at
least a 6.5% increase in income for each year of school completed whether
you get a degree or not. - - Bill





Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread Alex T Tabarrok
The focus of the discussion has been on whether college students do the
math of attending college.  Perhaps a better question is whether those
young people not in college have done the math.

Alex

--
Alexander Tabarrok
Department of Economics, MSN 1D3
George Mason University
Fairfax, VA, 22030
Tel. 703-993-2314

and

Director of Research
The Independent Institute
100 Swan Way
Oakland, CA, 94621
Tel. 510-632-1366





Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread William Dickens
I see Bill already answered my question. 

>>>Not the way you think. See my response to yours. 

I should also add that the social costs of tuition are much higher than
the private costs for public universities, making it even more likely
that the social return is quite low.

>>>I happen to believe the public good argument for education, but even if I didn't, 
>you know as well as I do that you can't attribute the entire cost of the university 
>to its educational product. A big chunk is paying for research. Take that out and I 
>doubt the costs would be so high. After all, no reason why a college education would 
>have to cost that much more than HS unless you want all Profs to be researchers.  - - 
>Bill

William T. Dickens
The Brookings Institution
1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20036
Phone: (202) 797-6113
FAX: (202) 797-6181
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
AOL IM: wtdickens





Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread William Dickens
If the decision is literally a "no-brainer," then failing to consider
alternatives is rational.  

>>>??!!! Not if they make the wrong choice! OK, I suppose you are going to argue that 
>all the people who didn't have a clue what the return to continuing their education 
>was are the ones for whom it was a no brainer and the ones who were about to drop out 
>all answered my questions correctly. I can't prove that wrong but do you really 
>believe that was what was going on?

Marginal students frequently weigh continuing
vs. dropping out (just like they weigh attending vs. not attending!).

>>>Agreed, but it is my contention that they don't deal with the future returns in a 
>way an economist would judge as rational. 

Incidentally, most of your arguments (here and later in this discussion)
suggest that people over-estimate the return to education.  Is that your
real view?

>>>If you ask people to think about it my guess is that the average person attending a 
>four year college will give you a response suggesting that they over estimate how 
>much money they will make either when they graduate or if they drop out. The only 
>evidence I have on this (my survey of Berkeley undergrads taking intermediate macro) 
>suggests that they over estimate the percentage return as well. However, I don't 
>think people act on this information. It is my strong impression that people 
>tremendously overweight their current feelings of happiness or unhappiness about 
>being in school so that on net people don't get as much schooling as they should if 
>they were truly utility maximizes. 
- - Bill

William T. Dickens
The Brookings Institution
1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20036
Phone: (202) 797-6113
FAX: (202) 797-6181
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
AOL IM: wtdickens





Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread William Dickens

>My other side couldn't disagree more strongly.  A significant percentage
>of undergrads should really be in some kind of 2-year trade school
>instead.

Ahhh... But then you have to deal with the very empirical evidence that kicked this 
whole discussion off. If you think that people are making irrational (essentially 
random) decisions to go to school then the OLS estimates of the rate of return are 
right and the real returns to education are the best you can get anywhere. You may not 
think that they are getting much out of college, but the average return to each 
additional year of education is very high. If you think they are behaving rationally 
...   Now I won't argue that some people who get two years of college and then drop 
out without a degree might not have been better off getting a two year degree of 
certification, but the first order effect is something like at least a 6.5% increase 
in income for each year of school completed whether you get a degree or not. - - Bill





Fw: America's Second Plutocratic Gilded Age Pt. 2

2002-10-28 Thread Alypius Skinner



 
 (Continued from Part 1)IV. The Price of 
InequalityIt was one of those revealing moments. Responding to an e-mail 
message from aCanadian viewer, Robert Novak of ''Crossfire'' delivered a 
little speech:''Marg, like most Canadians, you're ill informed and wrong. 
The U.S. has thelongest standard of living -- longest life expectancy of any 
country in theworld, including Canada. That's the truth.''But it was 
Novak who had his facts wrong. Canadians can expect to live abouttwo years 
longer than Americans. In fact, life expectancy in the U.S. is wellbelow 
that in Canada, Japan and every major nation in Western Europe. Onaverage, 
we can expect lives a bit shorter than those of Greeks, a bit longerthan 
those of Portuguese. Male life expectancy is lower in the U.S. than it isin 
Costa Rica.Still, you can understand why Novak assumed that we were No. 
1. After all, wereally are the richest major nation, with real G.D.P. per 
capita about 20percent higher than Canada's. And it has been an article of 
faith in thiscountry that a rising tide lifts all boats. Doesn't our high 
and risingnational wealth translate into a high standard of living -- 
including goodmedical care -- for all Americans?Well, no. Although 
America has higher per capita income than other advancedcountries, it turns 
out that that's mainly because our rich are much richer.And here's a radical 
thought: if the rich get more, that leaves less foreveryone 
else.That statement -- which is simply a matter of arithmetic -- is 
guaranteed tobring accusations of ''class warfare.'' If the accuser gets 
more specific,he'll probably offer two reasons that it's foolish to make a 
fuss over thehigh incomes of a few people at the top of the income 
distribution. First,he'll tell you that what the elite get may look like a 
lot of money, but it'sstill a small share of the total -- that is, when all 
is said and done therich aren't getting that big a piece of the pie. Second, 
he'll tell you thattrying to do anything to reduce incomes at the top will 
hurt, not help, peoplefurther down the distribution, because attempts to 
redistribute income damageincentives.These arguments for lack of 
concern are plausible. And they were entirelycorrect, once upon a time -- 
namely, back when we had a middle-class society.But there's a lot less truth 
to them now.First, the share of the rich in total income is no longer 
trivial. These days1 percent of families receive about 16 percent of total 
pretax income, andhave about 14 percent of after-tax income. That share has 
roughly doubled overthe past 30 years, and is now about as large as the 
share of the bottom 40percent of the population. That's a big shift of 
income to the top; as amatter of pure arithmetic, it must mean that the 
incomes of less well offfamilies grew considerably more slowly than average 
income. And they did.Adjusting for inflation, average family income -- total 
income divided by thenumber of families -- grew 28 percent from 1979 to 
1997. But median familyincome -- the income of a family in the middle of the 
distribution, a betterindicator of how typical American families are doing 
-- grew only 10 percent.And the incomes of the bottom fifth of families 
actually fell slightly.Let me belabor this point for a bit. We pride 
ourselves, with considerablejustification, on our record of economic growth. 
But over the last few decadesit's remarkable how little of that growth has 
trickled down to ordinaryfamilies. Median family income has risen only about 
0.5 percent per year --and as far as we can tell from somewhat unreliable 
data, just about all ofthat increase was due to wives working longer hours, 
with little or no gain inreal wages. Furthermore, numbers about income don't 
reflect the growingriskiness of life for ordinary workers. In the days when 
General Motors wasknown in-house as Generous Motors, many workers felt that 
they hadconsiderable job security -- the company wouldn't fire them except 
inextremis. Many had contracts that guaranteed health insurance, even if 
theywere laid off; they had pension benefits that did not depend on the 
stockmarket. Now mass firings from long-established companies are 
commonplace;losing your job means losing your insurance; and as millions of 
people havebeen learning, a 401(k) plan is no guarantee of a comfortable 
retirement.Still, many people will say that while the U.S. economic 
system may generate alot of inequality, it also generates much higher 
incomes than any alternative,so that everyone is better off. That was the 
moral Business Week tried toconvey in its recent special issue with ''25 
Ideas for a Changing World.'' Oneof those ideas was ''the rich get richer, 
and that's O.K.'' High incomes atthe top, the conventional wisdom declares, 
are the result of a free-marketsystem that provides huge incentives for 
performance. And the system deliversthat performance, which means that 
wealth at the top doesn't come at theexpense of the 

Fw: America's Second Plutocratic Gilded Age Pt. 1

2002-10-28 Thread Alypius Skinner



 
Krugman tries so hard to make his case that he 
ignores some other factors (perhaps even more controversial) that contribute to 
some of the new social developments that Krugman describes.  Unfortunately, 
I don't have time to comment on them, but they would not in any 
event cancel out the basic direction of socio-economic evolution that 
Krugman describes.~ams---http://www.nytimes.com/2002/10/20/magazine/20INEQUALITY.htmlThe 
New York Times MagazineOctober 20, 2002For RicherBy PAUL 
KRUGMANI. The Disappearing MiddleWhen I was a teenager growing 
up on Long Island, one of my favorite excursionswas a trip to see the great 
Gilded Age mansions of the North Shore. Thosemansions weren't just pieces of 
architectural history. They were monuments toa bygone social era, one in 
which the rich could afford the armies of servantsneeded to maintain a house 
the size of a European palace. By the time I sawthem, of course, that era 
was long past. Almost none of the Long Islandmansions were still private 
residences. Those that hadn't been turned intomuseums were occupied by 
nursing homes or private schools.For the America I grew up in -- the 
America of the 1950's and 1960's -- was amiddle-class society, both in 
reality and in feel. The vast income and wealthinequalities of the Gilded 
Age had disappeared. Yes, of course, there was thepoverty of the underclass 
-- but the conventional wisdom of the time viewedthat as a social rather 
than an economic problem. Yes, of course, some wealthybusinessmen and heirs 
to large fortunes lived far better than the averageAmerican. But they 
weren't rich the way the robber barons who built themansions had been rich, 
and there weren't that many of them. The days whenplutocrats were a force to 
be reckoned with in American society, economicallyor politically, seemed 
long past.Daily experience confirmed the sense of a fairly equal 
society. The economicdisparities you were conscious of were quite muted. 
Highly educatedprofessionals -- middle managers, college teachers, even 
lawyers -- oftenclaimed that they earned less than unionized blue-collar 
workers. Thoseconsidered very well off lived in split-levels, had a 
housecleaner come inonce a week and took summer vacations in Europe. But 
they sent their kids topublic schools and drove themselves to work, just 
like everyone else.But that was long ago. The middle-class America of my 
youth was anothercountry.We are now living in a new Gilded Age, as 
extravagant as the original.Mansions have made a comeback. Back in 1999 this 
magazine profiled ThierryDespont, the ''eminence of excess,'' an architect 
who specializes in designinghouses for the superrich. His creations 
typically range from 20,000 to 60,000square feet; houses at the upper end of 
his range are not much smaller thanthe White House. Needless to say, the 
armies of servants are back, too. So arethe yachts. Still, even J.P. Morgan 
didn't have a Gulfstream.As the story about Despont suggests, it's not 
fair to say that the fact ofwidening inequality in America has gone 
unreported. Yet glimpses of thelifestyles of the rich and tasteless don't 
necessarily add up in people'sminds to a clear picture of the tectonic 
shifts that have taken place in thedistribution of income and wealth in this 
country. My sense is that few peopleare aware of just how much the gap 
between the very rich and the rest haswidened over a relatively short period 
of time. In fact, even bringing up thesubject exposes you to charges of 
''class warfare,'' the ''politics of envy''and so on. And very few people 
indeed are willing to talk about the profoundeffects -- economic, social and 
political -- of that widening gap.Yet you can't understand what's 
happening in America today withoutunderstanding the extent, causes and 
consequences of the vast increase ininequality that has taken place over the 
last three decades, and in particularthe astonishing concentration of income 
and wealth in just a few hands. Tomake sense of the current wave of 
corporate scandal, you need to understandhow the man in the gray flannel 
suit has been replaced by the imperial C.E.O.The concentration of income at 
the top is a key reason that the United States,for all its economic 
achievements, has more poverty and lower life expectancythan any other major 
advanced nation. Above all, the growing concentration ofwealth has reshaped 
our political system: it is at the root both of a generalshift to the right 
and of an extreme polarization of our politics.But before we get to all 
that, let's take a look at who gets what.II. The New Gilded 
Age[T]he Securities and Exchange Commission hath no fury like a woman 
scorned.The messy divorce proceedings of Jack Welch, the legendary former 
C.E.O. ofGeneral Electric, have had one unintended benefit: they have given 
us a peekat the perks of the corporate elite, which are normally hidden from 
publicview. For it turns out that when Welch retired, he was granted

EU to Swiss: end banking secrecy or else!

2002-10-28 Thread Alypius Skinner



 
 http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/main.jhtml?xml=/news/2002/10/09/wswis09.xml/
 


  
  

  EU attacks Swiss over bank reform 
  By Ambrose Evans-Pritchard in 
  Brussels(Filed: 09/10/2002) 
  The European Union moved a step closer to economic warfare 
  against the Swiss yesterday, threatening to throttle Switzerland's 
  financial sector unless it agrees to abandon banking secrecy.
  Frits Bolkestein, the European tax commissioner, put forward a list of 
  possible sanctions at a meeting of EU finance ministers in Luxembourg, 
  including the "nuclear option" of restrictions on capital movements by 
  Swiss investors and firms. The measures, to be finalised in December, also 
  covered suspension of bilateral agreements.
  Chancellor Gordon Brown, the driving force behind the push 
  for sanctions, said: "We are determined to move this forward. We are 
  utterly serious about the importance of this issue."
  EU diplomats warned yesterday that Mr Brown was playing 
  with fire by allowing the EU to threaten exchange controls against third 
  countries, even if the punitive measures don't come into force until 
  2010.
  They said he is establishing a precedent that may come back 
  to haunt the City of London, which depends on free flow of capital for its 
  survival.
  The tactics are aimed at forcing Switzerland to take part 
  in a Brussels plan to crack down on tax evasion by handing over 
  information on all EU citizens investing money in the country.
  However, Swiss voters would almost certainly oppose the EU 
  demands in a referendum, obligatory under the constitution, even if their 
  government agreed. The Swiss financial sector accounts for 11 percent of 
  the country's GDP.
  The scheme was proposed by Mr Brown as an alternative to an 
  EU withholding tax that threatened to devastate the City of London's 
  international bond business, and was trumpeted as a triumph of British 
  diplomacy at the EU's Feira summit in June 2000.
  Without Swiss participation, the arrangement will fall 
  apart. Austria, Luxembourg, and Belgium all refuse to give up their own 
  banking secrecy codes unless other financial centres take part. The fear 
  at the Treasury is that the withholding tax could be resurrected.
  Switzerland's entire political and business establishment 
  was united in fury yesterday. "This is absolutely outrageous. Switzerland 
  is not Iraq," said James Nason of the Swiss Bankers Association.
  
  


  
  8 October 2002[Money]: Swiss fury as commissioner attacks 
'lack of help on tax'

  
  29 September 2002: Swiss see red as our man in Berne 
demands tax details 


  
  


  
  External links
   
  


   

  
  Taxation and customs union - European 
Commission

   

  
  European Union

   

  
  Swiss Banking Organisation

   

  
  Government of Switzerland

   
  
  
  
  

  
  

  
  


Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread Bryan Caplan
Eric Crampton wrote:
> 
> On Fri, 25 Oct 2002, William Dickens wrote:
> 
> > continue schooling largely under weights the future benefits. Nearly
> > everyone should get more schooling than they do. This is only one of

I see Bill already answered my question.  Blunt reaction: Come on!  If
you really think most students are failing to considering foregone
earnings, and these are the big cost of school, then the problem goes in
the other direction.

I should also add that the social costs of tuition are much higher than
the private costs for public universities, making it even more likely
that the social return is quite low.
-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  "He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it." 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread Bryan Caplan
A belated reply to Bill.

William Dickens wrote:

> >>>Note its the _parents_ in your story who are groaning, not the kids.
> OK, I'll admit that the "no idea" was based on what I know it was like
> when I was going to college in the 70s. However, it is still my
> impression after 13 years of teaching college that the vast majority of
> college students not only have never done a present value computation
> about their decision to go to school, but have never seriously
> considered the alternative of not going to school - - what they could
> do, how much they could make, what their lives would be like etc.

If the decision is literally a "no-brainer," then failing to consider
alternatives is rational.  Marginal students frequently weigh continuing
vs. dropping out (just like they weigh attending vs. not attending!).

> >>>Are you thinking only of economics majors? Business and economics
> majors (some) think this way. Do you think the average lit major is?
> Psych? Pol. Sci?

Yes.  In fact, right after a lit major tells you his major, he
frequently comments on his low expected earnings.  "I'm a lit major. 
Not much money in that, but I like it."
 
> >>>Standard economic model assumes that most of the costs are forgone
> earnings. Mom and Dad paying for school should be small potatoes (since
> you can always go to a state school at low cost). My impression is that
> this factor ways in people's decisions way out of proportion to its
> economic value.

Maybe back in the '70's.  Now in-state tuition is significant.  At Mason
it's $4400.  If you add in housing (as you should if you would have
lived at home otherwise), it's up to about $10,000.  About the annual
pay of a minimum wage job before taxes.

> But more
> to the point, I doubt that parents are making any sort of intertemporal
> comparison in paying for kids school. How many do you think have thought
> "Well, if I invest the money I'm paying for the kids school in corporate
> AAAs at 6.5% his income from my bequest will be $XX, in 20XX whereas
> if I pay for his school it will be..." No way. What they think is
> "better to teach a man to fish than to buy him fish..." or something
> like that and they fork over the bucks to  U. Not the economic model
> at all.  

I grant that few open Excel and punch in the numbers.  You could improve
their decision-making by teaching them to do so.  But if college grads
earned only 10% more than non-college grads, parents would be a lot less
quick to parrot old cliches about fishing.

Incidentally, most of your arguments (here and later in this discussion)
suggest that people over-estimate the return to education.  Is that your
real view?

-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  "He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it." 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*