Re: Productivity: Economics Blogs

2004-07-17 Thread Dmytri Kleiner
On Fri, Jul 16, 2004 at 05:20:40PM -0400, Paul wrote:
 Dmytri Kleiner wrote:
 As I'm sure most of you have noticed US labour productivity has been the
 talk of
 the economics blog world of late.
 ..

 I can't resist asking which ones you read or would reccomend.  I am aware
 of DeLong and Sawicky - any others that focus seriously on economics or eco
 policy?

Yes, those two, especialy the later, are the best, but there are also
Albert King's EconLog and Marginal Revolution which are quite active.

You will find many links there.

Micheall Albert also has two, Though Dreams and Goodbye Maggie, both
hosted on ZNet, where discusses 'Participatory Economics.'

Regards,
Dmytri.


Productivity: Economics Blogs

2004-07-16 Thread Paul
Dmytri Kleiner wrote:
As I'm sure most of you have noticed US labour productivity has been the
talk of
the economics blog world of late.
..
I can't resist asking which ones you read or would reccomend.  I am aware
of DeLong and Sawicky - any others that focus seriously on economics or eco
policy?


Re: Productivity: Economics Blogs

2004-07-16 Thread Max B. Sawicky
Angry Bear
The Big Picture
Kautilyan
ArgMax
D-Squared Digest
Nathan Newman
Billmon (Whiskey Bar)

You can get the links on my site (on the left)

lots of right-wing ones too, some knowledgeable,
some loony.

max


-Original Message-
From: PEN-L list [mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED] On Behalf Of Paul
Sent: Friday, July 16, 2004 5:21 PM
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: Productivity: Economics Blogs

Dmytri Kleiner wrote:
As I'm sure most of you have noticed US labour productivity has been
the talk of the economics blog world of late.
..

I can't resist asking which ones you read or would reccomend.  I am aware of
DeLong and Sawicky - any others that focus seriously on economics or eco
policy?


Productivity.

2004-07-14 Thread Dmytri Kleiner
As I'm sure most of you have noticed US labour productivity has been the talk of
the economics blog world of late.

I have a few questions regarding this productivity boom that have not been
answered sufficiently in what I have read so far.

Productivity, as best as I can tell, is defined as follows:

Productivity = (Gross Output - Foreign Inputs) / Domestic Labour

So, foreign inputs are simply ignored by the formula, doesn't this mean
that if cheaper foreign inputs displace domestic inputs that this calculation
would show a rise in productivity?

Also, since US dollars sent abroad to pay for these foreign inputs will
eventually come home and make demands on US productivity, shouldn't this
increasing dependence on foreign inputs eventually cause inflation?

In fact, doesn't this rise in productivity happen to exist against the
backdrop of massive hoarding of US currency in Asian Central Banks? Is
this preventing the inflation?

In this light, can it be said that the 'Productivity Boom' is really
Asian productivity financing US consumption?

What hapens when the Asians begin to spend some of that US currency?


Re: Productivity.

2004-07-14 Thread Diane Monaco
Dmytri asks:
I have a few questions regarding this productivity boom that have not been
answered sufficiently in what I have read so far.
Productivity, as best as I can tell, is defined as follows:
Productivity = (Gross Output - Foreign Inputs) / Domestic Labour
So, foreign inputs are simply ignored by the formula, doesn't this mean
that if cheaper foreign inputs displace domestic inputs that this calculation
would show a rise in productivity?
Dmytri, foreign inputs don't appear to be ignored in the formula you've
given above, but I would definitely agree with you that as cheaper foreign
labor inputs displace domestic labor inputs, productivity would rise.  I
would crudely measure labor productivity by dividing real GDP in a
period by the number of labor input units employed during the same
period.  I would also add that ANY measure of productivity is sure to
increase in value if firms are:
1. learning how to do more with fewer full-time labor inputs
2. learning how to replace full-time labor input with temporary labor input
3. learning how to replace labor-intensive processes with more
capital-intensive ones
4. learning how to replace domestic labor input with foreign labor input
(as you mention)
...which is what is happening in the US today, thus the so-called
productivity boom.

Also, since US dollars sent abroad to pay for these foreign inputs will
eventually come home and make demands on US productivity, shouldn't this
increasing dependence on foreign inputs eventually cause inflation?
That's an interesting question.  If US dollars are going abroad to purchase
machinery and equipment (increasing imports in machinery/equipment as is
happening in Canada today, see article below), there would be a downward
pressure on prices on the demand side -- and future productivity increases
on the supply side.  Also, if US dollars are going abroad to purchase
cheaper foreign labor inputs, productivity rises (as you mention),
theoretically expanding aggregate supply and putting downward pressures
on the average level of prices.
But there are so many other factors and the part I wrote above about US
dollars going abroad to purchase machinery/equipment is not happening.
Thanks for the interesting thoughts.
Diane
Surge in imports spurs hopes for gains in productivity
Machinery demand fuels record gains
The Globe and Mail
Wednesday, Jul 14, 2004
Exploding demand for machinery and equipment fuelled a record surge in
Canadian imports in May, sparking hopes that the long-awaited improvement
in productivity may be around the corner.
The Canadian business sector has been lagging the United States in
productivity improvement since 2001.
The jump in imports -- attributed in part to a strong Canadian dollar --
cut sharply into Canada's trade surplus, which fell to $5.2-billion from
$7-billion a month ago.
Imports of machinery and equipment climbed 13.9 per cent during the month
to $9.6-billion, the largest increase since September of 1981, offering
some grounds for optimism that Canadian firms are investing in technology
that will bolster their competitiveness and yield long-awaited economy-wide
improvements in productivity.
Gains were widespread, affecting telecommunications gear, office machinery,
transportation equipment and laboratory supplies.
The sharp increase suggests a meaningful capital spending cycle is
developing, said Robert Spector, of Merrill Lynch Canada Inc. We've been
anticipating this for some time as companies take advantage of the stronger
Canadian dollar, the low cost of capital and lean balance sheets in an
effort to boost sagging productivity.
The rise implies spending in the economy is becoming more balanced between
the consumer and business investment, he added.
Overall imports climbed 7.8 per cent in May, the biggest gain since the
beginning of 1997, reaching a record $31.6-billion.
Exports showed a modest gain of 1.3 per cent to $36.8-billion.
Businesses are more confident, and willing to shell out on machinery and
equipment, said Warren Lovely, senior economist at CIBC World Markets
Inc., with equipment imports now up 20 per cent from a year ago.
Three solid months of labour-force growth show businesses are hiring and
investing in capital goods as well, Mr. Lovely said.
The upturn mirrored a Bank of Canada survey this week showing a growing
optimism among Canadian firms about sales prospects, investment intentions
and hiring.
Last year's 20-per-cent rise in the value of the Canadian dollar means
goods imported from the United States are cheaper, said Stephen Poloz,
chief economist at Export Development Canada (EDC). It's like putting the
equipment on sale, he said, and that's where our productivity catch-up
will come from.
More than 70 per cent of machinery and equipment imports come from the
United States.
Among those looking for productivity gains is Toronto-Dominion Bank, which
signed a $420-million contract with Hewlett-Packard Canada to upgrade its
network of banking machines and debit-card

Re: Productivity.

2004-07-14 Thread Doug Henwood
Diane Monaco wrote:
Dmytri, foreign inputs don't appear to be ignored in the formula you've
given above, but I would definitely agree with you that as cheaper foreign
labor inputs displace domestic labor inputs, productivity would rise.
A productivity guy at the BLS told me that foreign labor inputs would
be counted as foreign production as well, with little impact on the
productivity figures.
Doug


Re: Productivity.

2004-07-14 Thread Diane Monaco
Doug wrote:
Diane Monaco wrote:
Dmytri, foreign inputs don't appear to be ignored in the formula you've
given above, but I would definitely agree with you that as cheaper foreign
labor inputs displace domestic labor inputs, productivity would rise.
A productivity guy at the BLS told me that foreign labor inputs would
be counted as foreign production as well, with little impact on the
productivity figures.
Would have little impact on which productivity figures, Doug?  If foreign
labor inputs are displacing domestic labor inputs, and domestic labor
inputs are counted in domestic productivity figures, wouldn't there be an
impact on domestic productivity figures?
(domestic labor productivity)=(domestic output)/(domestic labor input)
...so if domestic labor input goes down and if domestic output stays the
same or increases...then domestic labor productivity will go up.
I'm thinking that the BLS productivity person you refer to was suggesting
that foreign labor inputs don't directly enter domestic labor
productivity formulas as Dmytri originally suggested in the previous
post...and I would agree.  Just a thought.
Thanks,
Diane


Re: Productivity.

2004-07-14 Thread Doug Henwood
Diane Monaco wrote:
Would have little impact on which productivity figures, Doug?  If foreign
labor inputs are displacing domestic labor inputs, and domestic labor
inputs are counted in domestic productivity figures, wouldn't there be an
impact on domestic productivity figures?
(domestic labor productivity)=(domestic output)/(domestic labor input)
...so if domestic labor input goes down and if domestic output stays the
same or increases...then domestic labor productivity will go up.
If the work is done abroad the value added is counted as part of
foreign, not domestic, output. The foreign labor would be embodied in
purchased components.
Doug


Re: Productivity.

2004-07-14 Thread Devine, James
strictly speaking, labor productivity isn't (domestic output)/(domestic labor input). 
Rather, it's (domestic value added)/(domestic labor input), where value added = 
domestic output minus intermediate goods input. 

BTW, it sure looks like the concept of value added is very similar to Marx's  S+V.


Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




 -Original Message-
 From: PEN-L list [mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED] Behalf Of Diane
 Monaco
 Sent: Wednesday, July 14, 2004 10:57 AM
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject: Re: [PEN-L] Productivity.
 
 
 Doug wrote:
 Diane Monaco wrote:
 
 Dmytri, foreign inputs don't appear to be ignored in the 
 formula you've
 given above, but I would definitely agree with you that as 
 cheaper foreign
 labor inputs displace domestic labor inputs, productivity 
 would rise.
 
 A productivity guy at the BLS told me that foreign labor inputs would
 be counted as foreign production as well, with little impact on the
 productivity figures.
 
 Would have little impact on which productivity figures, Doug? 
  If foreign
 labor inputs are displacing domestic labor inputs, and 
 domestic labor
 inputs are counted in domestic productivity figures, wouldn't 
 there be an
 impact on domestic productivity figures?
 
 (domestic labor productivity)=(domestic output)/(domestic labor input)
 
 ...so if domestic labor input goes down and if domestic 
 output stays the
 same or increases...then domestic labor productivity will go up.
 
 I'm thinking that the BLS productivity person you refer to 
 was suggesting
 that foreign labor inputs don't directly enter domestic labor
 productivity formulas as Dmytri originally suggested in the previous
 post...and I would agree.  Just a thought.
 
 Thanks,
 Diane
 



Re: Productivity.

2004-07-14 Thread Michael Perelman
Suppose a Chinese girl makes a pair of Nikes for $2.  Someone in the US puts them in
a box and sells them for $150.  The boxer is paid $2, but his productivity
statistics will look fairly impressive, even considering the marketing  management
overhead.



--
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail michael at ecst.csuchico.edu


Re: Productivity.

2004-07-14 Thread Diane Monaco
Doug wrote:
Diane Monaco wrote:
Would have little impact on which productivity figures, Doug?  If foreign
labor inputs are displacing domestic labor inputs, and domestic labor
inputs are counted in domestic productivity figures, wouldn't there be an
impact on domestic productivity figures?
(domestic labor productivity)=(domestic output)/(domestic labor input)
...so if domestic labor input goes down and if domestic output stays the
same or increases...then domestic labor productivity will go up.
If the work is done abroad the value added is counted as part of
foreign, not domestic, output. The foreign labor would be embodied in
purchased components.
True, in a perfect world.  But the foreign labor inputs used, should
technically be subtracted from domestic value added as imported
intermediate goods inputs, as Jim D. more accurately detailed above,
although it is always understated, thus overstating domestic output
(domestic value added).  So when domestic value added, if you will, is
overstated and domestic labor input falls, domestic labor productivity
rises.  Imported intermediate goods inputs are understated because the work
that is outsourced to contractors, is typically further outsourced to
subcontractors and other unidentifiable brokers, jobbers, etc. along the
way -- and the actual value is lost and hidden.
Diane


productivity

2004-01-02 Thread joanna bujes
In a recent SF Chron article on productivity, the author wrote:

Such fast-growing productivity is a tremendous boon for society,
economists stress. While jobs might disappear in the short run, higher
output per worker spurs growth that in the long run creates more
opportunity.
Higher productivity generates profit that is often reinvested in new
job- creating activities, they note.
Full article at

http://www.sfgate.com/cgi-bin/article.cgi?file=/chronicle/archive/2003/12/28/BUGE03U34Q1.DTL

I think that the statement that profit is often reinvested in new
job-creating activities deserves closer scrutiny. First, it says nothing
about where these jobs are going to be. Second, I actually don't think
that's the trend. I read recently, I think it was in Barrons, that the
profits are not being reinvested but used largely for speculation.
Does anyone have data on this?

Joanna


Re: productivity

2004-01-02 Thread DMS
There is plenty of data on this and except for that data collected by Dr.
Pangloss and his assistants at the Milton Friedman-Ayn Rand School of
the Dismal Science(Team Fight Song-- First I Look At the Purse),  the
last 30 years have proved just the opposite-- greater profits have been
accompanied by reductions in living standards, declining real wages, reduced
manufacturing employment, etc. etc.

Reduced profits trigger even greater reductions in living standards, wages,
employment etc.

Rates of growth, globally, have declined from the 1948-1973 period in output,
trade, and profits while the mass of profit has expanded.

Not too long ago, the chief economist for Alliance Capital, measured a
worldwide decline in manufacturing employment, including China, despite
the increased direct investment.

Overall, the trends are for reduced manufacturing employment levels, at both
absolute and relatively diminished wage levels, with growing service sectors where
wages are lower than in manufacturing and for work force increases basically
derived from the employment of women at lower rates than those paid to men.

But it's the best of all possible worlds, and when it gets worse, that will be the
best of all possible worlds, too.


dms


Re: productivity

2004-01-02 Thread Mike Ballard
--- joanna bujes [EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:
 In a recent SF Chron article on productivity, the
 author wrote:

 Such fast-growing productivity is a tremendous boon
 for society,
 economists stress. While jobs might disappear in the
 short run, higher
 output per worker spurs growth that in the long run
 creates more
 opportunity.

 Higher productivity generates profit that is often
 reinvested in new
 job- creating activities, they note.
**

Was the author's name Supply Side Jesus?

Mike B)

=

Talent develops in tranquility, character
in the full current of human life.

Johann Wolfgang von Goethe (1749-1832)

http://profiles.yahoo.com/swillsqueal

__
Do you Yahoo!?
Find out what made the Top Yahoo! Searches of 2003
http://search.yahoo.com/top2003


Inflation and productivity questions

2003-12-05 Thread Martin Hart-Landsberg
I wanted to ask for help on two questions, one on inflation and the
other on productivity.
As to the inflation question, a while back business week had a special
article on fees.  The article argued that many businesses unable to
raise prices are adding fees, like banks for example.  My question: do
these fees enter into the CPI, or are we understating inflation?
As to productivity, a while ago there were articles showing that a lot
of the productivity increase came from the sector that produced
computers.  And that the increase in productivity in that sector was
the result of statistical work designed to take into account quality
increases.  As a result, the national income accounts showed a higher
value of output than actually produced or sold.  Those articles also
made the point that the higher productivity figures resulting from that
calculation were not comparable with productivity figures from other
countries, because most did not do that adjustment.  My question: are
recent productivity gains a product of the same statistical adjustments?
Thanks, Marty Hart-Landsberg


Re: Inflation and productivity questions

2003-12-05 Thread Michael Perelman
With regard to productivity, Robert Gordon was the most prominent sceptic.
He has back off from his scepticism somewhat.

I don't think fees are part of the CPI.  Nor are sales taxes although
corporate taxes are, at least that is my understanding.

On Fri, Dec 05, 2003 at 01:08:18PM -0800, Martin Hart-Landsberg wrote:
 I wanted to ask for help on two questions, one on inflation and the
 other on productivity.

 As to the inflation question, a while back business week had a special
 article on fees.  The article argued that many businesses unable to
 raise prices are adding fees, like banks for example.  My question: do
 these fees enter into the CPI, or are we understating inflation?

 As to productivity, a while ago there were articles showing that a lot
 of the productivity increase came from the sector that produced
 computers.  And that the increase in productivity in that sector was
 the result of statistical work designed to take into account quality
 increases.  As a result, the national income accounts showed a higher
 value of output than actually produced or sold.  Those articles also
 made the point that the higher productivity figures resulting from that
 calculation were not comparable with productivity figures from other
 countries, because most did not do that adjustment.  My question: are
 recent productivity gains a product of the same statistical adjustments?

 Thanks, Marty Hart-Landsberg

--
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]


Re: productivity growth as a mixed bag

2003-10-24 Thread soula avramidis
Do the dollars really go back to the US and buy US products or do they stay outside in waiting?
Do you Yahoo!?
The New Yahoo! Shopping - with improved product search

productivity growth as a mixed bag

2003-10-23 Thread Devine, James
[I wonder how Varian would explain this point in terms of his micro
textbook.]

October 23, 2003/New York TIMES/ECONOMIC SCENE 

The Mixed Bag of Productivity

By HAL R. VARIAN

RECENTLY productivity has been growing at a rate of about 4 percent a
year. For the country as a whole, this means that each year we can work
as much as we did last year and consume 4 percent more; or we can
consume as much as we did last year and work 4 percent less.

That's got to be a good thing, right?

Well, it depends on whom you ask. In truth, those productivity gains
have resulted in some people's working 100 percent less, with the rest
of us consuming 4.01 percent more. If you are one of the unemployed,
chances are you are less enthusiastic about the productivity gains than
are those who have enjoyed the increased consumption.

Strangely, productivity growth is not getting much blame for the
jobless recovery. Criticizing technological progress is downright
un-American. On the other hand, criticizing foreign trade is a
traditional pastime here, as in every other country.

To economists, trade and productivity growth have a lot in common: each
allows you to produce more with less.

James Ingram's economics text tells the story of how an entrepreneur
built a factory that was significantly more productive than his
competitors' plants, and was hailed far and wide for his brilliance.

But then his dirty little secret was revealed: all he was doing was
importing goods from abroad through the back door.

In terms of impact on employment, trade is usually better than
productivity growth; those dollars sent abroad eventually come back to
purchase American products, and employ more workers. By contrast, jobs
lost to productivity increases stay lost; try to find someone today who
can make buggy whips.

Gains from trade or technology initially tend to accrue to owners of
capital. When a company fires a computer programmer and shifts the job
to India, the company captures the difference in wages.

It wouldn't have to work that way. Suppose the programmer found his
doppelganger in India, and started exporting tasks on his own. Dear
Sanjay, please write a subroutine to sort these accounts and send it
back to me by 5 p.m. (California time). Each week the programmer could
cash his $1,000 paycheck and send $100 to Sanjay.

This is only a thought experiment, not a policy proposal. But it
illustrates the point that the controversy over trade and technology is
not about whether or not they are good things - of course they are - but
about who will capture their benefits and who will bear their costs.

There is little doubt who wins in the long run: consumers. Virtually all
the gains in the standard of living in the last two centuries have come
from technology. Trade has had a smaller but still significant effect on
growth in per capita consumption.

Achieving the gains from technological advances can be tortuous. Back in
1886, when America's railroads standardized on one gauge, it became
substantially cheaper to transport goods. A great boon for everyone,
right? Well, tell that to the workers who unloaded and loaded freight at
the cities where different-gauge railroads met. They rioted over the
change, and understandably so - the benefits from technological progress
came at the expense of their jobs.

Eighty years later, the longshoremen's union was more farsighted. It saw
new technology coming for unloading ships and negotiated lifetime
employment at high wages. The result was that by 2002 a full-time
longshoreman earned $80,000 to $107,000, depending on whether you ask
the union or management.

The crucial issue in last year's West Coast port strike was not whether
technology for managing shipyards would be introduced - both sides were
in favor - but whether the new information-processing jobs went to union
workers.

The longshoremen's union has tried to ensure that a significant part of
the gains from productivity increases accrued to its members. But even
the longshoremen recognize, though they might be loath to admit it, that
there has to be something for both sides in the negotiation; if all the
gains go to labor, there will be no incentive for capitalists to adopt
more productive technology.

Capitalists have to get their piece, so they will have an incentive to
pony up the money. How much labor ends up with depends on its bargaining
power. If workers do not have much bargaining power, they get the short
end of the deal.

In the long run, as the new technology becomes widely adopted,
competition pushes prices down. The gains that originally accrued to the
owners of capital are competed away, and consumers - meaning workers for
the most part - end up with the benefits.

Look at travel agents. The Internet opened up a new channel for airlines
to communicate directly to travelers. Intense competition for passengers
meant that most of the gains from the new technology were passed along
to consumers, with travel agents squeezed out

productivity growth failing US

2003-07-11 Thread Devine, James
http://www.latimes.com/business/la-fi-dispatch11jul11,1,5661366.story?c
oll=la-headlines-business 
WASHINGTON DISPATCH
Cause for U.S. Recovery Lacking Effect
By Peter G. Gosselin
Los Angeles Times Staff Writer

July 11, 2003

WASHINGTON - Here's an economic kick in the pants for you: Mainstream
economists say that the nation is finally on the road to recovery. And
not just any recovery, but a splendid one fueled by technology-driven
productivity gains.

But the revival has yet to produce any of what matters most to people -
namely, jobs. The chief reason there has been no pickup in employment:
the very productivity gains that are supposed to ensure a grand
comeback.

High productivity means that companies can meet the current level of
demand without going to the trouble of hiring new people, said
Princeton economist and former Federal Reserve Vice Chairman Alan
Blinder. It makes the task of providing enough demand to soak up all
that productive capacity a much harder one.

The lack of new jobs is just one instance of what could prove to be a
new phenomenon: the evidence-free recovery.

Economic turning points usually produce a welter of conflicting signals,
some suggesting full revival and others further trouble. But thus far,
this one has been remarkably free of the former.

Although forecasters busily explain why the economy should come roaring
back - near-record low interest rates, still more tax cuts and a sliding
dollar to help exports - they have yet to be able to cite a solid piece
of evidence that it actually is on the way back.

There's not much out there to convince you we're headed into a period
of strong growth, said Gregory D. Hess, a former Fed staffer who is an
economist at Claremont McKenna College.

What's happening to jobs and wages offers a vivid example of what's
half-empty about the economy and what could put a cork in a full-fledged
recovery.

American employers have created no new jobs on a net basis since the
presumed end of the recent recession in January 2002. Worse yet,
according to Labor Department statistics, they actually have been
cutting jobs, especially over the last five months, when payrolls fell
by nearly half a million.

The latest result came Thursday, when the department announced that the
number of people collecting unemployment benefits hit a 20-year high of
3.82 million in June.

Some economists maintain that recent job trends pose no threat to the
recovery. They say employment and unemployment are lagging indicators
that improve only after a turnaround is well underway.

But at 18 months and counting, the lag is getting mighty long.

Other analysts comfort themselves with the thought that the tens of
millions of Americans who are still employed have continued to borrow
and buy at a remarkable pace, keeping the economy afloat and primed for
recovery.

Even so, however, the trends are not altogether happy.

Wages, which play a big role in what most of us decide we can and cannot
afford, and which moved in lock step with rising productivity during the
late 1990s, have broken loose in the last couple of years. Although they
still are rising, they are doing so at a slower - and slowing - pace.

The nation's nonfinancial corporations boosted their labor productivity
- the amount of goods and services they can produce per hour of labor -
by a record 5.5% last year, according to government statistics. But the
working Americans who provided that labor saw their wages rise by less
than one-third of that amount, and at less than half the pace of the
hottest moments of the late '90s.

[the print copy has a graph showing the growth of real wages growing
more or less in step with labor productivity from 1999 to 2001 and then
falling behind. The latter implies a rise in the rate of exploitation,
associated with the rise in the size of the reserve army of unemployed
labor.]

Analysts say that, although painful for workers, the divergence of
productivity and wages could turn out to be a good thing for the economy
as a whole. That's because if people aren't reaping the benefits, then
companies must be seeing them in the form of bigger profits. And bigger
profits might motivate firms to begin investing, expanding and hiring
again, setting off an upward spiral of growth.

[that fits with Marx's theory of accumulation, but not the standard
neoclassical view.]

The problem is that corporate America has shown almost no interest in
doing any of these things, all of which leave the economy in a nasty
bind.

[as I've said before, adding to Marx, unused capacity, corporate debt,
and pessimistic expectations can block accumulation.]

It's unlikely that consumers will be able to continue to shrug off
mounting job losses, rising unemployment and diminishing wage increases
for much longer, said Mark Zandi, chief economist of West Chester,
Pa.-based Economy.com.

In fact, other than home buying, he said, consumers appear to be growing
increasingly cautious. Car sales, for example, have slipped

productivity for information technology

2002-12-23 Thread Michael Perelman
Fortune magazine suggests that the productivity paradox is finished.
Information technology is now lifting productivity by facilitating
outsourcing jobs abroad.

http://www.fortune.com/fortune/fastforward/0,15704,401035,00.html
-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




mommy, what's the marginal productivity of a ceo?

2002-09-17 Thread Ian Murray


http://www.wsws.org
General Electric's Jack Welch and the corporate plundering of America
By Jeremy Johnson
17 September 2002


Divorce papers filed in court earlier this month against retired General
Electric Corporation Chairman and CEO John F. Welch Jr. provided a glimpse into
the lifestyle of America's corporate elite. In her suit to dissolve their
13-year marriage, Jane Beasley Welch complains that the $35,000 per month
offered by her husband is nowhere near enough to maintain the extraordinary
standard of living that they enjoyed together.

Her papers quantify $126,820 in monthly expenses incurred by the couple, not
counting sizable additional amounts paid by General Electric as perks to its
former chief executive. Among the most significant items, GE provides a
company-owned luxury apartment at the Trump International Hotel and Towers on
Central Park West in New York City. Besides allowing Welch to live there
rent-free, GE picks up the tab for such additional necessities as fresh flowers,
wine, laundry and dry cleaning services, a cook and wait staff, a housekeeper,
and every other detail down to toiletries, newspaper and magazine subscriptions,
even postage. GE also pays a portion of Welch's dining bills at the exclusive
restaurant Jean Georges, which is located in the building.

Additionally, Welch receives a free grand tier box at the Metropolitan Opera,
memberships at four country clubs, including Georgia's prestigious Augusta
National, court-side tickets to New York Knicks basketball games, box seats
behind the dugout at Yankee Stadium plus a skybox for the Boston Red Sox, prime
tickets to the French Open, Wimbledon and US Open tennis tournaments, VIP
tickets to all Olympic events, and unlimited use of a corporate Boeing 737 jet.
The cost of this last item alone is estimated at $291,869 a month.

The list goes on. GE pays for Welch's limousine and driver in New York,
bodyguards when he travels abroad, satellite TV installations in his New York
apartment and his three other homes in Massachusetts, Connecticut and Florida.
And, Mrs. Welch reports, GE contributed $7.5 million over the course of their
marriage to help furnish the four homes with appliances, security systems and
sophisticated computer and telecommunications equipment, with GE employees
assisting with the installation.

All of these fringe benefits supplement a retirement agreement that includes a
pension of over $9 million a year and a health insurance and life insurance
package that Welch negotiated with the GE board of directors in 1996 when he
agreed to extend his tenure as chief executive until age 65. The contract
specified that upon retirement, Welch would retain lifetime access to company
facilities and services comparable to those made available to him as CEO. Welch
formally retired on September 1 of last year, but, in addition to everything
else, he receives a consulting fee of $86,535 for his first 30 days of work each
year, plus $17,307 for each additional day.

Yet another company-paid perk is the cost of financial planning services to help
Welch manage his fortune, estimated at $900 million.

In statements released on September 6, neither Welch nor General Electric
disputed the extent of the perks, most details of which had never been revealed
to shareholders. GE spokesperson Gary Sheffer insisted that the company had
complied with all legal disclosure requirements, while Welch asserted that the
arrangement had worked to the benefit of all constituencies.

Welch has been lionized as the model corporate executive for producing higher
profits year after year. He is credited by his corporate admirers with almost
single-handedly turning GE from a company valued at $15 billion when he took
over to one valued at over $400 billion when he retired a year ago. Since then,
the company stock has declined some 25 percent, in spite of reporting a 15
percent increase in six-month profits this year to $7.94 billion.

His ruthless methods earned Welch the nickname Neutron Jack among GE workers,
due to the layoffs he carried out soon after taking over. In the course of the
1980s Welch cut some 100,000 jobs.

He established the principle of selling off any subsidiaries that failed to
maintain a number one or number two market share in their respective industries,
while meeting profit expectations. General Electric owns businesses that range
from its traditional lighting and appliance production to aircraft engine
manufacturing, electric generating systems, financial services and insurance,
and the major broadcast network NBC.

This latter enterprise provided Welch with exceptional political clout. Analysts
point to the kid glove media treatment of George W. Bush during the 2000
presidential election campaign, after his top advisor Karl Rove promised Welch
and other media moguls that, if elected, Bush would carry out a major
deregulation of the broadcast industry.

Welch reportedly took a keen personal interest in the NBC News 

marginal productivity of a ceo

2002-08-21 Thread Ian Murray

http://www.businessweek.com/
AUGUST 21, 2002
NEWS ANALYSIS


CEO Pay Tomorrow: Same as Today

Despite the uproar over gargantuan compensation packages, here's why the level of 
reform is likely
to be modest at best
During the boom years of the late 1990s, the fact that CEOs made out like bandits may 
have prompted
disgust, but it sparked little outrage. After all, lots of other people were getting 
wealthy off the
bull market, too. Now that actual banditry is being blamed for the collapse of major 
companies --
and for billions of dollars in shareholder losses -- CEO compensation is being 
scrutinized as never
before.

It seems like every company that had accounting problems also had troublesome 
compensation
practices, says Brandon Rees, a research analyst with the AFL-CIO's office of 
investment in
Washington, D.C. He believes that executive compensation abuses can be symptomatic of 
broader
corporate governance problems.

The two seem to have occurred simultaneously at Enron, WorldCom, Adelphia, and Global 
Crossing. And
this year's scandals have revealed disturbing exec pay quirks even at companies that 
haven't
imploded. Tyco, for instance, showered deposed CEO Dennis Kozlowski with the type of 
largesse
usually reserved for royalty only to see him charged with trying to evade a measly -- 
compared with
his pay -- $1 million or so in sales taxes on high-priced art.

LOWER PAY? NO WAY.  And you don't even have to be a CEO to come under fire for an 
outsize
compensation package. Who can explain the reported $30 million that superstar telecom 
analyst Jack
Grubman got when he recently resigned from Citigroup's Salomon Smith Barney -- even as 
he's under
investigation for misleading investors in telecommunications stocks?

With over-the-top pay and executive misbehavior so closely aligned, it might seem that 
exec
compensation would be facing an overhaul. But the experts see little ahead that will 
reset the
priorities of CEOs -- and certainly nothing that will ratchet down the average $11 
million that top
executives were paid in 2001. We aren't going to see CEOs being paid less, says 
David Aboody, an
associate professor of accounting at UCLA's Anderson graduate school of business and 
an expert in
executive compensation.

A survey of experts in the field finds a consensus that the reforms from this year's 
debacles will
be exceedingly modest, at best. In fact, they believe that substantive compensation 
changes will
most likely be left to individual companies eager to set themselves apart from the 
pack.

WINDOW DRESSING.  CEOs will suffer some, of course. For a while, they'll all be tarred 
with the same
brush as their disgraced peers, some of whom may end up in jail (see BW Online, 
8/21/02, One CEO's
Take on CEO-itis). There's also the indignity of having to vouch in writing for the 
financial
results of their companies because no one wants to rely on their word anymore. But for 
the most
part, the changes being contemplated for stock-option plans and corporate compensation 
committees
have the look of window dressing.

Most companies are likely to stick with the status quo, in part because they do 
business on the up
and up. Moreover, it's now obvious that an exec who really wants to cheat can probably 
find a way
to -- at least for a while. It's tough to legislate integrity, says Steve Hall, a 
managing
director at compensation consultants Pearl Meyer  Partners in New York.

Many observers think the only changes likely to be widely adopted are the two the New 
York Stock
Exchange and the Nasdaq may require of companies traded on those exchanges. (Experts 
say both could
be adopted by yearend if approved by the Securities  Exchange Commission.) One would 
stipulate that
corporate compensation committees, which decide how much a CEO is paid, be composed 
only of
independent directors. Today, some 39% of these committees at the country's top 5,000 
public
companies include either company insiders or outsiders with direct connections to the 
corporation,
according to the National Association of Corporate Directors.

Still, independent compensation committees may not do much to improve the moral fiber 
of execs,
because such committees are often populated with CEOs -- active or retired -- who are 
from the same
old-boys club, notes Rees. And there's nothing in the Nasdaq/New York exchange 
proposals that would
keep boards from loading up compensation committees with the CEO's golfing buddies.

THOSE CEO LOANS.  The other reform the exchanges have proposed would require 
shareholder approval of
executive equity awards including stock options. (Currently, shareholder approval 
isn't necessary if
the options plan is broadly based or results in at least a portion of the shares 
being distributed
to employees.) But greater shareholder oversight of compensation practices may not 
eliminate
executive shenanigans until there's more disclosure of the private dealings between 
corporation and
CEO, says Judith 

Good Health=Higher Productivity

2002-06-27 Thread Hari Kumar

ORIGINAL NOTE:
The support for national health care: Good health = higher productivity

= higher profits.
.. Eugene Coyle wrote:
 Jenkins did say that placebos work as well. .I missed how the
column could be read to support national health care?
RESPONSE:
The equation above, is of course nothing new. It was instrumental  lay
behind many of the progressive social policies introduced by many
capitalist governments. One case in point was the NHS of the UK
introduced by Bevan. Even before that was school meals in the UK;  the
Boer War recruits being so weak  stunted prompted much consternation in
the ruling class.
Hari Kumar




RE: Re: Prozac Productivity

2002-06-27 Thread Devine, James
Title: RE: [PEN-L:27264] Re: Prozac  Productivity





  A WSJ columnist, Holman Jenkins, today praised Prozac et al for
raising worker productivity. 


-Original Message-
From: Tom Walker


This is what I was trying to tell Jim Devine about speed up -- post hoc
ergo prozac.


COMMENT: I don't know where Tom got the false impression that I was praising speed up. I also don't praise productivity. 

Jim 





Prozac Productivity

2002-06-27 Thread Charles Brown

Prozac  Productivity
by Carrol Cox
27 June 2002 04:02 UTC  

There was a fine science column in last Friday's WSJ -- on the way
environment turns genes off and on. For example, if you've been without
sex for awhile and are expecting to get some tomorrow your beard may
grow faster: sexual activity triggers a flow of testosterone, but
apparently even thinking about it can do the same thing. And rats that
are licked a lot by their mother when pups are more curious and less
subject to panic than other rats -- because the licking turns on some
genes.

-clip-

This all comes from a new technology of microarray analysis, in which
'gene chips' reveal which DNA in a sample of tissue is expressed and
which is quiescent.

In other words technology is beginning to show that macro features of
the environment are _part_ of genetic causation; a huge new pile of data
to support the argument in Levins  Lewontin's _Not in Our Genes_ --
it's in the environment which turns on some genes and turns off others.

^

CB: I agree with your general approach of relating genes and environment as a 
dialectical whole, but specifically, when testosterine flow is begot, it is not 
through genes being turned on is it ? It would be glands, not genes. Genes function to 
shape more fundamental developments mostly in the womb and infancy, no ? For example, 
the development of glands is related to genes ( and proteins have a bigger role at 
this level the genome project results suggest). But a once a gland is developed in an 
adult, its function is not related to current genetic activity in the gland.




Re: Prozac Productivity

2002-06-27 Thread Carrol Cox



Charles Brown wrote:
 
 

 
 CB: I agree with your general approach of relating genes and environment as a 
dialectical whole, but specifically, when testosterine flow is begot, it is not 
through genes being turned on is it ? It would be glands, not genes. Genes function 
to shape more fundamental developments mostly in the womb and infancy, no ? For 
example, the development of glands is related to genes ( and proteins have a bigger 
role at this level the genome project results suggest). But a once a gland is 
developed in an adult, its function is not related to current genetic activity in the 
gland.

I was just paraphrasing/quoting/condensing the column. I don't have an
opinion of my own.

Carrol




Re: Prozac Productivity

2002-06-27 Thread Tom Walker

I don't know where Jim got the false impression that I thought he was
praising speed up. For the record, I'll say it one more time: my point is
simply that there might not be the causal relationship between speed up and
productivity growth that most people assume there is. It has nothing to do
with whether either speed up or productivity are good or bad in themselves.

Jim Devine wrote,

 COMMENT: I don't know where Tom got the false impression that I was
praising speed up. I also don't praise productivity.


Tom Walker
604 255 4812




Prozac Productivity

2002-06-26 Thread Eugene Coyle

A WSJ columnist, Holman Jenkins, today praised Prozac et al for raising
worker productivity.  The suggestion is that the jump in prescriptions
over the past years have resulted in a jump in productivity.  And as the
economy moves more toward service work, involving meeting customers,
future gains will result if we get more of the work force on Effexor and
Prozac.  Holman quotes $ gains provided by others.

The column was not titled Brave New World.

Gene Coyle




Re: Prozac Productivity

2002-06-26 Thread Michael Perelman


But he says that placebos work as well.  You could read the article to
support national health care.

On Wed, Jun 26, 2002 at 10:53:47AM -0700, Eugene Coyle wrote:
 A WSJ columnist, Holman Jenkins, today praised Prozac et al for raising
 worker productivity.  The suggestion is that the jump in prescriptions
 over the past years have resulted in a jump in productivity.  And as the
 economy moves more toward service work, involving meeting customers,
 future gains will result if we get more of the work force on Effexor and
 Prozac.  Holman quotes $ gains provided by others.
 
 The column was not titled Brave New World.
 
 Gene Coyle
 

-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Prozac Productivity

2002-06-26 Thread Eugene Coyle

Jenkins did say that placebos work as well.  But he used that as an attack on
the FDA.  He wants the FDA to approve drugs even if they can't be shown to
work better than placebos -- because that would permit more placebos in the
market.
I missed how the column could be read to support national health care?
If I wanted to cause Jenkins a bad night I would tell him your interpretation
-- he's pretty much a Libertarian.

Gene

Michael Perelman wrote:

 But he says that placebos work as well.  You could read the article to
 support national health care.

 On Wed, Jun 26, 2002 at 10:53:47AM -0700, Eugene Coyle wrote:
  A WSJ columnist, Holman Jenkins, today praised Prozac et al for raising
  worker productivity.  The suggestion is that the jump in prescriptions
  over the past years have resulted in a jump in productivity.  And as the
  economy moves more toward service work, involving meeting customers,
  future gains will result if we get more of the work force on Effexor and
  Prozac.  Holman quotes $ gains provided by others.
 
  The column was not titled Brave New World.
 
  Gene Coyle
 

 --
 Michael Perelman
 Economics Department
 California State University
 Chico, CA 95929

 Tel. 530-898-5321
 E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Re: Prozac Productivity

2002-06-26 Thread Michael Perelman


The support for national health care: Good health = higher productivity
= higher profits.  I hope that he has a bad night.

On Wed, Jun 26, 2002 at 05:59:25PM -0700, Eugene Coyle wrote:
 Jenkins did say that placebos work as well.  But he used that as an attack on
 the FDA.  He wants the FDA to approve drugs even if they can't be shown to
 work better than placebos -- because that would permit more placebos in the
 market.
 I missed how the column could be read to support national health care?
 If I wanted to cause Jenkins a bad night I would tell him your interpretation
 -- he's pretty much a Libertarian.
 
 Gene
 
 Michael Perelman wrote:
 
  But he says that placebos work as well.  You could read the article to
  support national health care.
 
  On Wed, Jun 26, 2002 at 10:53:47AM -0700, Eugene Coyle wrote:
   A WSJ columnist, Holman Jenkins, today praised Prozac et al for raising
   worker productivity.  The suggestion is that the jump in prescriptions
   over the past years have resulted in a jump in productivity.  And as the
   economy moves more toward service work, involving meeting customers,
   future gains will result if we get more of the work force on Effexor and
   Prozac.  Holman quotes $ gains provided by others.
  
   The column was not titled Brave New World.
  
   Gene Coyle
  
 
  --
  Michael Perelman
  Economics Department
  California State University
  Chico, CA 95929
 
  Tel. 530-898-5321
  E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 

-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Prozac Productivity

2002-06-26 Thread Tom Walker

This is what I was trying to tell Jim Devine about speed up -- post hoc ergo
prozac.

  A WSJ columnist, Holman Jenkins, today praised Prozac et al for raising
  worker productivity.

Tom Walker
604 255 4812




Re: Re: Prozac Productivity

2002-06-26 Thread Carrol Cox

There was a fine science column in last Friday's WSJ -- on the way
environment turns genes off and on. For example, if you've been without
sex for awhile and are expecting to get some tomorrow your beard may
grow faster: sexual activity triggers a flow of testosterone, but
apparently even thinking about it can do the same thing. And rats that
are licked a lot by their mother when pups are more curious and less
subject to panic than other rats -- because the licking turns on some
genes.

Prozac is one of the SSRIs -- Selective Serotonin Reuptake Inhibitors.
But there has always been a puzzle. It begins to inhibit the uptake of
serotonin in about 24 hours -- but it doesn't began to affect mood for
three weeks or more. (There is some recent research to the effect that
for some patients it only begins to work after about six months -- I
don't remember this exactly but it was in Medscape some months ago.) So
its direct effect on serotonin is probably not the reason it works. A
tentative hypothesis is that it works by altering gene expression
causing sprouting of new neurons or remodeling synapses.

This all comes from a new technology of microarray analysis, in which
'gene chips' reveal which DNA in a sample of tissue is expressed and
which is quiescent.

In other words technology is beginning to show that macro features of
the environment are _part_ of genetic causation; a huge new pile of data
to support the argument in Levins  Lewontin's _Not in Our Genes_ --
it's in the environment which turns on some genes and turns off others.

Carrol

Michael Perelman wrote:
 
 But he says that placebos work as well.  You could read the article to
 support national health care.
 
 On Wed, Jun 26, 2002 at 10:53:47AM -0700, Eugene Coyle wrote:
  A WSJ columnist, Holman Jenkins, today praised Prozac et al for raising
  worker productivity. 




The ECONOMIST on U.S. productivity growth.

2002-05-10 Thread Devine, James

[Interestingly, the ECONOMIST doesn't mention the role of the over 4%
average annual increase in the nominal major-currencies trade-weighted value
of the dollar -- or over 5% in real terms -- during the period 1996 to 2001.
This is a key factor that would hurt profits despite rising productivity.]

May 11, 2002

FINANCE  ECONOMICS
To these, the spoils

NOT only has America's productivity wonder survived its first recession; it
has positively thrived. Output per man-hour in the non-farm business sector
rose at an annual rate of 8.6% in the first quarter of this year, its
fastest growth in 19 years. Quarterly figures are volatile, yet the
year-on-year growth in productivity was also impressive, at 4.2%. This bodes
well for America's future economic growth--but not necessarily for company
profits, or for share prices.

Commentators cheered the latest evidence of rapid productivity gains, hoping
that it might promise fatter profits ahead. That America's productivity
continued to rise last year, in contrast to previous recessions, seems to
confirm that an increase has taken place in trend productivity growth.
Still, the latest numbers overstate the underlying trend.

First, the growth in output, and hence productivity, was inflated in the
first quarter by a big swing in inventories. Productivity often surges in
the first year of a recovery after recession, as firms produce more without
needing to hire extra workers. Productivity rose by 4-5% in the first year
following both the 1981-82 and the 1990-91 recessions. Firms have actually
continued to cut jobs this year, lifting the unemployment rate in April to
an eight-year high of 6%. Today's best guess is that trend productivity
growth is around 2-2.5%. That is less than the 3-4% claimed at the height of
the new-economy bubble; but still well above the 1.4% average over the two
decades to 1995.

A second, more fundamental quibble is that, although profits will certainly
rebound this year, as firms continue to trim their costs and revenues rise,
in the longer term faster productivity growth does not automatically mean
faster profits growth. A new study by Stephen King, chief economist at the
HSBC bank, concludes that workers and consumers have received the lion's
share of the productivity gains of therevolution in information technology
(IT). Companies have received relatively little reward for their
risk-taking.

In the late 1990s it was widely assumed that faster productivity growth
would mean higher profits (so justifying higher share prices). Over the
previous half-century a strong positive relationship had indeed held between
productivity and profits. In the 1990s that relationship broke down. Despite
a surge in productivity, national-accounts profits (as opposed to profits
reported by companies, a less accurate measure) fell between 1997 and 2000,
even before the economy dipped into recession (see chart). At the end of
2000 the profits of America's non-financial firms were no higher in real
terms than in 1994, implying a big fall in their share of GDP.

Mr King argues that workers (who are, naturally, also consumers) were
virtually the sole beneficiaries of the new economy, in the shape of faster
real wage growth. This was partly thanks to a fall in the prices of IT goods
that they bought. More important, the same IT that spurred productivity also
increased competition more widely across industries, from airlines and
banking to insurance and cars, squeezing prices and profits. Information
technologyreduces barriers to entry, and makes it easier for consumers to
compare prices.

What is more, globalisation, itself spurred by information technology, has
further trimmed the pricing power of firms. HSBC finds that, in most
economies, the correlation between domestic inflation and domestic
unit-labour costs has declined over the past 40 years; the correlation
between domestic inflation and average OECD inflation has risen. In most
countries in the 1990s domestic inflation was more closely correlated with
OECD inflation than it was with domestic costs.

The dismal performance of profits should not surprise. As the IMF's World
Economic Outlook last October pointed out, productivity gains from previous
technological revolutions, from railways and textiles to electricity and the
car, have gone largely to consumers. Each time, a decline in the prices of
goods and services has given a big boost to real incomes. Consumers gained
from cheaper travel or clothes, but profits disappointed. The difference
this time is that new technology has increased competition and squeezed
profit margins across the whole economy.

None of this lessens the overall benefit of faster productivity growth. But
it does lead to some interesting conclusions:

* The profit expectations built into share prices are unrealistic. Even if
productivity growth remains robust, long-term profits growth is likely to be
weaker than expected, making shares overvalued.

* A lower return on equities means

Re: The ECONOMIST on U.S. productivity growth.

2002-05-10 Thread miychi
On 2002.05.11 02:08 AM, "Devine, James" [EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 [Interestingly, the ECONOMIST doesn't mention the role of the over 4%
 average annual increase in the nominal major-currencies trade-weighted value
 of the dollar -- or over 5% in real terms -- during the period 1996 to 2001.
 This is a key factor that would hurt profits despite rising productivity.]
 
 May 11, 2002
 
 FINANCE  ECONOMICS
 To these, the spoils
 
 NOT only has America's productivity wonder survived its first recession; it
 has positively thrived. Output per man-hour in the non-farm business sector
 rose at an annual rate of 8.6% in the first quarter of this year, its
 fastest growth in 19 years. Quarterly figures are volatile, yet the
 year-on-year growth in productivity was also impressive, at 4.2%. This bodes
 well for America's future economic growth--but not necessarily for company
 profits, or for share prices.
 
 Commentators cheered the latest evidence of rapid productivity gains, hoping
 that it might promise fatter profits ahead. That America's productivity
 continued to rise last year, in contrast to previous recessions, seems to
 confirm that an increase has taken place in trend productivity growth.
 Still, the latest numbers overstate the underlying trend.
 
 First, the growth in output, and hence productivity, was inflated in the
 first quarter by a big swing in inventories. Productivity often surges in
 the first year of a recovery after recession, as firms produce more without
 needing to hire extra workers. Productivity rose by 4-5% in the first year
 following both the 1981-82 and the 1990-91 recessions. Firms have actually
 continued to cut jobs this year, lifting the unemployment rate in April to
 an eight-year high of 6%. Today's best guess is that trend productivity
 growth is around 2-2.5%. That is less than the 3-4% claimed at the height of
 the new-economy bubble; but still well above the 1.4% average over the two
 decades to 1995.
 
 A second, more fundamental quibble is that, although profits will certainly
 rebound this year, as firms continue to trim their costs and revenues rise,
 in the longer term faster productivity growth does not automatically mean
 faster profits growth. A new study by Stephen King, chief economist at the
 HSBC bank, concludes that workers and consumers have received the lion's
 share of the productivity gains of therevolution in information technology
 (IT). Companies have received relatively little reward for their
 risk-taking.
 
 In the late 1990s it was widely assumed that faster productivity growth
 would mean higher profits (so justifying higher share prices). Over the
 previous half-century a strong positive relationship had indeed held between
 productivity and profits. In the 1990s that relationship broke down. Despite
 a surge in productivity, national-accounts profits (as opposed to profits
 reported by companies, a less accurate measure) fell between 1997 and 2000,
 even before the economy dipped into recession (see chart). At the end of
 2000 the profits of America's non-financial firms were no higher in real
 terms than in 1994, implying a big fall in their share of GDP.
 
 Mr King argues that workers (who are, naturally, also consumers) were
 virtually the sole beneficiaries of the new economy, in the shape of faster
 real wage growth. This was partly thanks to a fall in the prices of IT goods
 that they bought. More important, the same IT that spurred productivity also
 increased competition more widely across industries, from airlines and
 banking to insurance and cars, squeezing prices and profits. Information
 technologyreduces barriers to entry, and makes it easier for consumers to
 compare prices.
 
 What is more, globalisation, itself spurred by information technology, has
 further trimmed the pricing power of firms. HSBC finds that, in most
 economies, the correlation between domestic inflation and domestic
 unit-labour costs has declined over the past 40 years; the correlation
 between domestic inflation and average OECD inflation has risen. In most
 countries in the 1990s domestic inflation was more closely correlated with
 OECD inflation than it was with domestic costs.
 
 The dismal performance of profits should not surprise. As the IMF's World
 Economic Outlook last October pointed out, productivity gains from previous
 technological revolutions, from railways and textiles to electricity and the
 car, have gone largely to consumers. Each time, a decline in the prices of
 goods and services has given a big boost to real incomes. Consumers gained
 from cheaper travel or clothes, but profits disappointed. The difference
 this time is that new technology has increased competition and squeezed
 profit margins across the whole economy.
 
 None of this lessens the overall benefit of faster productivity growth. But
 it does lead to some interesting conclusions:
 
 * The profit expectations built into share prices are unrealistic. Even if
 pr

productivity jumps

2002-05-07 Thread Ian Murray

Worker productivity shoots up 8.6 percent, best performance in nearly 19
years
By Jeannine Aversa, Associated Press, 5/7/2002 10:54

WASHINGTON (AP) Worker productivity, a key ingredient to the economy's
long-term vitality, shot up at an annual rate of 8.6 percent in the first
quarter, the best performance in nearly 19 years.

The jump in productivity the amount of output per hour of work followed a
strong 5.5 percent rate of increase in the final three months of 2001, the
Labor Department reported Tuesday.

Productivity performance in the January-March quarter was better than many
analysts expected. They were forecasting a 7 percent growth rate.

But the improvement came at a price. Businesses, responding to the
lingering effects of last year's recession, cut back on their payrolls.
That caused the total number of hours worked to fall at a rate of 1.9
percent. Output, however, rose at a solid 6.5 percent rate.

On Wall Street, stocks were mixed. The Dow Jones industrial average was up
32 points, while the Nasdaq index was down 15 points in morning trading.

The first-quarter productivity gain marked the best showing since a 9.9
percent growth rate registered in the second quarter of 1983.

The rise in productivity in the first quarter helped to push down unit
labor costs, a gauge of inflation. Unit labor costs declined at an annual
rate of 5.4 percent, the biggest drop since the second quarter of 1983. In
the fourth quarter, unit labor costs fell at a rate of 3.1 percent.

The performance of unit labor costs in the first quarter also was better
than analysts' expectations of a 3.5 percent rate of decline and suggests
that inflation is a no-show even as the budding economic recovery unfolds.

In general, productivity tends to rise strongly when the economy is
booming. Gains in productivity can become weak or productivity can fall
when the economy slows or contracts.

In the long run, productivity gains are good for workers, for the economy
and for companies, whose profits took a hit during the slump.

Gains in productivity allow companies to pay workers more without raising
prices, which would eat up those wage gains, and permit the economy to
grow faster without triggering inflation. If productivity falters,
however, pressure for higher wages could force companies to raise prices,
thus worsening inflation.

For the year ending March, productivity rose 4.3 percent, the biggest gain
since the second quarter of 2000. Unit labor costs dipped by 0.9 percent.

Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan and his colleagues remain bullish
about the long-term prospects of productivity growth, even though
businesess sharply cut investment in productivity-enhancing computers and
other high-tech equipment during the recession. That was a key source of
the economy's weakness.

''With the growth of productivity well maintained and inflation pressures
largely absent, the foundation for economic expansion has been laid,''
Greenspan told Congress last month.

Last year's recession, which ended a 10-year economic expansion, the
longest such period in U.S. history, has been determined to have begun in
March 2001. The National Bureau of Economic research has yet to rule when
the recession ended but many economists say the committee probably will
eventually select January or February.





RE: productivity jumps

2002-05-07 Thread Devine, James


 Worker productivity shoots up 8.6 percent, best performance 
 in nearly 19
 years
 By Jeannine Aversa, Associated Press, 5/7/2002 10:54
 
 WASHINGTON (AP) Worker productivity, a key ingredient to the economy's
 long-term vitality, shot up at an annual rate of 8.6 percent 
 in the first quarter, the best performance in nearly 19 years... 

Labor productivity is key to long-term vitality (as some old German guy
said), but a single quarter's statistic means little or nothing about the
trend in this variable, since quarterly statistics jump around the trend.
(This is especially true since the numbers being reported are preliminary
estimates.) In addition to statistical noise, it likely shot up due to:

1. the big increase in demand -- due to monetary and fiscal stimulus -- that
allowed employers to use long-term or overhead employees' time more
completely, or to distribute their salary costs over more units of output.
(These folks make little or no direct contribution to production in the
short run.) 

2. decreases in the amount of overhead labor held, as part of the continued
response to the 2001 recession.

3. speed-up of production workers (and/or increases in hours of unpaid
work), as a part of the continued response to the 2001 recession and the
increase in demand.

The above fits with:
 ... But the improvement came at a price. Businesses, responding to the
lingering effects of last year's recession, cut back on their payrolls. That
caused the total number of hours worked to fall at a rate of 1.9 percent.
Output, however, rose at a solid 6.5 percent rate.
 
... The rise in productivity in the first quarter helped to push down unit
labor costs, a gauge of inflation. Unit labor costs declined  at an annual
rate of 5.4 percent, the biggest drop since the second  quarter of 1983. In
the fourth quarter, unit labor costs fell at a rate of 3.1 percent.

Unit labor costs only drop due to increases in labor productivity when
workers don't share in the benefits of increased productivity. That is,
wages are not rising with producitivity. In the short run, in other words,
the rate of surplus-value is increasing for this sector of the economy. 

... In general, productivity tends to rise strongly when the economy is
booming. Gains in productivity can become weak or productivity can fall when
the economy slows or contracts.

this is due to effect #1 above. 

 In the long run, productivity gains are good for workers, for the economy
and for companies, whose profits took a hit during the slump.

productivity gains are often _not_ shared with workers, as during most of
the quarter-century after 1975. Also, labor productivity gains often imply
the shedding of labor (or slow growth of employment), as in manufacturing
during recent decades, because demand may not rise in step with labor
productivity. (Of course, labor productivity refers to only production
sold through the market, ignoring external costs  benefits.) 

 Gains in productivity allow companies to pay workers more without raising
prices, which would eat up those wage gains, and permit the economy to grow
faster without triggering inflation. If productivity falters, however,
pressure for higher wages could force companies to  raise prices,  thus
worsening inflation.

most students of this phenomenon would say that increases or decreases in
labor productivity that are due to demand changes -- and effect #1 above --
do not help to avoid or help to stimulate inflation. It's the _trend_ rate
of growth of labor productivity that is relevant here. Again, one quarter's
labor productivity growth is not a good way to judge the trend.

Jim Devine




machines and labor productivity at Amazon.com

2002-01-21 Thread Ian Murray

[NYTimes]
January 21, 2002
Amazon Ships to Sorting Machine Beat
By SAUL HANSELL
FERNLEY, Nev., Jan. 18 - Ever since it built five vast warehouses in 1999, Amazon 
(news/quote) .com
has boasted of the wonders of the machinery inside them - 10 miles of conveyer belts 
and myriad
other gadgets.

What Amazon was not so vocal about was how many people it took to operate those 
machines, especially
during the holiday rush. In 2000, for example, Amazon had to hire 7,200 temporary 
workers to
supplement the 4,400 people working in its warehouses in the United States.

Now, Amazon.com, once the champion the strategy of get big fast, has learned how to 
become small.
On Dec. 11, its busiest day last year, Amazon's warehouses employed only 4,000 temps 
and 3,700
full-time employees. With one-third fewer people than the year before, the warehouses 
processed what
analysts estimate were 10 to 15 percent more items.

Amazon, which plans to release its fourth- quarter results on Tuesday morning, needs 
every dollar it
can save. A year ago, the company - which has lost $2.8 billion since its founding in 
1995 -
promised investors it would turn an operating profit in the fourth quarter of 2001 (at 
least by its
own pro forma calculation).

That goal was made harder because Amazon's sales grew at only half the rate it 
predicted at the
beginning of the year, dragged down by the recession, the aftermath of Sept. 11 and 
some of the
company's own missteps.

If, as analysts expect, Amazon nonetheless hits its fourth-quarter profit target, a 
key reason will
be the savings from its yearlong campaign to reorganize the people and the machines in 
its
warehouses.

They are focused on productivity in a very structured way, and it appears they have 
made good
progress, said Anthony Noto, an analyst for Goldman, Sachs. Mr. Noto estimates that
order-fulfillment costs absorbed 11 percent of Amazon's sales in the fourth quarter, 
down from 13.5
percent a year earlier. Still, he said, those costs need to fall below 9 percent for 
the company to
thrive.

Walking amid a forest of bookshelves and climbing metal bridges over the rivers of 
conveyer belts in
the warehouse here 40 miles east of Reno, Jeff Wilke, Amazon's senior vice president 
for operations,
pointed to dozens of improvements big and small.

One big goal had been to reduce errors in keeping track of the several million items 
continually
being placed onto and pulled off of hundreds of thousands of bins on metal shelves. In 
theory,
Amazon's computers know exactly where each item is at any moment. But in 2000, the 
computers were
wrong more than 10 percent of the time, causing delays as workers searched for missing 
items and
restocked spares.

We had a whole secret plant, not our main focus, putting stuff back, Mr. Wilke said.

To reduce errors, Amazon wrote new software to take better advantage of the gizmo that 
each
warehouse worker was already carrying - a shoehorn-size device that combines a bar 
code scanner, a
display screen and a two-way data transmitter.

The new software beams far more explicit instructions to workers about where they 
should go and what
they should do. And it checks their work by forcing them to scan each item every time 
they put it on
or take it off a shelf. Errors have fallen to below 5 percent, from 10 percent, Mr. 
Wilke said.

This new system also helps with another of Mr. Wilke's main goals - improving the 
productivity of
seasonal temporary workers - by giving them more direction. It also monitors their 
performance, so
those who cannot get up to speed in a week or so are given help - then fired, if 
necessary. Amazon
also instituted a formal training program for temps. As a result, the average 
productivity of each
temporary worker has doubled.

Many of Mr. Wilke's efforts reflect the highly quantitative bent expected of an 
M.I.T.-trained
engineer who ran chemical plants for Allied Signal before joining Amazon in 1999. But 
when he talks
about the biggest change here in Fernley, he uses the language of music, not 
manufacturing.

We needed to build cadence, Mr. Wilke said, to operate to the drumbeat of the 
constraint.

The drumbeating constraint is the $25 million Crisplant sorting machine at the center 
of Amazon's
automated approach. Working with batches of 500 to 2,000 orders, the employees with 
the hand-held
terminals feed items onto a network of conveyor belts into the sorting machine. The 
machine reads
the bar code on each item and routes it into one of 2,100 chutes, each chute 
representing an order
for a single customer. When all the items in an order are in the chute, a light 
flashes, and a
worker rushes to put them in a box. They are then sent on other conveyers to machines 
that print
packing slips, seal the boxes and send them off to shippers' trucks.

Adopting such an expensive and complex machine was controversial for Amazon.

Mr. Wilke acknowledges that he was skeptical of the Crisplant machines when he joined 
Amazon

Will Hutton on Enron productivity

2002-01-13 Thread Ian Murray

[snip]
...Enron could not have made the progress it did
without the intellectual backdrop that all regulation
and taxation is bad - and that the more the US
deregulated, the better its economy performed. This
was, and is, balderdash. Recent work by economists,
notably at investment bank Credit Suisse First Boston,
shows that after making the necessary accounting
adjustments and including downward revisions,
productivity growth in the US has done no more than
match that in Europe. Indeed, countries like France and
Germany have higher absolute productivity and faster
rates of growth than the Americans, despite their
approach to regulation and taxation. [snip]


http://www.observer.co.uk/comment/story/0,6903,632020,0
0.html 




productivity happy labor day!

2001-09-03 Thread Jim Devine

from the L.A. TIMES [9/3//01] --

Productivity Said Key to Rebound

Symposium: Top policymakers and others say a sustained pickup in worker 
output is needed for economy's recovery. (from Reuters)

JACKSON HOLE, Wyo. -- The information technology boom of the 1990s stoked a 
new economy characterized by surging output per worker but with 
hard-to-measure and possibly vulnerable underpinnings, participants at a 
blue-ribbon crowd of policymakers, economists and academics heard over the 
weekend.

Most felt a slowdown in the U.S. economy, which has developed over the last 
year, will ease later this year or in 2002. However, its timing and vigor 
depend on a pickup in productivity, or output per worker, being sustained 
even in the face of a rapid falloff in business capital spending on 
computers and other goods.

The information economy was the theme of this year's exclusive gathering, 
the 25th such symposium at a remote Rocky Mountain resort. Organized by the 
Kansas City Federal Reserve Bank, it brought Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan 
and about 100 people together to mull the issue in the meetings and to swap 
observations on the state of the economy in the corridors. All agreed that 
a remarkable speedup in productivity from about the mid-1990s until 
2000--when the pace of U.S. economic growth began to slow--was a key not 
only to past but future performance. In the process, it changed the way in 
which Americans work and spend and add to their incomes.

The high-pressure economy, tight labor market and gratifyingly low 
unemployment rate of the last half-decade is hard to envision without the 
productivity speedup, which is largely driven by the technological 
revolutions in data processing and data communications, said Lawrence 
Summers, president of Harvard University and former Treasury secretary.

Greenspan did not directly address the symposium's theme, snip

A strong flavor of uncertainty hung over the proceedings, with several 
participants noting the U.S. economy can successfully skirt recession if 
productivity holds up, but it could quickly be in trouble if output per 
worker falls to lower rates found in the 1970s and 1980s.

If the productivity trend collapses, the favorable performance of the '90s 
could unravel, with higher inflation, higher unemployment, slower growth, 
stock market weakness and a dollar that could drop sharply, cautioned 
Martin Baily, a senior fellow at the Institute for International Economics 
and a former chairman of the White House Council of Economic Advisers in 
the Clinton administration.

With the U.S. economy by far the largest in the world, Europe growing 
slowly and Japan in a funk, the prospect that a U.S. bounceback is so 
dependent upon productivity clearly made some participants nervous.

Michael Mussa, former chief economist and now special advisor to the 
International Monetary Fund, said he worried about unreasonably 
optimistic hopes for productivity gains, especially at a time when the 
U.S. economy already is burdened by a huge trade imbalance and when the 
U.S. dollar is at strong levels relative to other currencies.

If expectations disappoint, a lot of those imbalances could come back to 
haunt the United States and the global economy going forward, Mussa warned.

[COMMENT: I've decided that in common parlance, even among economists (who 
should know better), productivity is usually mixed up with 
profitability. So when the economists say they want increased 
productivity, they mean they want businesses' bottom lines to be doing 
better. This confusion arises in two main ways (besides the 
muddle-headedness of orthodox economics). First, rising labor productivity 
growth rates do NOT prevent inflation if workers get nominal wage gains in 
step with labor productivity. Economists assume -- and hope -- that wages 
won't do so, i.e., that profitability will rise. Also, note that increases 
in productivity growth can hurt recovery: if wages fall behind 
productivity, that hurts consumer spending (all else equal) relative to 
output. If fixed investment is stalled (along with other sources of 
aggregate demand), that hurts aggregate demand. If profitability rises, 
it's possible that fixed investment could get out of its stall.

[Second, economists talk about the disgustingly crude concept of total 
factor productivity (output divided by the weighted sum of capital 
services and labor services). Not only are the components of the 
denominator almost impossible to measure, but they are weighted according 
to what they are paid in the national income  product accounts (assuming 
that capital and labor are paid according to their contribution!) 
What's left -- the residual -- is mostly profits. So when total factor 
productivity goes up, so does the profit rate.]

[andÂ… happy labor day!]

Workers See Power Shifting to Employers

Labor: The economic slowdown has given companies the edge in the job market.

By LISA GIRION, TIMES STAFF WRITER

Re: productivity happy labor day!

2001-09-03 Thread Tom Walker

Or, maybe what economists really mean (although they don't know it) is
literally an increase in the rate of surplus value. See Marc Linder's From
Surplus Value to Unit Labor Costs: The Bourgeoisification of a Communist
Conspiracy in his _Labor Statistics and Class Struggle_. 

Linder tells the tale of the peregrination of an American Federation of
Labor resolution to link wage increases to productivity gains to a Marxist
statistical analysis (by Juergen Kuczynski in the 1920s) in support of that
resolution to a business argument that wages must not exceed productivity
gains to a status quo policy regime that productivity gains must precede and
exceed even nominal wage increases.

Jim Devine wrote,

[COMMENT: I've decided that in common parlance, even among economists (who 
should know better), productivity is usually mixed up with 
profitability. So when the economists say they want increased 
productivity, they mean they want businesses' bottom lines to be doing 
better. This confusion arises in two main ways (besides the 
muddle-headedness of orthodox economics). First, rising labor productivity 
growth rates do NOT prevent inflation if workers get nominal wage gains in 
step with labor productivity. Economists assume -- and hope -- that wages 
won't do so, i.e., that profitability will rise. Also, note that increases 
in productivity growth can hurt recovery: if wages fall behind 
productivity, that hurts consumer spending (all else equal) relative to 
output. If fixed investment is stalled (along with other sources of 
aggregate demand), that hurts aggregate demand. If profitability rises, 
it's possible that fixed investment could get out of its stall.

[Second, economists talk about the disgustingly crude concept of total 
factor productivity (output divided by the weighted sum of capital 
services and labor services). Not only are the components of the 
denominator almost impossible to measure, but they are weighted according 
to what they are paid in the national income  product accounts (assuming 
that capital and labor are paid according to their contribution!) 
What's left -- the residual -- is mostly profits. So when total factor 
productivity goes up, so does the profit rate.]


Tom Walker
Bowen Island, BC
604 947 2213




Re: Re: productivity happy labor day!

2001-09-03 Thread Jim Devine

At 08:58 AM 09/03/2001 -0700, you wrote:
Or, maybe what economists really mean (although they don't know it) is
literally an increase in the rate of surplus value.

exactly.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]  http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~JDevine




35-hour French surpass overworked US in productivity

2001-09-01 Thread Tom Walker

The NYT article below buries its lead in paragraph 13:

But partly because of the comparatively high number of hours that Americans
work, the report found that France and Belgium edged out the United States
in productivity per hour. In France, which ranked first, workers produced
$33.71 of value added per hour on average, compared with $32.98 in Belgium
and $32.84 in the United States.

http://www.nytimes.com/2001/09/01/national/01HOUR.html?todaysheadlines 

New York Times: September 1, 2001

Report Shows Americans Have More 'Labor Days'

By STEVEN GREENHOUSE

United Nations agency provided some discouraging news yesterday to Americans
who believe they are overworked, finding that American workers have
increased their substantial lead over Japan and all other industrial nations
in the number of hours worked each year.

The report, issued by the International Labor Organization, found that
Americans added nearly a full week to their work year during the 1990's,
climbing to 1,979 hours on average last year, up 36 hours from 1990. That
means Americans who are employed are putting in nearly 49 1/2 weeks a year
on the job.

. . .
Tom Walker
Bowen Island, BC
604 947 2213




Marginal productivity is for the other guy

2001-08-30 Thread Michael Keaney

Spearheading the latest ineffectual populist campaign the whole family
can join, the Guardian helpfully signals the difficult issues involved:

Anger at boom in executive pay

(snip)

But Sir Ken Jackson, Blairite leader of the AEEU engineering union and
a supporter of public service reforms, sounded a different note.
Where performance merits competitive levels of pay, then we support
companies rewarding their workers at all levels, including the
boardroom.

==

Prompting one to ask about remuneration for AEEU full time officials...

Any trade union leader who sports a sir or any badge of toadying (OBE,
MBE, CBE) -- and there's a lot -- sold the jerseys years ago.
Particularly if he is not yet retired.

In the early 1980s film-maker Ken Loach was commissioned by newly begun
and independent Channel 4 to film a series of documentaries on the
leadership of the British trade unions, Questions of Leadership. These
were completed, but never shown, and, apparently, are still banned. This
is John Pilger's take on the subject, since he seems to have been one of
the few lucky enough to have seen them:


The big unions, like the TGWU, are still absurdly portrayed by the
Tories and much of the media as a potentially dangerous fifth column in
the body politic. Yet without the timidity and inaction of some of the
famous union 'barons', the legislative attack on trade union rights in
the Eighties probably would have failed, along with the devastation of
the steel and mining industries, and the privatising of the docks.

This perspective on the unions has always been something of a taboo. It
was considered so threatening during the early part of Thatcher's reign
that a 1982 television series by Ken Loach, Questions Of Leadership, for
the fledgling Channel 4, was withdrawn and then drastically cut.
Consider the opening sequence of the Loach films. Over archive film of a
mass meeting of trade unionists during the Thirties Depression, the
sound-track begins to play the chorus from Gilbert and Sullivan's
Iolanthe:

Bow low ye lower middle classes;

Bow, bow ye tradesmen;

Bow ye masses . . .

As the mockery continues, the pictures dissolve to a parade of earnest
young men, standing on platforms, exhorting the masses. Then they grow
older, florid, comfortable, and become portraits of self-satisfaction,
dressed in the ermine of the House of Lords. They are Joe Gormley, Vic
Feather, Richard Marsh, all former trade union leaders (soon to be
joined by Lord Len Murray). The commentary says, 'There are some trades
union leaders who have in their own person achieved the harmony of the
classes.' Rank and file trade unionists speak about the meaning of
'democracy' within the big unions, referring to 'small bureaucratic,
centralised groups of people . . . that prevent individual members from
playing a role within the union and the general direction the union is
going'. Were these not the familiar media words of right-wingers
complaining about the 'militants' infiltrating their 'democratic'
institutions? Yes, but in the Loach film the voices came from ordinary
trade unionists analysing the hold of the trade union establishment on
the organisations and fortunes of millions of ordinary people.

From They Never Walk Alone (Part 1)
http://pilger.carlton.com/print/48727

As Joe Gormley once said when discovered in a posh restaurant:
nothing's too good for the working class.

Michael K.




Marginal productivity is for the other guy

2001-08-29 Thread Ian Murray

Anger at boom in executive pay

Call for government action as unions and investors condemn effects of
top bosses achieving 28% rises

Jill Treanor and David Gow
Thursday August 30, 2001
The Guardian

Unions, powerful City investors, and company directors united
yesterday to round on the boards of FTSE 100 companies after the
Guardian-Inbucon survey revealed Britain's top bosses enjoyed 28% pay
rises last year.

Union leaders urged the government to appoint at least two employee
representatives to the secretive committees determining company
directors' pay, while Ruth Lea, head of the policy unit of the
Institute of Directors, warned these same committees against
remuneration ratcheting by rubber stamping wage rises.

The powerful body which represents all the major pen sion funds, the
National Association of Pension Funds, said the 28% jump - some six
times higher than the average pay increase - appeared to flout City
rules set to standards for corporate behaviour.

The rules call for these remuneration committees to be sensitive to
the wider scene...including pay and employment conditions when
determining annual salary increases.

Chris Baldry, manager of the NAPF's voting issues service, said:
There will be general concern about the numbers the Guardian has
unearthed. The figure seems very high and doesn't seem to comply with
the combined code (which sets City rules). Several unions are also
dismayed by what they see as the failure of the government to crack
down on so-called boardroom excesses, despite a raft of promises to
force companies to link pay to performance.

Ministers talked tough and the reality is that nothing has happened,
a senior trade union official said.

The government has said it would require companies to allow
shareholders to vote each year on the pay policy. Yesterday, sources
at the Department of Trade and Industry would only say the situation
was being reviewed.

John Monks, TUC general secretary, who is struggling to devise a
common TUC front on the issue of public services between outright
opponents of privatisation and the modernisers, believes the growing
gap between boardroom salary packages, irrespective of merit, and the
rest of the workforce is seriously damaging companies' morale and
will spill over into debates at next month's TUC congress.

Public service unions, already planning an assault at the congress on
plans for partial privatisation of key services such as education and
health, were outraged.

Dave Prentis, leader of Unison, the biggest public service union,
said: How much longer can fat cat bosses justify these huge pay and
perks while millions of workers are denied a decent living wage?

Calling for remuneration committees to have employee representation to
compel companies to justify pay packages to annual general meetings,
Mr Monks said: Fat cat pay shows no signs of letting up.

Ms Lea contrasted the rise in the boardoom with the IoD's surveys,
which showed the majority of all company directors - not just those in
the FTSE 100 - saw pay rises of just 4%. She said: I think
remuneration committees do have a tendency to look at the median
earnings and say 'Our chaps are better than the average and need
higher than the median'. Some questioned whether the threat of a
downturn would stem boardroom pay.

Michelle Edkins, corporate governance director at Hermes, which
manages BT's pension fund, said: It will be interesting to see
whether recession drives pay down. But in recessions, you will still
need strong executives.

But Sir Ken Jackson, Blairite leader of the AEEU engineering union and
a supporter of public service reforms, sounded a different note.
Where performance merits competitive levels of pay, then we support
companies rewarding their workers at all levels, including the
boardroom.







Productivity Byte, 8/7/01 by Dean Baker: Productivity Revisions Tarnish New Economy

2001-08-07 Thread Robert Naiman



August 7, 2001

Productivity Revisions Tarnish New Economy

By Dean Baker
__
___

The lower productivity numbers should raise
serious questions
about stock prices.
__
___

The second quarter productivity release included
large
downward revisions to previously released
productivity
numbers. These revisions raise serious questions
about the
extent to which the United States really has a
new economy
with a qualitatively different productivity growth
path.

The reported annual rate of productivity growth in
the non-
farm business sector from the fourth quarter of
1997 to the
fourth quarter of 2000 (the period for which data
was
revised), was lowered from 3.24 percent to 2.69
percent. This
is still a significant upturn from the 1.35
percent annual
rate of growth from 1973 to 1995, but much less
impressive
than the numbers originally reported.

The data for the second quarter of 2001 showed a
strong
rebound from the first quarter, with productivity
rising at a
2.5 percent annual rate in the second quarter
compared with an
increase of just 0.1 percent in the first quarter.
However,
this turnaround was entirely attributable to a
sharp drop in
the number of working hours reported in the second
quarter.
According to Labor Department's data, hours worked
fell at a
2.4 percent annual rate in the quarter. The
numbers reported
for hours worked in this data is poorly measured.
It is more
likely that the falloff in hours reported in the
second
quarter, and therefore the rise in productivity
growth, was
attributable to errors in measurement.
Productivity has
probably been advancing at an annual rate close to
the average
reported for the first two quarters, or 1.3
percent, so far
this year.

The main reason for the downward revisions in the
productivity
data was a downward revision in the rate of output
growth
reported for 1999 and 2000. The increase in output
in the non-
farm business sector had originally been reported
as 5.7 and
3.6 percent, respectively. In the new report the
growth rate
of output for 1999 was revised down to 4.9
percent, and to 2.8
percent for 2000. The downward revision to output
was in turn
primarily attributable to a significant reduction
in the
output of software reported by the Commerce
Department in its
GDP revisions last month.

With this report, the new economy years from 1996
to 2000 look
somewhat less impressive. The average rate of
productivity
growth over this period was 2.5 percent, compared
to the 2.9
percent previously reported. It is also worth
noting that this
2.5 percent figure somewhat overstates the
increase per hour
in usable output. Productivity is a measure of
gross output
per hour. The output that is actually usable, by
consumers or
firms, is determined by the growth in net output.
The
difference in the measures is the amount of output
that is
used to replace warn out or obsolete equipment.
Wages and
profits must be generated out of net output, no
one can eat
worn out equipment.

Typically, the increase in gross and net output is
virtually
the same. In fact, in the sixties and seventies
net output
actually increased slightly faster than gross
output. However,
in the last five years, there has been a large gap
between the
growth of gross and net output, with gross output
rising at a
rate that is approximately 0.35 percentage points
faster than
net output, on average. This difference is due to
the
increasing use of computers, which have very short
lives.

This means that a productivity measure that
examined the
growth in net output over the period from 1996 to
2000 would
show an annual rate of growth of less than 2.2
percent. This
is still an upturn from the productivity growth
rates of the
mid seventies and eighties, but its far below the
3.0 percent
productivity growth rates of the sixties.

The productivity revisions in this report should
raise
questions among new economy optimists. It is
unlikely that we
will see the sort of rapid GDP and profit growth
that many had
anticipated. This should raise some questions on
Wall Street,
where stocks are still priced as though the
economy will
maintain high rates of growth for the indefinite
future.

The downward revisions may also affect budget
projections. The
Congressional Budget Office assumed that
productivity growth
will average 2.7 percent over the next decade.
With the
revised data, the rate assumed by CBO is now
higher than the
growth rate achieved even at the peak of the boom.
Based on
this new data, CBO is likely to revise down its
growth
projections, and its surplus projections as well.






Productivity miracle or mirage?

2001-07-03 Thread Keaney Michael

Penners

Here's an interesting interview with someone who sounds interesting on the
topic of the IT investment boom and the great US productivity miracle. In
the same edition of the FT, Harvard professor Martin Feldstein pens an
opinion piece warning that thanks to this apparent miracle the US is
well-placed to rebound from its current economic difficulties, while Europe
is doomed to play catch-up, and always from far behind, thanks to its
attachment to old ways. Feldstein concludes: In Europe, fundamental changes
in employment practices, labour markets and management incentives are
necessary to encourage rapid adoption of new technology that can raise
productivity while increasing employment. Without such changes, the gap
between US and European incomes will continue to widen. In what
direction??? See
http://globalarchive.ft.com/globalarchive/articles.html?print=trueid=010628
001693
To me, at least, Strassmann reads a lot more convincingly.
=
Guru of profitless computing

Financial Times, Jun 28, 2001

BY ALAN CANE

Paul Strassmann is playing his favourite role once more: the computer expert
who claims companies are wasting money on computers. 
The information technology industry's leading iconoclast has been rehearsing
the part during more than 40 years of rigorous research into companies and
their use of IT. However, as the latest of his more than 200 reports, books
and articles on the subject nears publication, his message has been refined
into its ultimate, devastating form. 
Mr Strassmann's central thesis is that no relationship can be demonstrated
between the amount a company spends on computer systems and its
profitability. And, he believes, none ever will be. 
He quotes for emphasis Robert Solow, the Nobel Prize-winning economist, who
taught him statistics at Massachusetts Institute of Technology: You can see
computers everywhere - except in economic statistics. 
A second argument is no less contentious: that the IT industry, customers
and vendors alike, is on the cusp of an important - and final - disjunction:
Every seven years, we have torn up what has gone before and started again,
he says. There have been eight cycles of 'build and scrap' since 1946. The
first cost $100m, equal to 7 per cent of business investment at the time.
The last cost $2,000bn, or 47 per cent. The next would have cost $5,000bn
but we have run out of money: we have come to the end of history as we know
it. 
These conclusions have a significance beyond the computer industry. The US,
which spends more on IT than any other nation, is on the brink of its first
recession in a decade, dragging with it much of the developed world. It has
sustained growth during the past 10 years, many think, by investing in
information systems. The pundits argue that this has delivered competitive
gains, accelerated transactions and increased customer satisfaction. Many
other nations, envious of the performance of the US economy in the past
decade, have set out to achieve the same miracle. 
But is this belief in IT as the powerhouse of improved productivity
misplaced? Has the US's share of that $2,000bn been squandered on a false
promise? 
Few are better placed to answer these questions than Mr Strassmann, now 72
and as active in retirement as when he was chief information officer for the
US Department of Defence. 
His career has seen him managing the information interests of large
companies, including Kraft and Xerox. It culminated in his appointment to a
newly created post of director of defence information at the Department of
Defence, where he was responsible for a $35bn cost-reduction programme. He
oversaw the DoD IT strategy at the time of the Gulf war and was rewarded
with the Defence Medal for Distinguished Public Service, its highest
civilian award. 
It is, however, the quality and quantity of the data underpinning his chief
contentions that set Mr Strassmann apart. He has been collecting financial
statistics on the world's principal companies with all the enthusiasm of a
trainspotter since 1954, soon after leaving Cooper Union college in New York
City with an engineering degree. 
Today, the numbers - revenue, profits, assets, productivity, head count and
so on - fill appendix after appendix in his published works. He is
contemptuous of the profusion of studies from consultancies and the computer
industry proving the value of investment in computer systems: I give
little credence to the gloss. I say: 'Show me the numbers,' he declares
with a grin. Not for Mr Strassmann the superficial 150 leading companies
that contribute to most surveys. His latest work, on European
competitiveness, analyses in depth more than 3,000 companies. 
The question of how investment in computers may be linked to profitability
is as intriguing as it is difficult to answer, in spite of intensive efforts
during the past half-century. 
Mr Strassmann believes his numbers indicate unequivocally that there is no
connection between investment in computers

Re: Productivity miracle or mirage?

2001-07-03 Thread Michael Perelman

Strassmann's book, The Squandered Computer, is interesting.  His work is often
contrasted with Eric Brynjolfsson of MIT, who seems to make the strongest case
for the New Economy of all the economists.  He tries to measure the actual
productivity of computers and high tech gear.  Needless to say, his work is not
universally accepted.


Keaney Michael wrote:

 Penners

 Here's an interesting interview with someone who sounds interesting on the
 topic of the IT investment boom and the great US productivity miracle. In
 the same edition of the FT, Harvard professor Martin Feldstein pens an
 opinion piece warning that thanks to this apparent miracle the US is
 well-placed to rebound from its current economic difficulties, while Europe
 is doomed to play catch-up, and always from far behind, thanks to its
 attachment to old ways. Feldstein concludes: In Europe, fundamental changes
 in employment practices, labour markets and management incentives are
 necessary to encourage rapid adoption of new technology that can raise
 productivity while increasing employment. Without such changes, the gap
 between US and European incomes will continue to widen. In what
 direction??? See
 http://globalarchive.ft.com/globalarchive/articles.html?print=trueid=010628
 001693
 To me, at least, Strassmann reads a lot more convincingly.
 =
 Guru of profitless computing

 Financial Times, Jun 28, 2001

 BY ALAN CANE

 Paul Strassmann is playing his favourite role once more: the computer expert
 who claims companies are wasting money on computers.
 The information technology industry's leading iconoclast has been rehearsing
 the part during more than 40 years of rigorous research into companies and
 their use of IT. However, as the latest of his more than 200 reports, books
 and articles on the subject nears publication, his message has been refined
 into its ultimate, devastating form.
 Mr Strassmann's central thesis is that no relationship can be demonstrated
 between the amount a company spends on computer systems and its
 profitability. And, he believes, none ever will be.
 He quotes for emphasis Robert Solow, the Nobel Prize-winning economist, who
 taught him statistics at Massachusetts Institute of Technology: You can see
 computers everywhere - except in economic statistics.
 A second argument is no less contentious: that the IT industry, customers
 and vendors alike, is on the cusp of an important - and final - disjunction:
 Every seven years, we have torn up what has gone before and started again,
 he says. There have been eight cycles of 'build and scrap' since 1946. The
 first cost $100m, equal to 7 per cent of business investment at the time.
 The last cost $2,000bn, or 47 per cent. The next would have cost $5,000bn
 but we have run out of money: we have come to the end of history as we know
 it.
 These conclusions have a significance beyond the computer industry. The US,
 which spends more on IT than any other nation, is on the brink of its first
 recession in a decade, dragging with it much of the developed world. It has
 sustained growth during the past 10 years, many think, by investing in
 information systems. The pundits argue that this has delivered competitive
 gains, accelerated transactions and increased customer satisfaction. Many
 other nations, envious of the performance of the US economy in the past
 decade, have set out to achieve the same miracle.
 But is this belief in IT as the powerhouse of improved productivity
 misplaced? Has the US's share of that $2,000bn been squandered on a false
 promise?
 Few are better placed to answer these questions than Mr Strassmann, now 72
 and as active in retirement as when he was chief information officer for the
 US Department of Defence.
 His career has seen him managing the information interests of large
 companies, including Kraft and Xerox. It culminated in his appointment to a
 newly created post of director of defence information at the Department of
 Defence, where he was responsible for a $35bn cost-reduction programme. He
 oversaw the DoD IT strategy at the time of the Gulf war and was rewarded
 with the Defence Medal for Distinguished Public Service, its highest
 civilian award.
 It is, however, the quality and quantity of the data underpinning his chief
 contentions that set Mr Strassmann apart. He has been collecting financial
 statistics on the world's principal companies with all the enthusiasm of a
 trainspotter since 1954, soon after leaving Cooper Union college in New York
 City with an engineering degree.
 Today, the numbers - revenue, profits, assets, productivity, head count and
 so on - fill appendix after appendix in his published works. He is
 contemptuous of the profusion of studies from consultancies and the computer
 industry proving the value of investment in computer systems: I give
 little credence to the gloss. I say: 'Show me the numbers,' he declares
 with a grin. Not for Mr Strassmann the superficial 150 leading companies

US productivity shows steepest fall since 1993

2001-06-05 Thread Louis Proyect

www.ft.com

US productivity shows steepest fall since 1993 

By Peronet Despeignes in Washington Published: June 5 2001 13:06

US workforce productivity fell more than expected in the first quarter amid
a slowdown in demand for goods and services that was more abrupt than
previously thought. 

The labour department said on Tuesday that output per person-hour outside
the agricultural sector dipped at an annual rate of 1.2 per cent in the
first quarter, marking the first time US productivity has faltered since
1995 and its biggest decline since 1993. The report revised sharply
downward the initial estimate of a 0.1 per cent dip. The sharp
first-quarter drop followed the previous quarter's 2 per cent gain. 

Lower productivity and continued gains in worker pay mean higher labour
costs per unit of output - a key inflation gauge. Labour costs jumped at
the fastest pace in a decade - at a 6.3 per cent annual rate instead of the
5.2 per cent in the first quarter initially estimated. 

It is the first time US labour productivity has sunk since economists began
asking five years ago whether the US economy had entered a new era of
perpetually fast growth, low inflation, fatter profits and rising living
standards due to the adoption of new technologies and better economic
policies. 

Higher productivity was a distinguishing feature of US economic performance
in the 1990's. Other industrialised nations failed to match its twin
achievements of strong job creation and accelerating productivity growth
from 1995 to 2000, according to a recent survey of international trends by
the Conference Board, a New York-based research group. 

The Board's report found that outside of the US virtually every country
showed decelerations in productivity growth in the latter half of the
decade. Japan managed to maintain persistently high productivity growth at
the expense of employment growth. 

The revival of job creation in Europe over the past five years came amid
slowing productivity growth. The report, by authors Robert H McGuckin and
Bart van Ark, concluded that greater economic reforms allowed the US to
make better use of its resources, including labour and capital. 

New-era enthusiasts, including Alan Greenspan, Federal Reserve chairman,
and Roger Ferguson, Fed vice chairman, have repeatedly expressed faith in
the possibility that productivity would hold up through any downturn. After
its last interest-rate cut in mid-May, the Fed's policy-making open market
committee, said in a public statement that although measured productivity
growth stalled in the first quarter, the impressive underlying rate of
increase that developed in recent years appears to be largely intact,
supporting longer-term prospects. 

This assumption is critical because the pickup in productivity growth over
the past few years helped suppress US inflation. If the nation's money
supply were rising much faster than its output of goods and services,
inflation might become a bigger problem for the Fed, which is currently
fighting off recession risks with interest rate cuts - a point reaffirmed
recently by Robert McTeer, president of the Dallas Federal Reserve. In
comments at a Puerto Rico banking conference this week, Mr McTeer said he
was uncertain about the assumption that inflation would slow along with the
economy: I believe that in part inflation went down in the late 1990s not
despite rapid growth but because of rapid growth [in output of goods and
services]. If too much money is chasing too few goods, causing inflation,
more goods are just as helpful as less money. Sceptics of the new economy
view, including Robert Gordon, Northwestern University economics professor,
and recently Stephen Cecchetti, former research director of the New York
Federal Reserve, have expressed growing doubt that the productivity surge
was real or enduring. 

One top Fed official told the Financial Times recently that the central
bank needed to better justify its faith. Another senior official, Fed board
member Laurence, plans to give a speech on the topic tomorrow. 

What the latest figures actually say about the strength of the US economy's
productivity miracle is unclear. One quarter's data is not a trend, and
both cyclical and structural factors influence productivity. 

The current downturn may say more about the abrupt slowdown in demand for
goods and services than the private sector's ability to improve efficiency. 

But the sharp, ongoing plunge in business spending on equipment and
software that is supposedly productivity-enhancing and renewed uncertainty
among investors about the course of US economic policymaking amid political
changes in Washington have cast doubt on that as well. 


Louis Proyect
Marxism mailing list: http://www.marxmail.org




Re: US productivity shows steepest fall since 1993

2001-06-05 Thread Rob Schaap

Of course, none of this matters a jot to the markets.  They're efficiently
signalling nothing but blue sky today - the Hand as unseeing as it is
invisible.  

Funny; if technology really is responsible for rising productivity, it makes
sense to drop rates again, so that capital investment might be resuscitated,
and productivity thus rejuvenated.  But the monetarist's way to combat high
wages in times of decreasing productivity and upcoming tax cuts should be to
hike interest rates, no?

Wouldn't be Greenspan for quids ...

Cheers,
Rob.




Re: Re: US productivity shows steepest fall since 1993

2001-06-05 Thread Ian Murray


- Original Message -
From: Rob Schaap [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: Tuesday, June 05, 2001 6:26 PM
Subject: [PEN-L:12775] Re: US productivity shows steepest fall since
1993


 Of course, none of this matters a jot to the markets.  They're
efficiently
 signalling nothing but blue sky today - the Hand as unseeing as it
is
 invisible.

 Funny; if technology really is responsible for rising productivity,
it makes
 sense to drop rates again, so that capital investment might be
resuscitated,
 and productivity thus rejuvenated.  But the monetarist's way to
combat high
 wages in times of decreasing productivity and upcoming tax cuts
should be to
 hike interest rates, no?

 Wouldn't be Greenspan for quids ...

 Cheers,
 Rob.
=
I'm always fascinated by the absence of naming slow sales as the
culprit for lagging productivity. If no one's biting on the product,
workers can't help but slow down on the jobs/sales that are still in
the pipeline. Sales teams get boom tired too.

Ian




Re: US productivity shows steepest fall since 1993

2001-06-05 Thread Jim Devine

the FINANCIAL TIMES wrote:
US productivity shows steepest fall since 1993

...The labour department said on Tuesday that output per person-hour outside
the agricultural sector dipped at an annual rate of 1.2 per cent in the
first quarter, marking the first time US productivity has faltered since
1995 and its biggest decline since 1993. The report revised sharply
downward the initial estimate of a 0.1 per cent dip. The sharp
first-quarter drop followed the previous quarter's 2 per cent gain.

Lower productivity and continued gains in worker pay mean higher labour
costs per unit of output - a key inflation gauge. Labour costs jumped at
the fastest pace in a decade - at a 6.3 per cent annual rate instead of the
5.2 per cent in the first quarter initially estimated.

Of course, as the article notes toward the end, labor productivity falls 
every time there's a recession or a sharp slow-down of the economy (since 
the workers not laid off -- the overhead managers, staff,  supervisors -- 
aren't productive, at least in the short run). This causes unit labor costs 
to rise, as does the fact that the less-well-paid workers tend to be laid 
off first. But this is not a sign of inflation to come, since it reflects a 
fall in demand.

(Wachtel and Adelsheim once argued that recessions promote inflation as 
monopoly corporations try to restore profitability (hurt by falling 
utilization of capacity) by raising profit margins and thus prices. But 
this story seems remarkably quaint in the current competitive era. Monopoly 
pricing is relevant -- look what it's done to California energy -- but it's 
not a response to falling demand.)

It is the first time US labour productivity has sunk since economists began
asking five years ago whether the US economy had entered a new era of
perpetually fast growth, low inflation, fatter profits and rising living
standards due to the adoption of new technologies and better economic
policies.

Higher productivity was a distinguishing feature of US economic performance
in the 1990's. Other industrialised nations failed to match its twin
achievements of strong job creation and accelerating productivity growth
from 1995 to 2000, according to a recent survey of international trends by
the Conference Board, a New York-based research group.

It's a mistake, however, to assume that just because there's a cyclical 
decrease in labor productivity there's also an end to the alleged trend in 
productivity growth. In fact, the latter is very hard if not impossible to 
measure and it's unclear whether or not there was a new economy spurt in 
labor productivity growth or not (as Gordon and Ceccetti are cited as 
saying, later in the article).

...  the pickup in productivity growth over
the past few years helped suppress US inflation. If the nation's money
supply were rising much faster than its output of goods and services,
inflation might become a bigger problem for the Fed,

these days, the Fed doesn't care about the money supply. Old-style 
monetarism is dead, at least in the U.S., because the demand for money is 
so unstable.

It's amazing that the high dollar exchange rate isn't cited as a major 
reason for the suppression of inflation.

... the sharp, ongoing plunge in business spending on equipment and
software that is supposedly productivity-enhancing and renewed uncertainty
among investors about the course of US economic policymaking amid political
changes in Washington have cast doubt on that as well.

a fall in real investment doesn't affect productivity growth right away. It 
takes several years of sustained depression of investment to have this 
effect, and it may be counteracted by other things, such as the shake-out 
effect, in which the scrapping of the least productive operations raises 
the average. The long depression of investment during the 1930s doesn't 
seem to have ended the period of relatively fast growth of U.S. labor 
productivity which reached from 1919 or so until 1970 or so.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




Re: Re: Re: US productivity shows steepest fall since 1993

2001-06-05 Thread Jim Devine

At 08:48 AM 6/5/01 -0700, you wrote:
I'm always fascinated by the absence of naming slow sales as the
culprit for lagging productivity. If no one's biting on the product,
workers can't help but slow down on the jobs/sales that are still in
the pipeline. Sales teams get boom tired too.

I agree that slow sales are the culprit here, but I don't think it's the 
workers who are making the decision here.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




Re: Re: US productivity shows steepest fall since1993

2001-06-05 Thread Michael Perelman

That was a common observation during the Great Stagflation.  Also, the recessions
promote consolidations, which promote inflation in the long run.

Jim Devine wrote:


 (Wachtel and Adelsheim once argued that recessions promote inflation as
 monopoly corporations try to restore profitability (hurt by falling
 utilization of capacity) by raising profit margins and thus prices. But
 this story seems remarkably quaint in the current competitive era. Monopoly
 pricing is relevant -- look what it's done to California energy -- but it's
 not a response to falling demand.)

--

Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Floyd Norris: An Exaggerated Productivity Boom May Soon Be a Bust

2001-05-12 Thread Tom Walker

Or, productivity is cracked up to be something that it isn't. And therein
lies the one great enduring fallacy of bourgeois economics, which is
concerned above all to demonstrate the contribution to production of a
non-tangible essence, i.e. a contribution of capital that cannot be
attributed to previous accumulation of surplus value.

  [P]roductivity is not what it was cracked up to be. And therein lies one 
  of the great fallacies of the recent boom and bubble.

Tom Walker
Bowen Island, BC
604 947 2213




Re: Floyd Norris: An Exaggerated Productivity Boom May Soon Be a Bust

2001-05-12 Thread Jim Devine


   Floyd Norris: An Exaggerated Productivity Boom May Soon Be a Bust
 
   By FLOYD NORRIS
 
   [P]roductivity is not what it was cracked up to be. And therein lies 
 one of the great fallacies of the recent boom and bubble.
 
   Productivity — at least as measured by the government — zoomed in 
 recent years, rising at a faster rate than at any time since the 1960's. 
 That increase helped to persuade many economists that it was a new era, 
 one in which old economic verities might not apply.
 
   Rising productivity meant that the economy could grow rapidly without 
 fear of inflation while the information technology revolution, in the 
 year-old words of John T. Chambers, the chief executive of Cisco Systems, 
 enabled companies to reduce costs, generate revenue in new ways, empower 
 employees and citizens and provide the agility needed for the Internet 
 economy's rapid pace.
 
   Now productivity is falling, and Mr. Chambers is coping with a 
 collapse in demand that he did not see coming and still cannot quite 
 believe. This week he was still talking of Cisco returning to a 30 
 percent to 50 percent annual growth rate when the economy recovers.
 

Ellipsis

   Productivity booms are not permanent things.

I wish people wouldn't do this. We _don't know_ whether or not the 
productivity boom of the late 1990s was real or not. We may not know for 
decades. (The productivity boom of the 1920s turned out to be permanent and 
real, but we couldn't be sure until the 1950s or 1960s, when it became 
clear that labor productivity growth had a long-lasting acceleration in 
about 1919.)  We _do_ know that when the economy slows or recesses, 
realized labor productivity always falls. The latter is what Norris is 
referring to, but he can't generalize from that to statements about the 
trend of productivity growth. Nor can I.

There's a kind of Say's Law mystification of productivity growth. It's 
assumed that when productivity trends upward (or does so at a faster rate) 
that's automatically a good thing. Even ignoring external costs, etc., a 
rise in productivity may be a disaster if demand doesn't rise in step. All 
else constant, rising productivity means that demand _has to rise_ in order 
to keep unemployment from rising (one formulation of Okun's Law). But 
demand doesn't always rise, especially with the way that capitalists are 
always striving to push wages (and thus ultimately, consumer demand) down 
and the way in which capitalist investment can stop on a dime causing the 
economy to stall.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]  http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~JDevine Segui il
tuo corso, e lascia dir le genti. (Go your own way and let people talk.)
-- K. Marx, paraphrasing Dante A.




Land Productivity

2001-05-11 Thread Ricardo Duchesne


Wittgenstein once commented that the most important truths are 
usually right in front of you. The land productivity differential 
between Europe and China was basically a function of their 
environmental resource endowments. Explaining this will 
demonstrate it was China which enjoyed the greatest ecological 
windfall. P's entire thesis hinges on the claim that Europe would 
have followed a normal  Malthusian path were it not for the 
massive ecological relief it inherited through its *internal* coal 
supplies and its *external* colonial products. The industrial pattern 
of growth it enjoyed in the 19th century was an aberration. Lucky 
Europe, Normal China, says Perdue. But China was not one
bit normal. On a wide range of environmental factors, it was
exceptional, far luckier than Europe. 

The word around is that Pomeranz has changed dramatically the 
way we think about the origins of the modern world by refocusing 
the analysis away from technological innovations or cultural factors 
to geographical contingencies. Sifting through his book carefully 
rather than just advertising its contents demonstrates just how 
tendentious his geographical/ecological investigation really is. 
There is simply nothing on China's ecology. Europe and only 
Europe was the beneficiary of internal and external endowments.

First, internally, if China achieved the highest yields in the world, it 
was on the strength of its land-saving technologies and not any 
natural endowment. If  England achieved a  breakthrough in the use 
of coal, it was fundamentally a function of  geographic good luck. 
If China had less slack resources, it was because of  its efficient 
use. If Europe has more slack, it was because of inefficient use. If 
China kept soil fertility high despite intensive use of the land, it was 
due to better land management and effective use of fertilizers. If  
Europe still had large amounts of grasslands and pasture that 
were sufficiently well watered to be converted to arable, it was 
because it had a relative abundance of water as **a matter of 
original endowment** 

Did Europe really have an advantage in original endowments?

 




Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-11 Thread Michael Perelman

Ricardo, I know of nothing to say that China had an ecological advantage.
Almost all of its good land is on a narrow strip along the coast.  Most of
its land had to be manufactured into rice paddies.

The interior is mostly desert or mountain.


On Fri, May 11, 2001 at 11:10:12AM -0300, Ricardo Duchesne wrote:
 
 Wittgenstein once commented that the most important truths are 
 usually right in front of you. The land productivity differential 
 between Europe and China was basically a function of their 
 environmental resource endowments. Explaining this will 
 demonstrate it was China which enjoyed the greatest ecological 
 windfall. P's entire thesis hinges on the claim that Europe would 
 have followed a normal  Malthusian path were it not for the 
 massive ecological relief it inherited through its *internal* coal 
 supplies and its *external* colonial products. The industrial pattern 
 of growth it enjoyed in the 19th century was an aberration. Lucky 
 Europe, Normal China, says Perdue. But China was not one
 bit normal. On a wide range of environmental factors, it was
 exceptional, far luckier than Europe. 
 
 The word around is that Pomeranz has changed dramatically the 
 way we think about the origins of the modern world by refocusing 
 the analysis away from technological innovations or cultural factors 
 to geographical contingencies. Sifting through his book carefully 
 rather than just advertising its contents demonstrates just how 
 tendentious his geographical/ecological investigation really is. 
 There is simply nothing on China's ecology. Europe and only 
 Europe was the beneficiary of internal and external endowments.
 
 First, internally, if China achieved the highest yields in the world, it 
 was on the strength of its land-saving technologies and not any 
 natural endowment. If  England achieved a  breakthrough in the use 
 of coal, it was fundamentally a function of  geographic good luck. 
 If China had less slack resources, it was because of  its efficient 
 use. If Europe has more slack, it was because of inefficient use. If 
 China kept soil fertility high despite intensive use of the land, it was 
 due to better land management and effective use of fertilizers. If  
 Europe still had large amounts of grasslands and pasture that 
 were sufficiently well watered to be converted to arable, it was 
 because it had a relative abundance of water as **a matter of 
 original endowment** 
 
 Did Europe really have an advantage in original endowments?
 
  
 

-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-11 Thread Ricardo Duchesne

Michael Perelman:
Ricardo, I know of nothing to say that China had an ecological
advantage. Almost all of its good land is on a narrow strip along the
coast.  Most of its land had to be manufactured into rice paddies.

The interior is mostly desert or mountain.

-

You're right and that's why it is so fascinating to find out how the 
remaining good land (only 10 to 11 per cent of the land is arable, 
as compared to 25% in the  US) was able to feed so many people 
per square mile. 




Floyd Norris: An Exaggerated Productivity Boom May Soon Be a Bust

2001-05-11 Thread Stephen E Philion


  NYT

  May 11, 2001

  Floyd Norris: An Exaggerated Productivity Boom May Soon Be a Bust

  By FLOYD NORRIS

  [P]roductivity is not what it was cracked up to be. And therein lies one of the 
great fallacies of the recent boom and bubble.

  Productivity — at least as measured by the government — zoomed in recent years, 
rising at a faster rate than at any time since the 1960's. That increase helped to 
persuade many economists that it was a new era, one in which old economic verities 
might not apply.

  Rising productivity meant that the economy could grow rapidly without fear of 
inflation while the information technology revolution, in the year-old words of John 
T. Chambers, the chief executive of Cisco Systems, enabled companies to reduce 
costs, generate revenue in new ways, empower employees and citizens and provide the 
agility needed for the Internet economy's rapid pace.

  Now productivity is falling, and Mr. Chambers is coping with a collapse in demand 
that he did not see coming and still cannot quite believe. This week he was still 
talking of Cisco returning to a 30 percent to 50 percent annual growth rate when the 
economy recovers.

  The reality of the productivity explosion was that it was concentrated in the 
information technology industry. Some of that rise was not real anyway, since the 
government's statistical adjustments probably exaggerated the improvements in 
computers. But the failure of the productivity measures to show big gains in other 
areas should have been telling. If it was a real productivity miracle, how come we 
didn't see it in other places? asked Greg Jensen, an analyst at Bridgewater 
Associates.

  Nonetheless, it was believed to be real by the people that counted. It was that 
belief, says Robert Barbera, the chief economist of Hoenig  Company, that led the 
Federal Reserve to back away from a pre-emptive tightening framework, in which rates 
were raised when the economy began to grow too fast.

  There is no way to know just how much a tighter Fed would have been able to slow 
the expansion of the bubble, but it would have had some effect. Less money would have 
been wasted on unproductive investments, of which Cisco's $2.2 billion inventory 
write-down is but a small part. Think of the money invested in absurd dot-coms, as 
well as fiber optic lines that are installed but may never be used.

  Now we see a contraction of the ability of good companies to get money, because of 
all the money the bad companies sucked in, Mr. Jensen said.

  Instead, we must deal with the effects of a bust in capital investment, one that is 
likely to continue for some time. We will learn that productivity was probably really 
growing at a slower rate than we thought, and will continue to do so. That implies 
slower economic growth and lower multiples for earnings in the stock market.

  There are historical precedents. In the 1920's and again in the 1950's and 1960's, 
productivity surged along with the stock market. Productivity growth does not 
necessarily presage heaven on earth, James Grant, the editor of Grant's Interest 
Rate Observer, said.

  The last productivity boom came to an abrupt halt with the horrors of the 1970's, 
when high oil prices helped to choke off economic growth and slow investment. In the 
five years that ended with 1972, productivity rose 2.9 percent, very close to the 
level of the last five years. But by 1980, the five-year average was below 1 percent 
and the Dow Jones industrial average was below where it had been in 1966.

  Productivity booms are not permanent things.







(Fwd) land productivity

2001-05-10 Thread Ricardo Duchesne

 
 I would like to see the post you are responding to? And Deirdre is
 not by any chance Deirdre McCloskey is she? If so she is very
 brilliant but quite vicious.
 
Deleted it. You probably could find it in the EH archives (March 
2001). It is McCloskey.  She never responded to this post. It came 
out of  a short exchange with Greg Clark who was really having an 
exchange with Michael Perelman. As a woman she's not as 
vicious. Everyone is Dears now. From what Pugliese sent, 
Deirdre now notices that academic men are a lot more hierarchical, 
obsessed about their accomplishments. She's happier. It is tough 
being a man in this world.  




Land Productivity

2001-05-10 Thread Ricardo Duchesne

While P questions the western model of developmet, he still seeks 
to convince us that the Chinese model achieved the highest 
agricultural yields in the world due to their efficient land-saving 
practices. That they were as efficient, as rational, as developed, as 
powerful as the westerners. This is called polycentrism in world 
history. Never mind the poly, if you can show that either China, 
Japan, or India were as advanced as Europe, then you're ready to 
join the multicultural crowd and sing We are the World. What 
about the Africans? Well..Nubia, yes, that's right, it has a nice 
ring to it. But that's way back, isn't that Black Athena? That too 
should be included, and later there's the Songhay empire of West 
Africa, the largest state of modern Africa, including the Oyo Empire 
in Nigeria, Nupe, Igala, and Benin in the lower Niger valley, or the 
Hausa states of Northern Nigeria, and Kongo in central Africa. 
Other ethnic groups? Oh yes, there others like the Jahaanke of the 
Gambia-River Niger region; the Juula of northern Ghana, Cote 
d'Ivoire, and Upper Niger River; the Wolof of Senegal; and the Awka 
and Aro of Iboland in Nigeria - they were also powerful and wealthy; 
they were the ethnic groups that facilitated and controlled the slave 
trade. We are all equal.

A challenge to the western model this is not.




Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-10 Thread Louis Proyect

Ricardo:
history. Never mind the poly, if you can show that either China, 
Japan, or India were as advanced as Europe, then you're ready to 
join the multicultural crowd and sing We are the World. What 
about the Africans? Well..Nubia, yes, that's right, it has a nice 
ring to it. But that's way back, isn't that Black Athena? That too 
should be included, and later there's the Songhay empire of West 
Africa, the largest state of modern Africa, including the Oyo Empire 
in Nigeria, Nupe, Igala, and Benin in the lower Niger valley, or the 
Hausa states of Northern Nigeria, and Kongo in central Africa. 
Other ethnic groups? Oh yes, there others like the Jahaanke of the 
Gambia-River Niger region; the Juula of northern Ghana, Cote 
d'Ivoire, and Upper Niger River; the Wolof of Senegal; and the Awka 
and Aro of Iboland in Nigeria - they were also powerful and wealthy; 
they were the ethnic groups that facilitated and controlled the slave 
trade. We are all equal.

Is this diatribe going into your article? Is this meant for Science and
Society? If so, expect angry letters from black readers. Actually, no
problem since I doubt any African-American reads the journal--let alone
writes for it--even though there are articles commenting on them from time
to time.



Louis Proyect
Marxism mailing list: http://www.marxmail.org




Land Productivity

2001-05-10 Thread Ricardo Duchesne

Louis:
 Is this diatribe going into your article? Is this meant for Science
 and Society? If so, expect angry letters from black readers. Actually,
 no problem since I doubt any African-American reads the journal--let
 alone writes for it--even though there are articles commenting on them
 from time to time.

I have an agreement to send it to another journal. I have to choose 
journals that allow discussion of big questions which most don't. 
Unfortunately Universities/Journals  are still dominated by 
specialists. A lasting merit of  classical thinkers is they encourage 
real literacy and education. John Kenneth Galbraith said he can't 
understand why academic specialists are taken so seriously or 
held up as examplars of knowledge.




Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-10 Thread Michael Perelman

I think the Lou's question had to do with the way you presented your
thought.  Bringing up the Black Athena is an emotional subject.  I'm far
from an expert in the field -- not even a novice, but I suspect that most
professional journals would be reluctant to give a fair hearing to the
Afrocentric perspective.  I also suspect that some Afrocentric writers
overstate their position, offering easy targets to those who oppose
Afrocentrism.

We had been discussing how easy it is to make gross errors regarding other
societies in something as simple as an evaluation of how development
either improves or harms the life of the poor.  The further away you look
either in time or in culture, the more difficult such evaluations are.



On Thu, May 10, 2001 at 12:34:14PM -0300, Ricardo Duchesne wrote:
 Louis:
  Is this diatribe going into your article? Is this meant for Science
  and Society? If so, expect angry letters from black readers. Actually,
  no problem since I doubt any African-American reads the journal--let
  alone writes for it--even though there are articles commenting on them
  from time to time.
 
 I have an agreement to send it to another journal. I have to choose 
 journals that allow discussion of big questions which most don't. 
 Unfortunately Universities/Journals  are still dominated by 
 specialists. A lasting merit of  classical thinkers is they encourage 
 real literacy and education. John Kenneth Galbraith said he can't 
 understand why academic specialists are taken so seriously or 
 held up as examplars of knowledge.
 

-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-10 Thread Michael Pugliese

http://www.cup.org/
Mao's War Against Nature
Politics and the Environment in Revolutionary China

Shapiro, Judith

In clear and compelling prose, Judith Shapiro relates the great, untold
story of the devastating impact of Chinese politics on China's environment
during the Mao years. Maoist China provides an example of extreme human
interference in the natural world in an era in which human relationships
were also unusually distorted.

Under Mao, the traditional Chinese ideal of harmony between heaven and
humans was abrogated in favor of Mao's insistence that Man Must Conquer
Nature. Mao and the Chinese Communist Party's war to bend the physical
world to human will often had disastrous consequences both for human beings
and the natural environment. Mao's War Against Nature argues that the abuse
of people and the abuse of nature are often linked. Shapiro's account, told
in part through the voices of average Chinese citizens and officials who
lived through and participated in some of the destructive campaigns, is both
eye-opening and heartbreaking.

Judith Shapiro teaches environmental politics at American University in
Washington, DC. She is co-author, with Liang Heng, of several well known
books on China, including Son of the Revolution (Random House, 1984) and
After the Nightmare (Knopf, 1986). She was one of the first Americans to
work in China after the normalization of U.S.-China relations in 1979.

SERIES NAME:
Studies in Environment and History


- Original Message -
From: Ricardo Duchesne [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: Thursday, May 10, 2001 7:58 AM
Subject: [PEN-L:11338] Land Productivity


 While P questions the western model of developmet, he still seeks
 to convince us that the Chinese model achieved the highest
 agricultural yields in the world due to their efficient land-saving
 practices. That they were as efficient, as rational, as developed, as
 powerful as the westerners. This is called polycentrism in world
 history. Never mind the poly, if you can show that either China,
 Japan, or India were as advanced as Europe, then you're ready to
 join the multicultural crowd and sing We are the World. What
 about the Africans? Well..Nubia, yes, that's right, it has a nice
 ring to it. But that's way back, isn't that Black Athena? That too
 should be included, and later there's the Songhay empire of West
 Africa, the largest state of modern Africa, including the Oyo Empire
 in Nigeria, Nupe, Igala, and Benin in the lower Niger valley, or the
 Hausa states of Northern Nigeria, and Kongo in central Africa.
 Other ethnic groups? Oh yes, there others like the Jahaanke of the
 Gambia-River Niger region; the Juula of northern Ghana, Cote
 d'Ivoire, and Upper Niger River; the Wolof of Senegal; and the Awka
 and Aro of Iboland in Nigeria - they were also powerful and wealthy;
 they were the ethnic groups that facilitated and controlled the slave
 trade. We are all equal.

 A challenge to the western model this is not.





Re: Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-10 Thread Louis Proyect

http://www.cup.org/
Mao's War Against Nature
Politics and the Environment in Revolutionary China

 While P questions the western model of developmet, he still seeks
 to convince us that the Chinese model achieved the highest
 agricultural yields in the world due to their efficient land-saving
 practices. 

The Chinese model that Ricardo has been discussing for the past several
weeks has been that of the 17th and 18th century. I do not believe that Mao
was in power back then.

Louis Proyect
Marxism mailing list: http://www.marxmail.org




Re: Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-10 Thread Michael Perelman

Michael, I don't know what your point is.  I hope that you are not
starting a good Mao/bad Mao debate.

I recall that when mainstream Western agricultural types first visited
China after the Nixon visit, they were astounded by the way the Chinese
were able to feed so many people on such poor land.

On the other hand, China, like the U.S., displayed little awareness of
some environmental problems.  They used too many pesticides and dammed too
many rivers.  They also cut down too much wood.


On Thu, May 10, 2001 at 10:33:34AM -0700, Michael Pugliese wrote:
 http://www.cup.org/
 Mao's War Against Nature
 Politics and the Environment in Revolutionary China
 
 Shapiro, Judith
 
 In clear and compelling prose, Judith Shapiro relates the great, untold
 story of the devastating impact of Chinese politics on China's environment
 during the Mao years. Maoist China provides an example of extreme human
 interference in the natural world in an era in which human relationships
 were also unusually distorted.
 
 Under Mao, the traditional Chinese ideal of harmony between heaven and
 humans was abrogated in favor of Mao's insistence that Man Must Conquer
 Nature. Mao and the Chinese Communist Party's war to bend the physical
 world to human will often had disastrous consequences both for human beings
 and the natural environment. Mao's War Against Nature argues that the abuse
 of people and the abuse of nature are often linked. Shapiro's account, told
 in part through the voices of average Chinese citizens and officials who
 lived through and participated in some of the destructive campaigns, is both
 eye-opening and heartbreaking.
 
 Judith Shapiro teaches environmental politics at American University in
 Washington, DC. She is co-author, with Liang Heng, of several well known
 books on China, including Son of the Revolution (Random House, 1984) and
 After the Nightmare (Knopf, 1986). She was one of the first Americans to
 work in China after the normalization of U.S.-China relations in 1979.
 
 SERIES NAME:
 Studies in Environment and History
 
 
 - Original Message -
 From: Ricardo Duchesne [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Sent: Thursday, May 10, 2001 7:58 AM
 Subject: [PEN-L:11338] Land Productivity
 
 
  While P questions the western model of developmet, he still seeks
  to convince us that the Chinese model achieved the highest
  agricultural yields in the world due to their efficient land-saving
  practices. That they were as efficient, as rational, as developed, as
  powerful as the westerners. This is called polycentrism in world
  history. Never mind the poly, if you can show that either China,
  Japan, or India were as advanced as Europe, then you're ready to
  join the multicultural crowd and sing We are the World. What
  about the Africans? Well..Nubia, yes, that's right, it has a nice
  ring to it. But that's way back, isn't that Black Athena? That too
  should be included, and later there's the Songhay empire of West
  Africa, the largest state of modern Africa, including the Oyo Empire
  in Nigeria, Nupe, Igala, and Benin in the lower Niger valley, or the
  Hausa states of Northern Nigeria, and Kongo in central Africa.
  Other ethnic groups? Oh yes, there others like the Jahaanke of the
  Gambia-River Niger region; the Juula of northern Ghana, Cote
  d'Ivoire, and Upper Niger River; the Wolof of Senegal; and the Awka
  and Aro of Iboland in Nigeria - they were also powerful and wealthy;
  they were the ethnic groups that facilitated and controlled the slave
  trade. We are all equal.
 
  A challenge to the western model this is not.
 
 

-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-10 Thread Michael Pugliese

I had not been following this lengthy thread on Pomeranz.
Michael Pugliese, Better Mao Than Never...

- Original Message -
From: Michael Perelman [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: Thursday, May 10, 2001 11:40 AM
Subject: [PEN-L:11356] Re: Re: Land Productivity


 Michael, I don't know what your point is.  I hope that you are not
 starting a good Mao/bad Mao debate.

 I recall that when mainstream Western agricultural types first visited
 China after the Nixon visit, they were astounded by the way the Chinese
 were able to feed so many people on such poor land.

 On the other hand, China, like the U.S., displayed little awareness of
 some environmental problems.  They used too many pesticides and dammed too
 many rivers.  They also cut down too much wood.


 On Thu, May 10, 2001 at 10:33:34AM -0700, Michael Pugliese wrote:
  http://www.cup.org/
  Mao's War Against Nature
  Politics and the Environment in Revolutionary China
 
  Shapiro, Judith
 
  In clear and compelling prose, Judith Shapiro relates the great, untold
  story of the devastating impact of Chinese politics on China's
environment
  during the Mao years. Maoist China provides an example of extreme human
  interference in the natural world in an era in which human relationships
  were also unusually distorted.
 
  Under Mao, the traditional Chinese ideal of harmony between heaven and
  humans was abrogated in favor of Mao's insistence that Man Must
Conquer
  Nature. Mao and the Chinese Communist Party's war to bend the
physical
  world to human will often had disastrous consequences both for human
beings
  and the natural environment. Mao's War Against Nature argues that the
abuse
  of people and the abuse of nature are often linked. Shapiro's account,
told
  in part through the voices of average Chinese citizens and officials who
  lived through and participated in some of the destructive campaigns, is
both
  eye-opening and heartbreaking.
 
  Judith Shapiro teaches environmental politics at American University in
  Washington, DC. She is co-author, with Liang Heng, of several well known
  books on China, including Son of the Revolution (Random House, 1984) and
  After the Nightmare (Knopf, 1986). She was one of the first Americans to
  work in China after the normalization of U.S.-China relations in 1979.
 
  SERIES NAME:
  Studies in Environment and History
 
 
  - Original Message -
  From: Ricardo Duchesne [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  Sent: Thursday, May 10, 2001 7:58 AM
  Subject: [PEN-L:11338] Land Productivity
 
 
   While P questions the western model of developmet, he still seeks
   to convince us that the Chinese model achieved the highest
   agricultural yields in the world due to their efficient land-saving
   practices. That they were as efficient, as rational, as developed, as
   powerful as the westerners. This is called polycentrism in world
   history. Never mind the poly, if you can show that either China,
   Japan, or India were as advanced as Europe, then you're ready to
   join the multicultural crowd and sing We are the World. What
   about the Africans? Well..Nubia, yes, that's right, it has a nice
   ring to it. But that's way back, isn't that Black Athena? That too
   should be included, and later there's the Songhay empire of West
   Africa, the largest state of modern Africa, including the Oyo Empire
   in Nigeria, Nupe, Igala, and Benin in the lower Niger valley, or the
   Hausa states of Northern Nigeria, and Kongo in central Africa.
   Other ethnic groups? Oh yes, there others like the Jahaanke of the
   Gambia-River Niger region; the Juula of northern Ghana, Cote
   d'Ivoire, and Upper Niger River; the Wolof of Senegal; and the Awka
   and Aro of Iboland in Nigeria - they were also powerful and wealthy;
   they were the ethnic groups that facilitated and controlled the slave
   trade. We are all equal.
  
   A challenge to the western model this is not.
  
 

 --
 Michael Perelman
 Economics Department
 California State University
 Chico, CA 95929

 Tel. 530-898-5321
 E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]





Land Productivity

2001-05-09 Thread Ricardo Duchesne

If P asks us to drop our Western biases and look at Chinese 
economic performance in terms of its specificities most 
fundamentally at its superior agrarian sector and its land-saving 
innovations, he says next to nothing about Chinese agricultural 
productivity. We are definitely told indirectly it was highly 
successful in the way  it was able to sustain relatively high living 
standards right through the 1800s. Even as China apporached the 
soon-to-come Malthusian limitations of the 19th century, its 
population doubled between 1750 and 1850 without any 
generalized fall in per capita income (p125). Why? Because 
despite the worsening person/land ratios so visible in regions like 
the Lower Yangzi, the Chinese were able to attain large gains in 
per-acre yields through such land-saving innovations as greater use 
of fertilizers, more multicropping and extremely careful weeding 
(p141). But P will hardly go further than this. He no doubt offers 
substantial numbers showing how much they consumed and 
produced crops like sugar, tabacco, tea and  rice. But there is 
really no analysis of the agrarian system as such or the land 
saving technologies. There is an Appendix (B) comparing 
'estimates of manure applied to North China and Europeans farms 
in the late 18th century, and of resulting nitrogen fluxes'. However, I 
would say that the Appendix, like the rest of the book, equivocates 
on the most crucial questions determining land productivity.   

  




Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-09 Thread Louis Proyect

Philip T. Hoffman. Growth in a Traditional Society: The French Countryside,
1450-1820. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996. xvi + 361 pp.
Appendices, notes, sources, bibliography, index. $39.50 (cloth), ISBN
0-691-02983-0. 

Reviewed by Jonathan J. Liebowitz, Department of History, University of
Massachusetts Lowell.

Published by H-France (May, 1997) 

In a recent on-line review of an economic history text edited by T. G.
Rawski, historian Michael Dintenfass of the University of Wisconsin remarks
that the book invites historians to discuss matters that no longer
interest them deeply. [1] In his volume on pre-Revolutionary French
agriculture, Philip Hoffman also seeks to write an economic history which
will make concepts and findings influenced by the cliometric revolution
accessible to historians.[2] I fear that despite his meticulous and
imaginative research, Hoffman will meet the same fate as the authors of
Rawski's volume and find that he is talking past his audience. Yet
historians of early modern and revolutionary France, even those of a
postmodern bent, will have to take into consideration his conclusions about
the agricultural economy if they want to understand the behavior of most
French men and women of the pre-industrial era. 

Hoffman's goal is to teach historians of early modern France that
cliometrics has something to offer them and that they can understand its
lessons even if not conversant with economic theory and econometric
methods. Specifically he wants to revise the consensus view that the
French agricultural economy was stagnant for more than 350 years before the
Revolution because small farms were inefficient and the village community
was hostile to innovation. After outlining this position in the first
chapter, the rest of the book argues that the consensus is wrong on all
particulars: early modern agriculture was not stagnant, at least not in all
times and places; small farms were no less efficient than large ones;
members of the village community were not bound by unyielding tradition but
sought their individual interests, which sometimes might be served by
traditional arrangements, sometimes by innovation. 

Chapter Two (Common Rights and the Village Community) begins with a
dispute, revealed in legal documents, from a village near Nantes on the
Loire in which the local farmers seem to be defending their traditional
rights to pasture on the common against a local lord who wants to enclose
it. But Hoffman springs a surprise on us: the poor farmers insisting on
their common rights were pasturing, not their family cows, but sheep, which
they leased from merchants in return for a share of the profits. In this
way the poor used traditional rights to break into nascent rural
capitalism (p. 23). The story is complicated, but by no means is it one in
which the poor cooperated to uphold tradition in face of a modernizing
capitalist elite. Instead, strife was more common among the villagers than
cooperation, and they were equally likely as the rich to be involved in the
market. 

In Chapter Three (Labor Markets, Rental Markets, and Credit in the Local
Economy), Hoffman disputes the claim that markets were risky, maintaining
that they reduced rather than increased the variation of peasants' income.
Most peasants were involved in one market or another, whether labor,
rental, or credit. Here he finds another assumption to disprove: that
higher rent on smaller parcels of land resulted from either the power of
large tenants or the land hunger of the poor. Rather he finds that the
difference resulted from the landlords' collection of a risk premium from
the poorer tenants of smaller parcels because they would be more likely to
default on their payments. 

With Chapters Four (Agricultural Productivity in France, 1450-1789) and
Five (Explaining Productivity in a Traditional Economy) Hoffman comes to
the center of his concerns. What was the output of farms and how did it
change? What were the reasons for the changes which occurred? At first
glance, it would seem that answering these questions would have to begin
with measurements of the total output of French agriculture at several
points in time. But that is probably impossible since no one was collecting
national data until the eighteenth century, and, even if contemporaries had
collected such data, the researcher would face problems such as changes in
national borders. So Hoffman adopts another strategy: comparison of Total
Factor Productivity (TFP) at different times and places. TFP measures how
efficiently producers turn their inputs--in agriculture typically land,
labor, and capital--into output--wheat, wool, and so on. When TFP rises it
means that the same inputs yield a greater output. The advantage of using
this measure is that TFPs can be compared even if areas are very different
because what is being measured is the output per unit of input.
Nevertheless, direct measurement of the factors runs into almost as many
problems

Re: Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-09 Thread Jim Devine

At 02:23 PM 5/9/01 -0400, you wrote:
Philip T. Hoffman. Growth in a Traditional Society: The French Countryside,
1450-1820. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996. xvi + 361 pp.
Appendices, notes, sources, bibliography, index. $39.50 (cloth), ISBN
0-691-02983-0.

... Chapter Two (Common Rights and the Village Community) begins with a
dispute, revealed in legal documents, from a village near Nantes on the
Loire in which the local farmers seem to be defending their traditional
rights to pasture on the common against a local lord who wants to enclose
it. But Hoffman springs a surprise on us: the poor farmers insisting on
their common rights were pasturing, not their family cows, but sheep, which
they leased from merchants in return for a share of the profits. In this
way the poor used traditional rights to break into nascent rural
capitalism (p. 23). The story is complicated, but by no means is it one in
which the poor cooperated to uphold tradition in face of a modernizing
capitalist elite. Instead, strife was more common among the villagers than
cooperation, and they were equally likely as the rich to be involved in the
market.

Hoffman seems to be using a definition of capitalism that includes 
simple commodity production (market-oriented production without 
proletarianization) under its umbrella. I would guess that the strife 
within the community resulted from the fact that some peasants wanted to be 
(true) capitalists, with others as proletarians.

... With Chapters Four (Agricultural Productivity in France, 1450-1789) and
Five (Explaining Productivity in a Traditional Economy) Hoffman comes to
the center of his concerns. What was the output of farms and how did it
change? What were the reasons for the changes which occurred? At first
glance, it would seem that answering these questions would have to begin
with measurements of the total output of French agriculture at several
points in time. But that is probably impossible since no one was collecting
national data until the eighteenth century, and, even if contemporaries had
collected such data, the researcher would face problems such as changes in
national borders. So Hoffman adopts another strategy: comparison of Total
Factor Productivity (TFP) at different times and places. TFP measures how
efficiently producers turn their inputs--in agriculture typically land,
labor, and capital--into output--wheat, wool, and so on. When TFP rises it
means that the same inputs yield a greater output. The advantage of using
this measure is that TFPs can be compared even if areas are very different
because what is being measured is the output per unit of input.

I don't understand why people (including my friend Bob Brenner) like TFP. 
It's bogus. The calculation adds up apples  oranges (labor, capital goods, 
land, etc.) to create the denominator. In order to do this addition, it 
assumes that each input's payment on the market = its contribution to the 
total production process. This is totally wrong, due to the existence of 
monopoly, monopsony, and externalities. Marx, for example, wouldn't equate 
the return on capital (profits, interest, rent) to capital's contribution 
to total production. The new growth theory of neoclassical economics also 
rejects this assumption.

Nevertheless, direct measurement of the factors runs into almost as many
problems as does measurement of total output, so Hoffman adopts a technique
used by Robert Allen (The Efficiency and Distributional Consequences,
Economic Journal, vol. 92, 1982) to circumvent these problems. Instead of
trying to measure how much wheat was produced or how many hours of labor
were needed in its production, he measures prices, wages, and especially
rents. Given certain assumptions about the agricultural economy, mostly
that it participated in a competitive market, Hoffman can derive its TFP. I
would accept Hoffman's assumptions, which recent studies of Italian,
English, French and United States farming tend to reinforce.

a competitive economy?! is there any validity to that assumption?

... What caused stagnation in some times and places and growth in others?
Peasant mentalities and communities were not responsible for stagnation.
Nor were obstacles to combining small farms into larger ones (e.g., by
enclosure), since small size was not in itself a cause of inefficiency and
small plots could be combined to produce larger ones if farmers wanted.
Recurrent wars and taxes, which caused uncertainty, were more to blame. So
conversely, peace encouraged growth, as did demand from large cities and
reduction of transport costs. Only Paris was really large enough to have a
stimulating effect, and productivity in the Parisian Basin rose steadily at
levels comparable with those of England.

Louis, this book seems to be written from a _laissez-faire_ perspective. Is 
that one you trust?

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




Re: Land Productivity

2001-05-09 Thread Michael Perelman

The Chinese developed a magnificent system of working the land with high
sustained yields.  There were problems.  High levels of intenstinal worms
and parasites because of the unsanitary ways of handling wastes.  Even so,
multi-cropping achieved yields the west could never achieve, except in
specialty agriculture, such as the Paris market gardens.

England, like the U.S. in modern times, excelled in cutting costs rather
than increasing yields.  In fact, US yields are still relatively low.

The key to England's success was in increasing net yeilds, what was left
over after the farm workers took their share.  In France, the Physiocrats
pushed the idea that net, rather than gross yields were the goal.

Ricardo Duchesne wrote:

 If P asks us to drop our Western biases and look at Chinese
 economic performance in terms of its specificities most
 fundamentally at its superior agrarian sector and its land-saving
 innovations, he says next to nothing about Chinese agricultural
 productivity. We are definitely told indirectly it was highly
 successful in the way  it was able to sustain relatively high living
 standards right through the 1800s. Even as China apporached the
 soon-to-come Malthusian limitations of the 19th century, its
 population doubled between 1750 and 1850 without any
 generalized fall in per capita income (p125). Why? Because
 despite the worsening person/land ratios so visible in regions like
 the Lower Yangzi, the Chinese were able to attain large gains in
 per-acre yields through such land-saving innovations as greater use
 of fertilizers, more multicropping and extremely careful weeding
 (p141). But P will hardly go further than this. He no doubt offers
 substantial numbers showing how much they consumed and
 produced crops like sugar, tabacco, tea and  rice. But there is
 really no analysis of the agrarian system as such or the land
 saving technologies. There is an Appendix (B) comparing
 'estimates of manure applied to North China and Europeans farms
 in the late 18th century, and of resulting nitrogen fluxes'. However, I
 would say that the Appendix, like the rest of the book, equivocates
 on the most crucial questions determining land productivity.



--

Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




(Fwd) land productivity

2001-05-09 Thread Ricardo Duchesne

The following forwarded message is from a short exchange I had in 
EH.R last March which briefly shows that I don't view productivity 
increases, including per capita income increases, as progress. 
Having said this, I still think we should acknowldge that productivity 
increases through labor-saving innovations bring power. The Soviets 
knew this as they went on to exterminate small-scale peasant 
agriculture during the collectivization program of the 1930s. Millions 
died, lost their land, became destitute; and, in fact, total 
agricultural production declined, yet the Soviets obtained their 
*surplus* which they used to finance the First Five Year Plan which 
eventually transformed the Soviet Union into a world power. 

--- Forwarded message follows ---
From:   Ricardo Duchesne [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject:EH.R: Clark on Perelman, _The Invention of Capitalism:..._
Date sent:  Mon, 19 Mar 2001 17:06:25 EST
Send reply to:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

- EH.RES POSTING - Commenting on 
Deirdre:   

That a cheery  (though I would prefer promising) view of peasant
life has characterized various Marxist interpretations is true enough 
 (not enough, of course, to warrant Greg's misreading of  Chapter
27). But we need a proper context. It appears cheery only  if we   
restrict ourselves to changes in  productivity and per capita
income a la Maddison. But perhaps less so if we care as well
about  economic concentration and self-control. We have enough
evidence suggesting that small scale farmers in England were
under serious threat particularly after 1600: First, an additional 24% 
of  the land was enclosed during the 17th century; second, in the   
early 17th  century small farmers occupied 1/3 of the cultivated   
area, yet by 1800  they occupied only 8%. Moreover, whereas   
farms of 100 acres and  more had constituted only 14% in the   
1600s, by the 1800s they  represented 52% (O'Brien, 1996).  

Given these facts, is it cheery to argue that small scale peasants 
were better  off  in 1600 than in 1800, even if agricultural   
productivity increased? Is it not silly to insist, or view this whole
process of concentration as one in which small farmers were too   
poor to be worth ripping off ?   

Finally, why don't we find the respective sources from below 
so we can hear the voices of the peasants themselves instead of 
just relying on abstract productivity numbers generated by we   
comfortable academics?

--- End of forwarded message ---




Re: (Fwd) land productivity

2001-05-09 Thread Carrol Cox



Ricardo Duchesne wrote:
 
 [clip]
 --- Forwarded message follows ---
 From:   Ricardo Duchesne [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject:EH.R: Clark on Perelman, _The Invention of Capitalism:..._
 Date sent:  Mon, 19 Mar 2001 17:06:25 EST
 Send reply to:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
 - EH.RES POSTING - Commenting on
 Deirdre:
 
 That a cheery  (though I would prefer promising) view of peasant
 life has characterized various Marxist interpretations is true enough
  (not enough, of course, to warrant Greg's misreading of  Chapter
 27).

I would like to see the post you are responding to? And Deirdre is not
by any chance Deirdre McCloskey is she? If so she is very brilliant
but quite vicious.

Carrol




Re: Re: (Fwd) land productivity

2001-05-09 Thread Michael Pugliese

http://www.linguafranca.com/br/9911/shalit.html
- Original Message -
From: Carrol Cox [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: Wednesday, May 09, 2001 4:37 PM
Subject: [PEN-L:11329] Re: (Fwd) land productivity




 Ricardo Duchesne wrote:
 
  [clip]
  --- Forwarded message follows ---
  From:   Ricardo Duchesne [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  Subject:EH.R: Clark on Perelman, _The Invention of
Capitalism:..._
  Date sent:  Mon, 19 Mar 2001 17:06:25 EST
  Send reply to:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
  - EH.RES POSTING - Commenting on
  Deirdre:
 
  That a cheery  (though I would prefer promising) view of peasant
  life has characterized various Marxist interpretations is true enough
   (not enough, of course, to warrant Greg's misreading of  Chapter
  27).

 I would like to see the post you are responding to? And Deirdre is not
 by any chance Deirdre McCloskey is she? If so she is very brilliant
 but quite vicious.

 Carrol





US productivity falls

2001-05-08 Thread Andrew Hagen

Instead of the expected increase at a 1 percent annual rate, US
productivity declined in the first quarter of this year. The
preliminarly BLS results, seasonally adjusted, annual rates, were

 -0.4 percent in the business sector and
 -0.1 percent in the nonfarm business sector.

This might be explained by the 5.2 percent annual rate increase in unit
labor costs over the same time period. Could it reflect a surge in
one-time downsizing charges taken by employers? If not, it may be a
sign that a purely monetarist response may be unable to to get the US
economy moving again. Since the economic crisis has entered the
perception of the public earlier this year, the FOMC has reduced both
the discount rate and the feds fund rate by 2 percent. Nevertheless,
Fed watchers are anticipating another rate cut at the Committee's May
15 meeting.

It could be that the current crop of investors have become so risk
adverse that they will not invest substantially even with reduced
interest rates. To speak anecdotally, I'm not personally aware of any
great new business plans or market opportunities. Particularly in the
tech sector, there is no new killer app or new device that people
simply must have. As a result, they continue to use the hardware and
software they already have. This could change. It may be, however, that
a Keyenesian government spending program could be required to spark the
economy again. A Keyensian tax cut will probably not work if investors
are so risk averse that they will not invest the money given to them by
the government. They'll just pocket it. In short, the wheels are stuck
in the mud, and no one is getting out to p


http://stats.bls.gov/news.release/prod2.nr0.htm

http://dailynews.yahoo.com/h/nm/20010508/bs/economy_productivity_dc_2.ht
ml

Andrew Hagen
[EMAIL PROTECTED]






Re: US productivity falls

2001-05-08 Thread Jim Devine

At 11:33 AM 5/8/01 -0400, you wrote:
Instead of the expected increase at a 1 percent annual rate, US
productivity declined in the first quarter of this year. The
preliminarly BLS results, seasonally adjusted, annual rates, were

  -0.4 percent in the business sector and
  -0.1 percent in the nonfarm business sector.

This might be explained by the 5.2 percent annual rate increase in unit
labor costs over the same time period.

no it can't be explained that way, since unit labor costs (ULC) reflect 
labor productivity rather than vice-versa:

ULC = (total employment costs)/(output) = (employment costs per 
worker)/(output per worker), where output per worker = labor productivity.

Could it reflect a surge in
one-time downsizing charges taken by employers?

More likely, it's because output fell drastically (or output growth slowed 
down drastically) but instead of laying off workers in proportion to 
output, employers held onto overhead workers in management (line and staff 
employees). The overhead workers are supposed to contribute to output in 
the long run, but in the short run holding onto them means falling output 
per worker. This is a normal cyclical phenomenon (though the triumphalism 
of as little as a year ago would have denied the possibility of a normal 
cyclical phenomenon).

If not, it may be a sign that a purely monetarist response may be unable 
to to get the US
economy moving again. Since the economic crisis has entered the
perception of the public earlier this year, the FOMC has reduced both
the discount rate and the feds fund rate by 2 percent. Nevertheless,
Fed watchers are anticipating another rate cut at the Committee's May
15 meeting.

I'd say instead that the unused industrial capacity, the extremes of 
consumer and corporate debt (relative to assets, which have fallen in 
value), and the shift to pessimism are blocking monetary policy. So far, 
however, lower interest rates might spur growth in the housing sector. If 
that begins to fail, then monetary policy is pretty useless.

It's true that lower interest rates can stimulate US net exports (by 
pushing the dollar exchange rate down), but that simply stimulates the US 
economy at the expense of other countries. This doesn't work if other 
countries' interest rates also fall -- or if there's an effort to stabilize 
the dollar. Worse, the policy could work _too well_: if the dollar falls 
drastically, that causes an inflationary shock to the US economy (rising 
import costs, including most raw materials), which encourages the Fed to 
start raising rates again.

(Monetarism refers to an old-fashioned Friedmaniac philosophy of monetary 
policy, one that's been rejected by the vast majority of economists. 
(Monetarism involved the idea of controlling the money supply, not interest 
rates, and keeping the MS growing at a constant rate each year, no matter 
what happens.) However, as pen-l's Brad deLong makes clear, there's a heck 
of a lot of that old philosophy in what's now called Keynesianism.)

It could be that the current crop of investors have become so risk
adverse that they will not invest substantially even with reduced
interest rates. To speak anecdotally, I'm not personally aware of any
great new business plans or market opportunities. Particularly in the
tech sector, there is no new killer app or new device that people
simply must have. As a result, they continue to use the hardware and
software they already have. This could change.

The household market for PCs is pretty dead, since people don't need to 
replace old ones. The same applies to businesses, to a large extent, 
especially as the market for used PCs is swamped. In addition, it's smart 
to wait for PCs or MACs that have the promised new operating systems 
already built in, because the new OSs are very different from the old ones.

It may be, however, that  a Keyenesian government spending program could 
be required to spark the
economy again.

That's Dumbya's plan. Of course, he has to compensate for the regressivity 
of the tax cut (how it mostly helps the high end of the income 
distribution) by making it long-term (permanent) so that the well-to-do 
people who can plan ahead can rely on future tax cuts in planning 
consumption. The latter makes the tax cut more effective than if it were a 
one-shot deal.

A Keyensian tax cut will probably not work if investors
are so risk averse that they will not invest the money given to them by
the government. They'll just pocket it. In short, the wheels are stuck
in the mud, and no one is getting out to p

Keynesian tax cuts -- including Dumbya's -- affect consumer spending much 
more than (real) investment. That in turn could create the markets that 
businesses require if they want to invest in new plant and equipment.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




Re: US productivity falls

2001-05-08 Thread Michael Perelman

Also, it suggests that, contrary to the wishes of the new economy types,
that Robert Gordon was correct in insisting that much of the recent
productivity growth was cyclical.

Andrew Hagen wrote:

 Instead of the expected increase at a 1 percent annual rate, US
 productivity declined in the first quarter of this year. The
 preliminarly BLS results, seasonally adjusted, annual rates, were

  -0.4 percent in the business sector and
  -0.1 percent in the nonfarm business sector.

 This might be explained by the 5.2 percent annual rate increase in unit
 labor costs over the same time period. Could it reflect a surge in
 one-time downsizing charges taken by employers? If not, it may be a
 sign that a purely monetarist response may be unable to to get the US
 economy moving again. Since the economic crisis has entered the
 perception of the public earlier this year, the FOMC has reduced both
 the discount rate and the feds fund rate by 2 percent. Nevertheless,
 Fed watchers are anticipating another rate cut at the Committee's May
 15 meeting.

 It could be that the current crop of investors have become so risk
 adverse that they will not invest substantially even with reduced
 interest rates. To speak anecdotally, I'm not personally aware of any
 great new business plans or market opportunities. Particularly in the
 tech sector, there is no new killer app or new device that people
 simply must have. As a result, they continue to use the hardware and
 software they already have. This could change. It may be, however, that
 a Keyenesian government spending program could be required to spark the
 economy again. A Keyensian tax cut will probably not work if investors
 are so risk averse that they will not invest the money given to them by
 the government. They'll just pocket it. In short, the wheels are stuck
 in the mud, and no one is getting out to p

 http://stats.bls.gov/news.release/prod2.nr0.htm

 http://dailynews.yahoo.com/h/nm/20010508/bs/economy_productivity_dc_2.ht
 ml

 Andrew Hagen
 [EMAIL PROTECTED]

--

Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Chico, CA 95929
530-898-5321
fax 530-898-5901




Re: Re: US productivity falls

2001-05-08 Thread Jim Devine

At 09:06 AM 5/8/01 -0700, you wrote:
Also, it [the decline in labor productivity] suggests that, contrary to 
the wishes of the new economy types,
that Robert Gordon was correct in insisting that much of the recent
productivity growth was cyclical.

yes, but it's hard to tell from one quarter's stats. We could have had a 
new economy spurt of productivity growth during the period 1996 to 2000. 
It's also possible that notional (constant unemployment rate) labor 
productivity is continuing to spurt, but that the slowdown/possible 
recession means that the spurt isn't being realized in terms of actual 
productivity.

There was a spurt of labor productivity growth during the 1920s that wasn't 
realized during the 1930s but turned out to be the beginning of a new trend 
(compared to the period before 1919 or so) once high aggregate demand 
returned with WW2 and the 1950s warfare/welfare state.


Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




Re: Re: Re: US productivity falls

2001-05-08 Thread Michael Perelman

Jim, I agree with you.  I only said suggests.  Maybe I am too
suggestable.

On Tue, May 08, 2001 at 09:47:53AM -0700, Jim Devine wrote:
 At 09:06 AM 5/8/01 -0700, you wrote:
 Also, it [the decline in labor productivity] suggests that, contrary to 
 the wishes of the new economy types,
 that Robert Gordon was correct in insisting that much of the recent
 productivity growth was cyclical.
 
 yes, but it's hard to tell from one quarter's stats. We could have had a 
 new economy spurt of productivity growth during the period 1996 to 2000. 
 It's also possible that notional (constant unemployment rate) labor 
 productivity is continuing to spurt, but that the slowdown/possible 
 recession means that the spurt isn't being realized in terms of actual 
 productivity.
 
 There was a spurt of labor productivity growth during the 1920s that wasn't 
 realized during the 1930s but turned out to be the beginning of a new trend 
 (compared to the period before 1919 or so) once high aggregate demand 
 returned with WW2 and the 1950s warfare/welfare state.
 
 
 Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine
 

-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: US productivity falls

2001-05-08 Thread christian11

Jim Devine wrote:

 Keynesian tax cuts -- including Dumbya's -- affect consumer spending much more than 
(real) investment. That in turn could create the markets that businesses require if 
they want to invest in new plant and equipment.

What's the theory behind this--ie tax cuts affect demand more than investment? In 
light of the Fed study that Michael just posted an article about, would not this have 
to do with the target of the cuts?

Christian




Re: Re: Re: US productivity falls

2001-05-08 Thread Jim Devine

I wrote:
  Keynesian tax cuts -- including Dumbya's -- affect consumer spending 
 much more than (real) investment. That in turn could create the markets 
 that businesses require if they want to invest in new plant and equipment.

Christian writes:
What's the theory behind this--ie tax cuts affect demand more than 
investment? In light of the Fed study that Michael just posted an article 
about, would not this have to do with the target of the cuts?

it's absolutely true that tax cuts that are targeted to spur business fixed 
investment will do so (though Bush's proposal doesn't include this). 
However, these types of tax cuts are notoriously weak, delivering little or 
no bang for the buck. The problem is that businesses typically treat 
corporate tax cuts and investment tax credits as rewards for something 
they'd do anyway. Other concerns like cash flow and expectations play a 
bigger role. This is more of an empirical generalization than a theory, but 
it seems to be true.
Maybe others on pen-l could help...

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]  http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~JDevine




Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-05-02 Thread Doug Henwood

Michael Perelman wrote:

I suspect that most of us who teach economics would find brats text one of
the best available.

Michael, there seem to be some bugs in your voice recognition 
software. Either that, or it can read your unconscious.

Doug




Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-05-02 Thread Michael Perelman

oops! (now writing via keyboard).

On Wed, May 02, 2001 at 09:13:54AM -0400, Doug Henwood wrote:
 Michael Perelman wrote:
 
 I suspect that most of us who teach economics would find brats text one of
 the best available.
 
 Michael, there seem to be some bugs in your voice recognition 
 software. Either that, or it can read your unconscious.
 
 Doug
 

-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-05-01 Thread charlie

Re: Low productivity in the Global South

Brad DeLong referred to the United Nations Development Program.
He said, You can take a look at trends in the HDI since the
1970s at http://www.undp.org/hdro/BackMatter1.pdf. The claim
that people in developing countries today are worse off than
their counterparts a generation or two ago is, as best as we can
tell from the life expectancy data (which is solid), the
education data (which is subject to some manipulation, but is by
and large consistent with what surveys report), and the real GDP
data (much more shaky), completely false.

Well, not exactly. I looked at the UN reports (one with the
highly ambiguous title, Globalization with a human face).

Life expectancy:
Yes, the UN found increases since 1970 in life expectancy at
birth. The shocking thing is that a dozen countries suffered
outright decline in expectancy:

Life expectancy at birth
Country 19701997
-   
Belarus 71.068.0
Lithuania   71.469.9
Russian Fed 68.766.6
Latvia  70.368.4
Armenia 71.970.5
Ukraine 70.668.8

Botwana 51.647.4
Zimbabwe50.344.1
Zambia  46.340.1
Uganda  46.339.6
Rwanda  44.440.5
Burundi 43.742.4
(from the 1999 report)

Education and GDP:

I didn't find statistics on change since 1970 in years of
education. Does Mr. DeLong have a better URL?

Let's stipulate broad increases in education and GDP. The point
is that it does not make much sense to talk about these increases
without comparing them in some way with the increase in people's
economic needs.

Nearly every country produces a surplus of output over that which
would just maintain the existing way of life without change. The
working people perform the surplus labor that produces the
surplus output, which in so-called developing countries goes
partly to developing the powers of production and partly to
supporting the unproductive comfort of a small percentage of the
population. With the development of the powers of production,
educational and material needs increase. An industrial worker
needs more education than a subsistence farmer. A city resident
needs more transportation services than a villager. If we compare
production with needs, we see that inequality is not an abstract
moral issue but a more pressing one: how much of the population
lives below the level of need corresponding to the level of
output? Does the economic order develop the powers of production
as much as it can in consideration of people's labor, and does it
equip people to participate fully and equally in the most
advanced labor as well as its fruits?

Relevant statistics would display inequalities within the
population now and also measure how increases in education and
GDP since 1970 compare with the increase in needs since then. In
the absence of UN data, various contributors to this topic have
argued from other information that inequality has increased since
1970 between the developed and developing countries and within
the latter, that world capitalism has wasted vast amounts of
people's labor, and that people's needs at today's levels of
education and market GDP are more acute than they were in 1970.

(As a minor addendum, the UN reports show the following for
external debt as a percent of GDP:
For the bottom-level low human development countries,
19851997
  69%   93%
For the medium developmentcountries,
19851997
  35%   33%
which averages increases in some countries with
decreases in others.)

Charles Andrews
Web site for my book is at http://www.LaborRepublic.org
and
my essay on globalization is posted at
http://www.LaborRepublic.org/Essay44.htm




Re: Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-05-01 Thread Rob Schaap

G'day Brad,

I think all this ribbing about your textbook is a bit off colour (I'd buy it
if I weren't stuck with Australian kopeks), but I reserve the right to
disagree with you.

 Everyone--at least everyone who was honest--agreed that improvements
 in working-class standards of living during the 1790-1850 period in
 Britain were small or nonexistent if there were any improvements at
 all. Everyone agreed that improvements in working-class standards of
 living after 1850 were large--on the order of 1% per year or more
 average growth in real incomes.
 
 Estimates of the average trend in British working-class standards of
 living between 1790 and 1850 ranged from a lower bound of about -0.3
 percent per year to an upper bound of +0.4 percent per year.
 
 Any honest assessment of the debate is very, very far indeed from:
 Just tell me the answer you want, and we can find the appropriate
 authorities to support it.

I agree with all this - as far as the United Kingdom of the time, the
imperialist hegemon du jour, is concerned.  How much that tells us about other
places and other times is what I'm worried about, though.

 The more interesting question--and the question about which there is
 more disagreement--is not what happened to working-class standards
 of living in Britain during the industrial revolution?--but what
 would have happened to working-class standards of living in the
 absence of the industrial revolution? 

A more interesting question is, can the lessons of UK 1790-1914 be
uncritically imported into debates about Ghana 1957-2001, or anywhere else, or
at any other time.  Cuba features well on international comparisons of these
social indicators, after all.  And rather than imperialist hegemon, it is a
blockaded pariah.

 One possibility (advocated by
 Ken Pomeranz and others) is that Britain would have undergone a
 full-blown Malthusian crisis with *massive* declines in living
 standards on the part of the poor until increases in death rates
 stopped population growth--and that only the coming of the industrial
 revolution allowed British working-class standards of living to
 remain roughly constant in the first half of the nineteenth century.
 Another possibility is that Britain without the social upheaval of
 the industrial revolution would have had lower rates of population
 growth, a higher land/labor ratio, and possibly higher real wages.
 These issues are still wide open.

Still don't think this is central stuff, I'm afraid.  Britain and the US
developed under relatively statist political conditions, whereby the
international dimension entered the picture primarily as value extraction from
periphery to core.  That ain't the relation Ghana faces.
 
 But this kind of nihilistic denial that we know anything about the
 past--that authorities are driven by ideology and nothing else--is
 simply false.

Well, one way of spotting ideology is to examine how stats are interpreted
(given that we've discussed that others are how they're produced, who produces
'em and why they're produced).  An improved life expectancy might correlate
with the permeation of commodified life, for instance, but cause-effect
relations are hard to establish.  The introduction of antibiotics,
anti-malaria and anti-diarrhoea medicines can make a huge difference in
tropical third-world societies in the short to medium term, for instance. 
That happened in many places (including your example of Bangladesh) precisely
in the period from which you choose your life expectancy stats.  Now, those
medicines might have entered the society through 'free market' processes (I
think that's moot, though), but neither the development (much of which
occurred through state-subsidised and coordinated research) nor the diffusion
(much of which occurred through government and NGO activity) of these drugs
was decisively dependent on 'free markets'.  They might have depended on
economic linkages between nations, but that, too, does not necessarily demand
capitalist relations (the Cuban example again). 

Add to that the point that the huge dislocations immanent in 'industrial
revolutions' are always traumatic, but more often exacerbated by economic
dependency (you don't have to reject the idea of a WB - but you should inquire
as to the politics of policy within the WB, for instance) than ameliorated by
the imperialist advantage enjoyed by the UK and US during their wonderful
advances, and you have plenty of reason to question the universalist
neoliberal prescriptions.

As for literacy, that too would be expected to increase radically while the
base is low.  There's nothing in IMF restructuring requirements to indicate
that health and literacy should be expected to increase across the population
after these initial improvements.  I think they'll decline or, at least, take
a more stratified form.  But we won't have the stats to prove that for a
generation or two.  

And then we'll still be arguing about whether technological advances like

Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-05-01 Thread Michael Perelman

On Wed, May 02, 2001 at 10:28:21AM +, Rob Schaap wrote:

 I think all this ribbing about your textbook is a bit off colour (I'd
buy it
 if I weren't stuck with Australian kopeks), but I reserve the right to
 disagree with you.

I suspect that most of us who teach economics would find brats text one of
the best available.  The fact that he says that he minimizes the Aggregate
Supply-Aggregate Demand material puts him at the head of the list.


-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-04-30 Thread Louis Proyect

Brad Delong wrote:
Good God! Do you think that the *entire* World Bank _Human 
Development Report_ is a lie?

No, it is not a lie. But it is far too narrow a perspective. This is like
examining the development statistics of Chile after 5 years or so of
Pinochet and crowing about how rapid the rise has been. Of course, this
only makes sense if you bracket out the Allende years, prior to the full
onslaught of the CIA, when the statistics far exceeded those of Pinochet.
So context is everything.

To properly gauge the success or lack of success of capitalism in the third
world, it is necessary to factor in lots of things that would get ignored
in a World Bank Report. For example, capitalism was responsible for the
slaughter of 90 percent of the indigenous population during the early
colonial years when capitalism was sinking roots. So if the wages from 1600
to 2000 are based on demographics that sweeps all the corpses under the
rug, things will look a lot better. It is like stating that the average
four-member family in some country owns a 3 bedroom house. But if that
family axe murdered another family who was living in the house beforehand,
then you can say that the system was not only stagnant but evil.

Basically I find DeLong's arguments a sophisticated defense of stagnation
and murder. Tens of millions of corpses never enter the picture. Who cares
if all the native inhabitants of New England were exterminated, if you have
shopping malls in Marblehead today. That's some god-damned argument.
Jonathan Swift, where are you when we need you.


Louis Proyect
Marxism mailing list: http://www.marxmail.org




Re: Re: Re: Re: Low productivity in the GlobalSouth

2001-04-30 Thread Doug Henwood

Michael Perelman wrote:

Brad, there was a long debate about the standard of living during the
Industrial Revolution.  You probably know the literature as well as
anyone.  The issue is complex, but Lou's monetization point cannot be
dismissed.

No it can't, but 1) we're a long way past the Industrial Revolution, 
and 2) does anyone know how many people it applies to today? We seem 
to have two extremes here, with LNP saying it applies broadly, and 
BDL saying it hardly applies at all. Does anyone really know?

Doug




Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-04-30 Thread Louis Proyect

No it can't, but 1) we're a long way past the Industrial Revolution, 
and 2) does anyone know how many people it applies to today? We seem 
to have two extremes here, with LNP saying it applies broadly, and 
BDL saying it hardly applies at all. Does anyone really know?

Doug

It is useful to hone in on specific countries rather than to talk about the
third world in broad generalizations. Of the countries I have made close
studies of, including Nicaragua and Colombia, I can say that my analysis is
rigorous and can be easily documented. In both countries the majority of
its citizens were peasants living by subsistence farming who traded surplus
for manufactured goods in cities like Esteli, Cordoba, etc. The entire 20th
century has been about removal of peasants from their land, to support
cattle-ranching in one case, or coffee growing in the other. Based on the
concrete historical experience of such nations, it is fairly easy to
extrapolate from this and judge Peru, Ghana, etc. on similar terms. They
share common characteristics:

1. reliance on export agriculture
2. failure to develop native industries
3. domination by foreign financial and industrial corporations
4. forced emigration in search of jobs (NYC's supermarket delivery boys
all come from Africa)
5. explosion of the informal economy

The economics has been documented extensively: Baran, Sweezy, Magdoff,
Petras, Wallerstein, Amin, Frank, Vilas, et al. If you take the economic
analysis and apply it to individual countries like Colombia or Nicaragua,
there is one and only one conclusion you can draw. Capitalism does not work.

Louis Proyect
Marxism mailing list: http://www.marxmail.org




Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-04-30 Thread Jim Devine

Doug wrote:we're a long way past the Industrial Revolution, 

that's true for the U.S. and the rest of the rich capitalist countries, but 
it's not true of most of the poor countries.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-04-30 Thread Michael Perelman

The debate about the standard of living him in the Industrial Revolution
involved some of the best in economic historians.  It was quite similar in
some ways to the exchanges between Lou and Brad.  You asked for conclusive
answers.  That's easy.  Just tell me the answer you want, and we can find
the appropriate authorities to support it.

One side said that the workers could now drink tea.  The other side said
that the team was a poor substitute for milk.

In a way, it is like the Boskin commission writ large.  Economic
measurement was very subjective.

On Mon, Apr 30, 2001 at 12:11:31PM -0400, Doug Henwood wrote:
 Michael Perelman wrote:
 
 Brad, there was a long debate about the standard of living during the
 Industrial Revolution.  You probably know the literature as well as
 anyone.  The issue is complex, but Lou's monetization point cannot be
 dismissed.
 
 No it can't, but 1) we're a long way past the Industrial Revolution, 
 and 2) does anyone know how many people it applies to today? We seem 
 to have two extremes here, with LNP saying it applies broadly, and 
 BDL saying it hardly applies at all. Does anyone really know?
 
 Doug
 

-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Re: Re: Low productivity in the GlobalSouth

2001-04-30 Thread Brad DeLong

Brad, there was a long debate about the standard of living during the
Industrial Revolution.  You probably know the literature as well as
anyone.  The issue is complex, but Lou's monetization point cannot be
dismissed.

Yes it can be dismissed. It's not important or powerful enough to alter trends.

There was a long debate about the standard of living during the 
Industrial Revolution *in* *Britain*. There is no debate about the 
standard of living during the Industrial Revolution in France, or 
Germany, or Spain, or Sweden, or Italy because no one maintains that 
urbanization and industrialization lowered the standard of living of 
the rural poor, or of those who migrated to the cities and so changed 
from being rural poor to being urban poor.

The United Nations Development Program works hard at compiling a 
human development index--a weighted combination of  life expectancy, 
educational attainment, and real material standards of living across 
the world. You can take a look at trends in the HDI since the 1970s 
at http://www.undp.org/hdro/BackMatter1.pdf. The claim that people 
in developing countries today are worse off than their counterparts a 
generation or two ago is, as best as we can tell from the life 
expectancy data (which is solid), the education data (which is 
subject to some manipulation, but is by and large consistent with 
what surveys report), and the real GDP data (much more shaky), 
completely false.

Now you can look at the world as it is--and see global progress 
(although much less than I would wish to see). Or you can emulate the 
Bourbons.


Brad DeLong




Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-04-30 Thread Brad DeLong

Michael Perelman wrote:

Brad, there was a long debate about the standard of living during the
Industrial Revolution.  You probably know the literature as well as
anyone.  The issue is complex, but Lou's monetization point cannot be
dismissed.

No it can't, but 1) we're a long way past the Industrial Revolution, 
and 2) does anyone know how many people it applies to today? We seem 
to have two extremes here, with LNP saying it applies broadly, and 
BDL saying it hardly applies at all. Does anyone really know?

Doug


Well, the Human Development Index suggests substantial progress over 
the past generation.

But that would involve actually looking at the world, which is not 
encouraged in this venue. A cite to Marx's belief that the urban poor 
of Manchester in 1848 were poorer than their grandparents had been in 
the British countryside in 1798 is preferable to observing that even 
in resource-poor Bangladesh today, with U.S. consumers protected 
against the danger of buying Bangladeshi textiles made with child 
labor, 80% of newborns are expected to survive to age 40, and that 
was definitely not the case two generations ago...


Brad DeLong




Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-04-30 Thread Brad DeLong

The debate about the standard of living him in the Industrial Revolution
involved some of the best in economic historians.  It was quite similar in
some ways to the exchanges between Lou and Brad.  You asked for conclusive
answers.  That's easy.  Just tell me the answer you want, and we can find
the appropriate authorities to support it.

One side said that the workers could now drink tea.  The other side said
that the team was a poor substitute for milk.


Bullshit.

Everyone--at least everyone who was honest--agreed that improvements 
in working-class standards of living during the 1790-1850 period in 
Britain were small or nonexistent if there were any improvements at 
all. Everyone agreed that improvements in working-class standards of 
living after 1850 were large--on the order of 1% per year or more 
average growth in real incomes.

Estimates of the average trend in British working-class standards of 
living between 1790 and 1850 ranged from a lower bound of about -0.3 
percent per year to an upper bound of +0.4 percent per year.

Any honest assessment of the debate is very, very far indeed from: 
Just tell me the answer you want, and we can find the appropriate 
authorities to support it.

The more interesting question--and the question about which there is 
more disagreement--is not what happened to working-class standards 
of living in Britain during the industrial revolution?--but what 
would have happened to working-class standards of living in the 
absence of the industrial revolution? One possibility (advocated by 
Ken Pomeranz and others) is that Britain would have undergone a 
full-blown Malthusian crisis with *massive* declines in living 
standards on the part of the poor until increases in death rates 
stopped population growth--and that only the coming of the industrial 
revolution allowed British working-class standards of living to 
remain roughly constant in the first half of the nineteenth century. 
Another possibility is that Britain without the social upheaval of 
the industrial revolution would have had lower rates of population 
growth, a higher land/labor ratio, and possibly higher real wages. 
These issues are still wide open.

But this kind of nihilistic denial that we know anything about the 
past--that authorities are driven by ideology and nothing else--is 
simply false.


Brad DeLong




Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-04-30 Thread Louis Proyect

But that would involve actually looking at the world, which is not 
encouraged in this venue. A cite to Marx's belief that the urban poor 
of Manchester in 1848 were poorer than their grandparents had been in 
the British countryside in 1798 is preferable to observing that even 
in resource-poor Bangladesh today, with U.S. consumers protected 
against the danger of buying Bangladeshi textiles made with child 
labor, 80% of newborns are expected to survive to age 40, and that 
was definitely not the case two generations ago...


Brad DeLong

This is a whitewash of Bangladesh capitalism. Of the five countries in the
world suffering from landlessness, Bangladesh rates the highest at 54%. The
reason you can get children to work for pennies in sweatshops that catch
fire every 6 months or so is because of unequal land ownership. As I
stated, this is the main problem in the third world. If peasants could grow
their own food in fertile Bangladesh, they wouldn't be so dependent on the
kindness of strangers shopping in Kmart.

Louis Proyect
Marxism mailing list: http://www.marxmail.org




Re: Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-04-30 Thread Michael Perelman

Rarely do I encounter someone so self confident.

Brad DeLong wrote:


 Bullshit.

 Everyone agreed that improvements in working-class standards of
 living after 1850 were large--on the order of 1% per year or more
 average growth in real incomes.


Oh, yeah, you mean the period when the poor got some trickle down from
imperialism.


 Estimates of the average trend in British working-class standards of
 living between 1790 and 1850 ranged from a lower bound of about -0.3
 percent per year to an upper bound of +0.4 percent per year.

 Any honest assessment of the debate is very, very far indeed from:
 Just tell me the answer you want, and we can find the appropriate
 authorities to support it.

 The more interesting question--and the question about which there is
 more disagreement--is not what happened to working-class standards
 of living in Britain during the industrial revolution?--but what
 would have happened to working-class standards of living in the
 absence of the industrial revolution?

Do you mean by this counterfactual, what if workers people were herded into the
cities without the jobs?

 One possibility (advocated by
 Ken Pomeranz and others) is that Britain would have undergone a
 full-blown Malthusian crisis

British did not practice very intensive agriculture.  They could have easily
produced much more food.  Disease in the cities was much more of a threat than
lack of food.

 with *massive* declines in living
 standards on the part of the poor until increases in death rates
 stopped population growth--and that only the coming of the industrial
 revolution allowed British working-class standards of living to
 remain roughly constant in the first half of the nineteenth century.
 Another possibility is that Britain without the social upheaval of
 the industrial revolution would have had lower rates of population
 growth, a higher land/labor ratio, and possibly higher real wages.
 These issues are still wide open.

 But this kind of nihilistic denial that we know anything about the
 past--that authorities are driven by ideology and nothing else--is
 simply false.

 Brad DeLong

--

Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-04-30 Thread Stephen E Philion


Brad wrote:
 in resource-poor Bangladesh today, with U.S. consumers protected
 against the danger of buying Bangladeshi textiles made with child
 labor, 80% of newborns are expected to survive to age 40, and that
 was definitely not the case two generations ago...
 
 
 Brad DeLong

The sarcastic reference to US consumers protected from Bangladeshi child
labor seems a bit off the mark given this letter to the NYT from an
AFL-CIO Dept. rep...


[T] o the Editor:

Re Hearts and Heads, by Paul Krugman (column, April 22):

It is true that in 1993 the threat of United States legislation led
irresponsible garment factory owners in Banladesh to dismiss child
workers, who had no immediate prospects for schooling. But a five-year
memorandum of understanding, signed in 1995 by Unicef and the
International Labor Organization with the Bangladesh Garment
Manufacturers and Exporters Association, has provided schooling and
income support for more than 27,000 former child laborers.

Since then, the number of exporting factories using children has dropped
from 43 to 5 percent, allowing more Bangladeshi adults to move into jobs
previously held by children. Meanwhile, the Bangladesh garment export
industry grew almost 500 percent from 1990 to 2000.

BARBARA SHAILOR




Re: Re: Low productivity in the Global South

2001-04-29 Thread Brad DeLong

Well, yes, but isn't it obvious to PK that the latter (competition 
among workers for jobs) far outweighs the former (competition among 
capitalists for workers) when 50% or more of the labor force are 
unemployed  sweatshop wages are better than wages of many other 
kinds of work in the area???  Since he himself argues that sweatshop 
work is in fact greatly desired by workers who have few other 
options???

Yoshie

No. Wage levels in open developing countries have been increasing 
rapidly over the past two generations, and so (with the exception of 
the United States and New Zealand) have wage levels in industrial 
countries...


Brad DeLong




  1   2   >