Re: Canada, NAFTA and energy

2001-01-30 Thread Ken Hanly

An excellent article. I am always amazed the National Post, a staunch
right-wing rag owned by left-hater Conrad Black, permits columns such as
this by a hard-hitting popular left wing writer. Albertans are also asking
themselves these days why they are required to pay about 800,000 to defend
their erstwhile treasurer
Stockwell Day, now leader of  federal right=wing Alliance party in a
law-suit resulting from his inability to keep his foot out of his mouth.
Action is being taken to have the payments declared illegal and to attempt
to have Day reimburse the province.
   Cheers, Ken Hanly

- Original Message -
From: Lisa  Ian Murray [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: Tuesday, January 30, 2001 10:08 AM
Subject: [PEN-L:7522] Canada, NAFTA and energy


 [from an FTAA list]
 http://www.nationalpost.com/
 It's the NAFTA, stupid


 Linda McQuaig
 National Post





Re: Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-14 Thread Rob Schaap

Asks Jim,

did the dominions -- and the colonies -- have any choice in this matter?

Yep, we did.  The one thing about which I agree with Brad is that it was no
bad thing we went the way we did.  But we've actually had the sovereignty
since 1901 to decide for ourselves whether we'd enter wars, shoot our own
chaps, allow nuclear tests on Australian soil, and so on.  Generally we are
very weak at such decisive moments, and, when we're ultimately - almost
inevitably - exploited, soiled or embarrassed, we inevitably wholly blame
the superior.  It could easily be argued it was our fault our lads' guts
ended up all over Gallipolli and the Somme, that they shot Breaker Morant
and his like, that they wafted great clouds of radioactive filth all over
central Australia etc etc.  But I've never heard anyone put that argument.
It was all those bloody poms, y'see.

And now it's all those bloody yanks ...

Cheers,
Rob.




Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-14 Thread Jim Devine

I asked:
 did the dominions -- and the colonies -- have any choice in this matter?

Rob said:
Yep, we did.  The one thing about which I agree with Brad is that it was no
bad thing we went the way we did.

yeah, I think it was good to fight Hitler, too. Too bad so many -- 
including the US gov't -- gave up on the fight against fascism so quickly 
when the war ended and started to embrace fascists as allies ...

But we've actually had the sovereignty since 1901 to decide for ourselves 
whether we'd enter wars, shoot our own chaps, allow nuclear tests on 
Australian soil, and so on.

but isn't there a lot of evidence that the Governor General of Australia (a 
British appointee at the time?) cooperated with the US to oust an 
inconvenient PM? (was that Gough Whitlam who was ousted?) If so, official 
sovereignty works different in practice.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-12 Thread Jim Devine

Ken wrote:
Interesting that you should say this in a post that includes the title
Canada and Australia. I don't know about Australia but Canada joined the war
very early, in 1939 I believe.

Brad writes:
Touche... All the dominions did...

did the dominions -- and the colonies -- have any choice in this matter?

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Nestor Miguel Gorojovsky

After I read what follows, and which deserves no answer at all, I am 
beginning to believe that I am not debating with Brad DeLong, but 
with Spruille Braden DeLong. From now onwards, I will put things in 
clear by addressing Mr. Braden DeLong...


En relación a [PEN-L:1685] Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina, 
el 10 Sep 00, a las 22:25, Brad DeLong dijo:

 En relación a [PEN-L:1549] Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argen, el
 10 Sep 00, a las 3:37, Rob Schaap dijo:
 
   Australia, too, consciously nourished its (relative) independence,
   largely through mutually constitutive ties between Australia's
   government and bourgeoisie - ensuring that the latter would not
   serve as a compradorial local elite for foreign interests. 
 
 This is EXACTLY what Peronism attempted to do here, and failed.
 
 Funny to see again how different are things in an imperialist country
 and in a colony. In more senses than one, Peronism, which is widely
 known outside Argentina (and particularly in the United States) as a
 Fascist South American overgrowth that remained alive for a decade
 after Nazism was swept away from Europe was in fact a domestic
 version of a Labour government in Australia...
 
 Any Labor government--hell, *any* democratic government or *any*
 left-of-center non-democratic government--would have been eager to
 join the war against Hitler. Peron was not--hence the classification
 of his regime as "fascist South American overgrowth" seems not
 unfair...

My dear Mr. Braden DeLong: Argentina wasn't, by any means, the only 
country that remained neutral during World War II. Most peoples 
weren't even allowed the possibility to have a saying, because they 
were under occupation: there were imperialist troops deployed all 
over Africa, over a good deal of Asia, even over Latin America -you 
the democratic Americans had put in prison our cherished and beloved 
Albizu Campos, who died in prison in Atlanta, because of the sin of 
fighting for the independence of Puerto Rico against your democratic 
will; India's leader Ghandi, out of calculation, decided to side with 
Britain, but not before a long debate took place and not before he 
intentionally had visited Mr. Mussolini against the advice of every 
"democratic" imperialist in Europe.

Hadn't the colonial empires existed, be sure that most people in the 
world would have been indifferent to Mr. Hitler's actions. "What's 
new with that, would many have said, he's just doing to white people 
what all of them have been doing to us for decades and centuries?"

Not that I agree with that position. I, personally and as an isolated 
individual, are for war against all imperialists. That is the 
position I would have raised in Argentina, 1939. But our neutrality 
was an absolutely justifiable one. And, as I explained, it even was 
of help for the war effort of Great Britain. Let me show now that 
countries who profited from the war, and who in many ways gave help 
to the Nazi regime, are considered "democratic" by Brad, whereas this 
treatment is denied to Argentina.

Among others which I could mention, I prefer to center on two: 
Switzerland. Sweden. Switzerland proved a "neutral" hideaway for Nazi 
money and riches stolen from many, particularly from the Jews, as it 
has recently been shown. Sweden was still worse: the Socialist 
government there allowed the Nazi troops to traverse its Northern 
territories in order to occupy Norway (by the way, in order to 
protect their own citizens, the Swedish government put the militant 
union leaders of the North in prison while the Wehrmacht merrily 
toured the Kiruna steel mines on way to the Atlantic).

Why do you slander the Argentinians, who were victims of Anglo-
American expoliation and thus had at least a reasonable motivation to 
remain neutral, while you do not slander the Swiss or the Swedes? I 
will tell you again, Mr. Braden: that is because you are an 
imperialist under "Leftist" robes.


 
 As for Peron's social and economic policies, I have always been 
 fascinated with the extraordinary economic success of post-WWII 
 western Europe relative to Argentina.

Ah, that's reasonable. Your country made a strong investment effort 
in an Europe that was ruined but still had strong assets to rebuild 
itself. Argentina had to clumsily manage by herself, against the 
pressure of the American Department of State and the cold hostility 
of other imperialist regimes. The Europeans had a full bearded 
bourgeoisie, while the first minister of Economy of Peronism was the 
chubby owner of a small manufacturer of tins for a minor peach 
packer. Miguel Miranda, a man with no Universities, proved however 
that it was possible to boost popular consumption, rise wages, and 
have an economic boom all at the same time. He could not prove (and 
this was his doom) that all this was sustainable without socialist 
measures, but at least he gave millions of people four

Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Rob Schaap

G'day Nestor and Brad,

Why do you slander the Argentinians, who were victims of Anglo-
American expoliation and thus had at least a reasonable motivation to 
remain neutral, while you do not slander the Swiss or the Swedes? 

Or the Americans?  Whose own popular president (if you don't count the views
of the big cappos, anyway) couldn't manage to bring that mighty democracy
into the war against tyranny until it got one of its colonies bombed by it
(and Germany, rather ambitiously, declared war).  How long would Unca Sam
have sat and watched, selling its hardware to the combatants all the while,
if events hadn't forced his mighty hand?

C'mon Brad.  Be fair.

Cheers,
Rob.




Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Brad De Long

After I read what follows, and which deserves no answer at all, I am
beginning to believe that I am not debating with Brad DeLong, but
with Spruille Braden DeLong. From now onwards, I will put things in
clear by addressing Mr. Braden DeLong...


En relación a [PEN-L:1685] Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina,
el 10 Sep 00, a las 22:25, Brad DeLong dijo:

  En relación a [PEN-L:1549] Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argen, el
  10 Sep 00, a las 3:37, Rob Schaap dijo:
  
Australia, too, consciously nourished its (relative) independence,
largely through mutually constitutive ties between Australia's
government and bourgeoisie - ensuring that the latter would not
serve as a compradorial local elite for foreign interests.
  
  This is EXACTLY what Peronism attempted to do here, and failed.
  
  Funny to see again how different are things in an imperialist country
  and in a colony. In more senses than one, Peronism, which is widely
   known outside Argentina (and particularly in the United States) as a
My dear Mr. Braden DeLong: Argentina wasn't, by any means, the only
country that remained neutral during World War II...

Hmmm. My count was Sweden (which profited immensely from shipping 
iron ore to Germany, and letting Wehrmacht trains run across its 
territory), Switzerland (which profited immensely for other reasons), 
Franco's Spain, and Argentina. Anybody else who remained neutral to 
the end? Any other countries that received Nazi refugees with open 
arms after the war? I'm not aware of any.

Hadn't the colonial empires existed, be sure that most people in the
world would have been indifferent to Mr. Hitler's actions. "What's
new with that, would many have said, he's just doing to white people
what all of them have been doing to us for decades and centuries?"

No. Very few people in the world believe in such doctrines of racial 
collective responsibility. Those guilty of crimes are those who 
commit them--not others who happen to look like them. None of the 
east european Jews herded into Auschwitz had ever taken hostages from 
a Burmese village. None of the Gypsies herded into Dachau had ever 
served as a vector of disease transmission to Mexico. None of the 
Russians summarily shot as the Wehrmacht entered a village had ever 
placed any Chinese migrant worker into debt peonage.

And very few of the people in the world thought the victims of 
genocide were just "getting what they deserved". Only Nazis thought 
so, and people who think like Nazis. Although your post suggests 
otherwise, relatively few people in the world have ever thought like 
Nazis.


Brad DeLong




Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Brad De Long

But Díaz Alejandro is... the ultimate sepoy, and it is
not a matter of chance that, in the economic circles of the United
States of America, the Braden DeLongs consider his 600 page long
bunch of half-muttered hardly digerible stupidities a "standard book"
on Argentina.

To argue that the Peronist economic strategy looked like a very 
reasonable one to adopt as of the end of World War II, but proved 
ultimately disastrous because it had unintended catastrophic 
consequences for the rate of capital accumulation--that's the core of 
Diaz Alejandro's argument. It's not a bunch of half-muttered hardly 
derigible stupidities.

And whence comes "sepoy" as a term of abuse? "Sepoy" is an English 
misspelling of "sipahi", the Turkic term for the elite cavalry of the 
Turkish empires, which after the Islamization of the Turks fought 
from Hyderabad to Moscow, from Urumchi to Vienna. Under Turkish rule 
commerce flourished and long distance trade grew: Turkic kingdoms 
played a key role in transferring technology and thus encouraging 
economic growth from one end of Eurasia to the other for a thousand 
years. Skilled, loyal, bold, clever--the British East India Company 
wanted to recruit sipahis from the declining Moghul Empire for their 
armies because of their virtues.


   Perón sought to generate rapid growth and to twist terms of
  trade against rural agriculture and redistribute wealth to urban
  workers who did not receive their fair share.

False. Perón sought to fuel industrial growth with the remains of the
differential rent on the world market that had bestowed such a gift
on Argentinian landed oligarchy for decaedes. He redistributed wealth
the country over. "Urban workers" were already the large mass of
Argentinians, but also "rural workers" were benefitted.

Everything I've seen suggests not. Lower prices for agricultural 
commodities blew back into lower standards of living for rural 
workers under Peron...


  The redistribution to
  urban workers and to firms that had to pay their newly increased wages
  required a redistribution away from exporters, agricultural oligarchs,
  foreigners, and entrepreneurs.

Yes, quite fair, but not "entrepreneurs" nor "foreigners": the first
is an obviously senseless category,

Marx did not think so...

  Landowner and
  exporter elites had always appropriated the lion's share of the
  benefits of free trade. They had in the 1930's shown a willingness to
  sacrifice political democracy in order to stunt the growth of the
  domestic welfare state.

Another idiocy. "Landowner and exporter elites" were in no way
interested in stunting the growth of a domestic welfare state because
this state did simply NOT exist.

And why didn't it exist? Because during the Great Depression--when 
FDR built the welfare state in the United States--Argentina's 
landlord and exporter elites used the army to make sure that no 
FDR-like figure held power in Argentina.

   The Peronist program seemed prima facie
  reasonable given the memory of the Great Depression, and it produced
  almost half a decade of very rapid growth toward the end of the 1940s.

Quite true. Only that "rapid growth" is not precisely what one would
say of a programme that at the same time reconstructed the country
and gave more than half its population a new sense of personal
dignity. But we are among economists here, who cares for these stupid
issues?


  Then exports fell sharply as a result of the international business
  cycle. And exports fell further as the consequences of the enforced
  reduction in real prices of rural exportables made themselves felt.

What do you mean, "enforced reduction"? On the contrary, the state
monopoly on foreign trade (the IAPI, a bourgeois forerunner of a
socialist self-defence mechanism, in fact) obtained better prices for
farmers than the prices they had ever obtained from the trade
monopolies of foreign capital. What is true is that a share of those
better prices was redistributed, via the State, to industries and not
to luxurious consumption.

Better prices for the state when it sells overseas, worse prices for 
farmers (and farmworkiers) when they sell to the monopsonistic state.


  Domestic consumption rose. The
  rural sector found itself short of fertilizer and tractors. Squeezed
  between declining production and rising domestic consumption,
  Argentinian exports fell.

Argentinian main export commodity was by those times meat. Meat needs
no tractors in the pastorile conditions of those times.

Meat needs a *lot* of grain for the final fattening-up process

On the other
side, Perón arrived at agreements for local design and construction
of agrarian machinery and tractors

At five times the resource cost of John Deere: expensive tractors are 
a very bad thing for temperate agricultural development.


The enemy was
already in combat outfit by 1950. Korea was to be the first
demonstration.

Oh God! Not another idiot fan of Kim Il Sung!

Brad DeLong




Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Jim Devine

At 10:25 PM 9/10/00 -0700, you wrote:
Any Labor government--hell, *any* democratic government or *any* 
left-of-center non-democratic government--would have been eager to join 
the war against Hitler. Peron was not--hence the classification of his 
regime as "fascist South American overgrowth" seems not unfair...

so you believe that Eldridge Cleaver's old dictum that "if you're not part 
of the solution, you're part of the problem"? So the fact that the US was 
"neutral" against the Spanish fascists during the Civil War there indicates 
that the US was semi-fascist?

This fits with the consistent trend of US foreign policy since then, i.e., 
the willingness to ally with fascists and to impose fascist governments (as 
in Chile) when democracy didn't serve US interests.

That said, I don't think that the over-used word "fascist" really fits the 
US government. Rather, the US gov't is pro-crypto-fascist (as Gore called 
Bill).

[That's Vidal and Buckley, not Al and Clinton.]

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Brad DeLong

so you believe that Eldridge Cleaver's old dictum that "if you're 
not part of the solution, you're part of the problem"? So the fact 
that the US was "neutral" against the Spanish fascists during the 
Civil War there indicates that the US was semi-fascist?


Lots of people refused to aid or tried to harm the Loyalist cause 
during the Spanish Civil War (including, IMO, the Soviet Union--much 
more interested in smashing Trotskyism than in defeating Franco). 
IIRC, only four governments--Switzerland, Sweden, Franco's Spain, and 
Peron's Argentina--had failed to join the United Nations by the end 
of the war against Hitler.


Brad DeLong




Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Ken Hanly

Interesting that you should say this in a post that includes the title
Canada and Australia. I don't know about Australia but Canada joined the war
very early, in 1939 I believe.
  Cheers, Ken Hanly

 In fact, all countries except for two either (i) waited for Hitler to
 bring the war to them, or (ii) joined in the war against Hitler only
 in the last stages, after his defeat was assured.

  Brad DeLong





Re: Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Shane Mage


Lots of people refused to aid or tried to harm the Loyalist cause
during the Spanish Civil War (including, IMO, the Soviet Union--much
more interested in smashing Trotskyism than in defeating Franco).
IIRC, only four governments--Switzerland, Sweden, Franco's Spain, and
Peron's Argentina--had failed to join the United Nations by the end
of the war against Hitler.


Brad DeLong

You leave one not unimportant country out of your list of neutrals--
Ireland (Eire).  Not to mention one "democratic" European country
that was allied with the Nazis throughout virtually the entire
war--Finland.

Shane Mage

"Thunderbolt steers all things."


Herakleitos of Ephesos, fr. 64




Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Eugene Coyle



Shane Mage quotes Brad DeLong:

 Lots of people refused to aid or tried to harm the Loyalist cause
 during the Spanish Civil War (including, IMO, the Soviet Union--much
 more interested in smashing Trotskyism than in defeating Franco).
 IIRC, only four governments--Switzerland, Sweden, Franco's Spain, and
 Peron's Argentina--had failed to join the United Nations by the end
 of the war against Hitler.
 
 
 Brad DeLong

 You leave one not unimportant country out of your list of neutrals--
 Ireland (Eire).  Not to mention one "democratic" European country
 that was allied with the Nazis throughout virtually the entire
 war--Finland.

 Shane Mage

 "Thunderbolt steers all things."

 Herakleitos of Ephesos, fr. 64

Brad, is the correct inference that you would have supported the Loyalist
cause?

And where do you put the USA on the spectrum of "refused to aid or tried
to harm"?  After all, winking at oil companies who sold oil to Franco in
spite of an embargo must go in that spectrum somewhere.

And wasn't UK and USA "neutrality" designed to harm the Loyalist
cause?

Gene Coyle





Premature Anti-Fascists (was Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina)

2000-09-11 Thread Yoshie Furuhashi

Jim D. wrote:

At 10:25 PM 9/10/00 -0700, you wrote:
Any Labor government--hell, *any* democratic government or *any* 
left-of-center non-democratic government--would have been eager to 
join the war against Hitler. Peron was not--hence the 
classification of his regime as "fascist South American overgrowth" 
seems not unfair...

so you believe that Eldridge Cleaver's old dictum that "if you're 
not part of the solution, you're part of the problem"? So the fact 
that the US was "neutral" against the Spanish fascists during the 
Civil War there indicates that the US was semi-fascist?

Not quite neutral -- for instance, those who went to fight for the 
Loyalist cause got "blacklisted  labeled 'premature anti-fascists'":

*   ...In July, 1936, Italian bombers appeared in Spanish skies, 
as part of a military coup against the Republic of Spain. Hitler, 
Mussolini, Franco and the Axis powers met with impassioned resistance 
by many Spaniards and their supporters, which included German and 
Italian volunteers dubbed "Guten Cameraden." Citing a policy of 
"non-involvement", the United States and other nations refused to 
come to Spain's aid. Astonishingly, an estimated 40,000 men and women 
- from 52 countries - crossed the oceans and the Pyrenees Mountains 
to join the fight to save Spain's first democratically-elected 
government.

They became known as the International Brigades - volunteers, trained 
and untrained soldiers, nurses and comrades. The foot soldiers, the 
medical staff, and the officers were of all nations and of all 
ancestries. Women were accepted into the effort and prominently 
served in the medical brigades throughout the Civil War. In the 
spirit of solidarity, Spanish Loyalist women stood shoulder to 
shoulder with their men on the front lines during the first few 
months of the conflict.

By the time the war ended in 1939, about half of the Brigadists had 
perished. Of the 2,800 Americans collectively known as the Abraham 
Lincoln Brigade, about 1,000 were killed. Those who survived and 
returned home were blacklisted and labeled "premature anti-fascists" 
by the U.S. Government agencies and others. Nearly 60 years later, 
the Spanish Parliament voted to make all Brigadists honorary 
citizens. Ceremonies held throughout Spain in November, 1996, 
commemorated their sacrifices 
http://www.enteract.com/~juditht/hochberg/home.html   *

Yoshie




Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Brad DeLong

Shane Mage quotes Brad DeLong:

  Lots of people refused to aid or tried to harm the Loyalist cause
  during the Spanish Civil War (including, IMO, the Soviet Union--much
  more interested in smashing Trotskyism than in defeating Franco).
  IIRC, only four governments--Switzerland, Sweden, Franco's Spain, and
  Peron's Argentina--had failed to join the United Nations by the end
  of the war against Hitler.
  
  
  Brad DeLong

  You leave one not unimportant country out of your list of neutrals--
  Ireland (Eire).  Not to mention one "democratic" European country
  that was allied with the Nazis throughout virtually the entire
  war--Finland.

  Shane Mage

  "Thunderbolt steers all things."

  Herakleitos of Ephesos, fr. 64

Brad, is the correct inference that you would have supported the Loyalist
cause?

Of course.

Brad DeLong




Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Brad DeLong

Interesting that you should say this in a post that includes the title
Canada and Australia. I don't know about Australia but Canada joined the war
very early, in 1939 I believe.
   Cheers, Ken Hanly
  

Touche... All the dominions did...

Brad DeLong
-- 
J. Bradford DeLong
Professor of Economics, U.C. Berkeley
601 Evans Hall, #3880
Berkeley, CA 94720-3880
(510) 643-4027 voice
(510) 642-6615 fax
http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/
[EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-11 Thread Ken Hanly

I think most of the larger British Commonwealth countries declared war
around September 1939, at least Australia and Canada did.

Casualties:(approximate)
India 25,000
New Zealand   10,000
Canada  37,000
South Africa 7,000
Australia 23,000



 Cheers,

Ken Hanly

- Original Message -
From: Brad DeLong [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: Monday, September 11, 2000 9:53 PM
Subject: [PEN-L:1791] Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina


 Interesting that you should say this in a post that includes the title
 Canada and Australia. I don't know about Australia but Canada joined the
war
 very early, in 1939 I believe.
Cheers, Ken Hanly
   

 Touche... All the dominions did...

 Brad DeLong
 --
 J. Bradford DeLong
 Professor of Economics, U.C. Berkeley
 601 Evans Hall, #3880
 Berkeley, CA 94720-3880
 (510) 643-4027 voice
 (510) 642-6615 fax
 http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/
 [EMAIL PROTECTED]





Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-10 Thread Rob Schaap

Hi again, Nestor,

This is EXACTLY what Peronism attempted to do here, and failed. 

Funny to see again how different are things in an imperialist country 
and in a colony. In more senses than one, Peronism, which is widely 
known outside Argentina (and particularly in the United States) as a 
Fascist South American overgrowth that remained alive for a decade 
after Nazism was swept away from Europe was in fact a domestic 
version of a Labour government in Australia. In fact, one of the 
parties on which Perón built his initial electoral victory in 1946 
was the Argentinian Labour party, a party based on the workers of the 
La Plata city foreign owned meat packing and slaughterhouse 
industries.

I'm not disagreeing with anything you say, comrade, but am left wondering if
a significant difference between Australia and Argentina might not be
precisely that we did follow our masters to war.  

It certainly occasioned a massive and belated shift from the almost entirely
agricultural economy we'd been.  This at once reduced an aspect of
dependence, diversified our stock market, and made us less reliant on a
low-value staple (we were more the price taker than the price maker in our
agricultural exports).  The Pacific War (beginning with the pathetic
Singapore disaster in '42) significantly contributed to a resentful
suspicion of the UK (already in place, given the equally pathetic Gallipolli
disaster and the continued and expensive mediocrity of British general staff
on the Western Front), itself occasioning a popular desire for less
dependence on 'em - indeed a distance from them (funnily enough, many on the
left were persuading everybody we should make for Unca Sam's open arms with
expedition).  

And it made Australia's Labor Party, and a large slab of the public, look
away from the old Commonwealth in its strategic (we immediately signed some
treaties with NZ) and trade policies (even Asia copped some overtures, but
that stopped when the Tories got in).  So both the sectoral structure
(higher value production and the creation of a new and integrated national
bourgeoisie) and the political culture (self-reliance and nation-building)
of the country were very much positively affected in the context of the
times.  Not lastingly and not completely, but perhaps decisively at and for
the time.

Perhaps the ALP did not face the problems Peron faced because of the war,
then?

What say you?

Cheers,
Rob.




Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-10 Thread Jim Devine

Bill Rosenberg wrote:
New Zealand was probably more successful than Australia until the UK 
joined the EU (and both countries began to lose their
privileged access to the UK market), and less successful since then, 
showing the weakness and essentially dependent nature of its bourgeoisie.

speaking of dependency: from the point of view of the US, one crucial 
aspect of "globalization" has been the slow (but sometimes rapid) 
conversion of the US from an autocentric economy toward being a dependent, 
outward-oriented one. For example, in his book THE WORK OF NATIONS, former 
Labor Secretary Robert Reich, one of the few well-known pro-labor liberals 
(of the US sort) around, puts forth the line that the way that US workers 
can do well is by offering high-skilled labor and well-built 
infrastructure. Though his emphasis is on trade issues rather than capital 
mobility, this policy is one of "if you build it, they will come," an 
effort to woo the affections of transnational capital.  Autocentric 
policies are out. Of course, the US-based capitalist class isn't dependent 
but is instead merging into the global capitalist class (as the dominant 
partner).

However I'll relate a little anecdote which to me illustrates an important 
point: that nationalism is a danger in the imperial countries, such as the 
US and UK, but a necessity in the dependent (and would-be independent) 
ones, as long as it is not allowed to become chauvinist.

That's still a problem, despite the changes limned above. A national 
economy that's declining can spawn all sorts of reactionary ideologies. 
It's the financial and macroeconomic bubble (a.k.a. the Clinton boom) that 
has prevented the US fascist movements that were burgeoning 8 years or so 
ago from continuing their growth. That's one reason that even though I 
expect a bad recession to hit sometime in the next year or so, I don't 
welcome it: the "worse" often doesn't produce the "better" but instead a 
bunch of Brown-Shirts.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]  http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~JDevine




Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-10 Thread Brad DeLong

En relación a [PEN-L:1549] Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argen,
el 10 Sep 00, a las 3:37, Rob Schaap dijo:

  Australia, too, consciously nourished its (relative) independence,
  largely through mutually constitutive ties between Australia's
  government and bourgeoisie - ensuring that the latter would not serve
  as a compradorial local elite for foreign interests. 

This is EXACTLY what Peronism attempted to do here, and failed.

Funny to see again how different are things in an imperialist country
and in a colony. In more senses than one, Peronism, which is widely
known outside Argentina (and particularly in the United States) as a
Fascist South American overgrowth that remained alive for a decade
after Nazism was swept away from Europe was in fact a domestic
version of a Labour government in Australia...

Any Labor government--hell, *any* democratic government or *any* 
left-of-center non-democratic government--would have been eager to 
join the war against Hitler. Peron was not--hence the classification 
of his regime as "fascist South American overgrowth" seems not 
unfair...

As for Peron's social and economic policies, I have always been 
fascinated with the extraordinary economic success of post-WWII 
western Europe relative to Argentina.

At the end of the Second World War, both regions were predisposed 
toward some strict regime of economic planning. Everyone remembered 
the disastrous outcome of the laissez-faire policies that had been in 
effect at the start of the 1930s. Politicians were predisposed toward 
intervention and regulation: no matter how
damaging "government failure" might be to the economy, it had to be 
better than the "market failure" of the Depression.

Had European political economy taken a different turn, post-World War 
II European recovery might have been stagnant, as in Argentina. 
Governments might have been slow to dismantle wartime allocation 
controls, and so have severely constrained the market mechanism. In 
fact the Marshall Plan era saw a rapid dismantling of controls over 
product and factor markets in Western Europe, and the restoration of 
price and exchange rate stability.

An alternative scenario would have seen the maintenance and expansion 
of wartime controls in order to guard against substantial shifts in 
income distribution. The late 1940's and early 1950's might have seen 
the creation in Western Europe of allocative bureaucracies to ration 
scarce foreign exchange, and the imposition of price controls on 
exportables in order to protect the living standards of urban working 
classes.

The consequences of such policies can be seen by looking in the 
Argentine mirror, for they were broadly the policies adopted by 
semi-fascist dictator Juan Peron. In response to the social and 
economic upheavals of the Depression, Argentina adopted demand 
stimulation and income redistribution. These policies were coupled 
with a distrust of foreign trade and capital, and an attraction to 
the use of controls instead of prices as allocative mechanisms. In 
the post-World War II era Argentina's growth performance under these 
policies was very poor.

Carlos Díaz Alejandro's (1970) _Essays on the Economic History of the 
Argentine Republic_ provides what has become the standard analysis of 
Argentina's post-World War II relative economic stagnation. According 
to his interpretation the collapse of world trade in the Great 
Depression was a disaster of the first magnitude for an Argentina 
tightly integrated into the world division of labor. While Argentina 
continued to service its foreign debt, its trade partners took 
unilateral steps to shut it out of markets. The experience of the 
Depression justifiably undermined the nation's commitment to 
international economic integration.

In this environment Juan Perón gained enthusiastic mass political 
support. Taxes were increased, agricultural marketing boards created, 
unions supported, urban real wages boosted, international trade 
regulated. Perón sought to generate rapid growth and to twist terms 
of trade against rural agriculture and redistribute wealth to urban 
workers who did not receive their fair share. The redistribution to 
urban workers and to firms that had to pay their newly increased 
wages required a redistribution away from exporters, agricultural 
oligarchs, foreigners, and entrepreneurs.

Moreover, conservative dictatorships in Argentina during the Great 
Depression had sharpened lines of political cleavage. Landowner and 
exporter elites had always appropriated the lion's share of the 
benefits of free trade. They had in the 1930's shown a willingness to 
sacrifice political democracy in order to stunt the growth of the 
domestic welfare state. The Perónist program seemed prima facie 
reasonable given the memory of the Great Depression, and it produced 
almost half a decade of very rapid growth toward the end of the 1940s.

Then exports fell sharply as a result of the

Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-09 Thread Nestor Miguel Gorojovsky

En relación a [PEN-L:1490] Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina, 
el 8 Sep 00, a las 10:22, Bill Burgess dijo:

 
 However, by the mid 1980s the US-controlled share of all non-financial
 industres in Canada declined to levels below the post-WW2 buildup (the
 US share has risen slightly since then, as has foreign control in all
 countries).
 
 I consider this 'repatriation' partial evidence that Canadian capital
 never lost _overal_ control of the domestic economy, which they
 originally gained, as I think Paul agrees, by around WW1. Just as a
 'national bourgeoisie' was able to develop while formally still a
 British colony, it was able to survive and even gain relative strength
 despite extensive US ownership and control in _some_ industrial
 sectors. I don't think the Argentine bourgeoisie ever developed this
 kind of hegemony over the economy and state.

The Argentine bourgeoisie doesn't even have a consciousness of its 
own existence as such bourgeoisie. What we have here is an oligarchy, 
a capitalist BUT NOT BOURGEOIS ruling class, which thrives under 
imperialist control of the country and in alliance with imperialism. 
This class is ORGANICALLY against any transformation of our economic 
structure that puts in danger the chain of dependency. And the 
constitution of a self-centered bourgeoisie such as happened in 
Canada was for decades the greatest threat to its domain. Thus 
trapped between a huge working class and the imperialist-oligarchic 
"rosca" our domestic bourgeoisie is a caricature of a bourgeoisie. 
During the same 1980s that saw the Canadian bourgeoisie regain some 
degree of control of their own economy, the Argentinian bourgeoisie 
was either physiclly destroyed (Gelbard and Broner, two of the 
mainstays of Perón's national-bourgeois government after 1973 -both 
were of Marxist intelectual origin, by the way, and Gelbard, Peron's 
Minister of Economy, a secret affiliate to the Communist Party-, were 
deprived of Arg. citizenship and had to take the road of exile; 
others, like arts patron and editorial owner Vogelius, were 
kidnapped, tortured, and killed due to alleged connections with 
terrorist cells, and so on), socially degraded (it is easy to find 
taxi drivers in Buenos Aires today who have been, for example, owners 
of a small industry), transformed into managers of foreign concerns 
or turned rentiers after they closed plants or sold them (and thus 
coopted into the oligarchy), etc.

[...]

 
 Where we differ is that Paul interprets this as Canadian and
 Australian dependence a la Frank. This would be appropriate for
 Argentina, but Canada and Australia are in the qualitatively different
 position of secondary imperialist countries. They get bullied by the
 US as do other secondary imperialist countries (e.g. in Europe, by the
 US and Japan, Germany, UK, etc.) but the politics of this relationship
 are very different than the politics of Frankian-like dependency.
 
 Sorry to harp on this issue but I think the failure to distinguish
 between the two kinds of relations with bigger-power imperialism has
 long been a key failing of socialism in Canada (and I think the same
 applies to Australia and New Zealand).


I am afraid that on this issue I would agree with Bill. Whoever wants 
to discover the difference between a minor imperialist power (that 
is, a cub of shark) and a wealthy semicolony (that is, a fat tuna), 
should compare Argentina with Australia or Canada, say, by the 40s or 
50s.

A hug to all,

Néstor Miguel Gorojovsky
[EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-09 Thread Rob Schaap

Bill, Paul and Nestor are very much on to something, I think.  Australia,
too, consciously nourished its (relative) independence, largely through
mutually constitutive ties between Australia's government and bourgeoisie -
ensuring that the latter would not serve as a compradorial local elite for
foreign interests.  Straight after the war, we nationalised Cable and
Wireless's international communications monopoly (funny that, they now
control our erstwhile public telco's main competitor), nationalised QANTAS,
opposed US aspirations over sovereignty over the SW Pacific islands they had
garrisoned (the Manus group near PNG), and arrived at a cozy balance
throughout many sectors (eg aviation, broadcasting, banking, education,
insurance, health) whereby private operators got to seek profit, but
standards were regulated and ensured by public sector competition.  They
poured money and people into publicly funded universities and technical
colleges, funded mammoth immigration schemes.  

The war had also provided the impetus we needed to get a decent
manufacturing sector going, and publicly subsidised enterprise was promoted
in a new, urban Australia (proving, I guess, that Australia's rural
'squatocracy' had lost much of the political clout they'd had).  In the
bush, the Snowy Mountains hydro-electric project, a public undertaking, was
to ensure reliable and sufficient power for the manufacturing turn and
irrigation for New South Wales and Victoria.  And nearly all funded from
public debt acquired within the country.  (the domestic share of public debt
went from 50 to 77% between '39 and '50).  Taken together, all these
developments served to strengthen the infrastructural and social capital
available to domestic capital, and it had become inextricably linked with
Canberra and the State Governments.  Tariffs, quotas and subsidies were
poured into the coffers of the new manufacturer capitalists, whose fortunes
and investments depended on the government rather than Wall and Threadneedle
Streets.

Then the Tories came in on a tide of 'red under the bed' scaremongering in
1949.  The corporate state Labor had put in place throughout and immediately
after the war was not instantly to be undone though, as domestic capital
knew where its interests lay by then and Menzies conservatices (called
Liberals here) had very little interest in policy anyway, and were happy to
allow their phalanx of nation-building civil servants (all brought up during
the wise-making years of the depression) to have their way.  

Yep, it took decades to ruin all that ...

Apologies for the nationalist-Keynesian tone - but it does all sound rather
better than the particular mode of 'globalisation' currently afoot, no?

Cheers,
Rob.

 I consider this 'repatriation' partial evidence that Canadian capital
 never lost _overal_ control of the domestic economy, which they
 originally gained, as I think Paul agrees, by around WW1. Just as a
 'national bourgeoisie' was able to develop while formally still a
 British colony, it was able to survive and even gain relative strength
 despite extensive US ownership and control in _some_ industrial
 sectors. I don't think the Argentine bourgeoisie ever developed this
 kind of hegemony over the economy and state.

The Argentine bourgeoisie doesn't even have a consciousness of its 
own existence as such bourgeoisie. What we have here is an oligarchy, 
a capitalist BUT NOT BOURGEOIS ruling class, which thrives under 
imperialist control of the country and in alliance with imperialism. 
This class is ORGANICALLY against any transformation of our economic 
structure that puts in danger the chain of dependency. And the 
constitution of a self-centered bourgeoisie such as happened in 
Canada was for decades the greatest threat to its domain. Thus 
trapped between a huge working class and the imperialist-oligarchic 
"rosca" our domestic bourgeoisie is a caricature of a bourgeoisie. 
During the same 1980s that saw the Canadian bourgeoisie regain some 
degree of control of their own economy, the Argentinian bourgeoisie 
was either physiclly destroyed (Gelbard and Broner, two of the 
mainstays of Perón's national-bourgeois government after 1973 -both 
were of Marxist intelectual origin, by the way, and Gelbard, Peron's 
Minister of Economy, a secret affiliate to the Communist Party-, were 
deprived of Arg. citizenship and had to take the road of exile; 
others, like arts patron and editorial owner Vogelius, were 
kidnapped, tortured, and killed due to alleged connections with 
terrorist cells, and so on), socially degraded (it is easy to find 
taxi drivers in Buenos Aires today who have been, for example, owners 
of a small industry), transformed into managers of foreign concerns 
or turned rentiers after they closed plants or sold them (and thus 
coopted into the oligarchy), etc.

[...]

 
 Where we differ is that Paul interprets this as Canadian and
 Australian dependence a la Frank. This would be appropriate for
 

Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-09 Thread phillp2

Nestor and Bill,

Let me reiterate my main point which I take you both would either 
agree with or at least accept as a reasonable argument.  The first 
world war consolidated industrial capitalism in Canada and the 
governing elite was firmly under control of industrial capital which 
no longer had a dependence on British finance which it previously 
had.  The interwar period did not increase dependence on foreign 
capital in part because three quarters of it was marked by 
depression.  The main investment was in railways in the late 
twenties over half of which was publicly owned.

The reliance (dependence) on foreign capital, now from the US, 
came after the 2nd WW in the form of resource based investment 
and branch plant.  Because of the alarming increase in foreign 
control of the economy and the negative economic results of this 
increase, (Watkins report, Grey report, etc.) Canada introduced the 
Foreign investment Review Agency which restricted foreign 
investment where there were no direct benefit demonstrated.  Along 
with the national energy program, this had the effect of decreasing 
the proportion of foreign investment.  With the conservatives in 
power in the 80s, these national interest restrictions were lifted and 
eventually abolished with C-USFTA and NAFTA and almost 
immediately, the proportion of foreign ownership began again to 
rise.  However, Canadian foreign ownership also expanded 
representing the fact that Canada is, in its own way, a junior in the 
economic imperialism game though most of the non-resource 
investment has been in the United States and frequently in sectors 
that were originally in Canada state protected and organized 
industries (e.g. CPR and CNR railway investments). 

On the issue of dependency, my definition of dependency is quite 
different than yours and is not in the early Frank model.  I define 
dependency in terms of two or three major parametres -- the 
direction of causation, the balance of economic power and the 
expropriation of surplus.  To illustrate, the early Canadian fur trade.  
Fur was important to Canada but was miniscule to the British 
economy such that changes in fashion in hats in Europe had little 
major impact on the European economies but they could boom or 
bust the Canadian commerical economy of the day.  Changes in 
Canadian supply, however, had little or no effect on the British 
economy.  Canadian policy, such as it was, was determined by the 
London council of the HBC and the British crown which granted the 
monopoly charter.  Finally, the profits accrued to the headquarters 
of the HBC in Britain, almost none of which was reinvested in 
Canada.  This was a classic case of staple dependency which 
characterized the early economic 'development' of Canada.

Does that same dependence exist today?  Yes, though to a lesser 
extent.  Investment in Canada is largely determined by US demand 
whereas Investment in the US is minimally affected by Canadian 
demand.  Trade in Canada is a macroeconomic issue, in the US 
more of a microeconomic issue.  Research and Development, 
technological change, etc. is in most advanced industries, 
determined by foreign companies and is generally poorly developed 
(except in the state sector).  Canada's economic laws are dictated 
by the US or its international client agencies, the WTO, IMF, WB, 
NAFTA etc.  e.g. the pharmaceutical patent legislation that was 
introduced to conform to US demands which has led to an 
enormous increase in drug costs in Canada which threatens to 
collapse the medicare system.  Canada has a huge, and growing, 
net deficit in services and in payments of interest, dividends and 
profits.  Almost all of the increase in foreign ownership in Canada is 
financed either from retained profits of existing investment or from 
borrowings of Canadian savings from Canadian banks.

It is for this reason or in this context that I say the Canadian 
economy is dependent.  And I agree that this is a very different 
form of dependency that Frank argues for Latin and South America 
which is, following Baran, based on an alliance between imperial 
capital and a local landed ('feudal") and military elite who retain 
control over the domestic political spoils and block the emergence 
of a truly national-bourgeois political state.

Nas vidinje,

Paul
Paul Phillips,
Economics,
University of Manitoba

From:   "Nestor Miguel Gorojovsky" 
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Date sent:  Sat, 9 Sep 2000 11:46:48 -0300
Subject:[PEN-L:1545] Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina
Priority:   normal
Send reply to:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

 En relación a [PEN-L:1490] Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina, 
 el 8 Sep 00, a las 10:22, Bill Burgess dijo:
 
  
  However, by the mid 1980s the US-controlled share of all non-financial
  industres in Canada declined to levels below the post-WW2 buildup (the
  US share has

Re: Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-09 Thread Nestor Miguel Gorojovsky

En relación a [PEN-L:1553] Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argen, 
el 9 Sep 00, a las 12:17, [EMAIL PROTECTED] dijo:

 Nestor and Bill,
 
 Let me reiterate my main point which I take you both would either
 agree with or at least accept as a reasonable argument.  

Dear Phillip,

I do not consider myself at all in a position to contest anything 
anyone says on Canada, particularly if the such is a Canadian. What I 
tried to muse over was on the qualitative difference that obviously 
(for me, at least) exists between the Canadian dependency towards the 
United States and that of Argentina or, for that matter, Mexico. 
Probably a comparative investigation of issues at both borderlands of 
the United States would prove extraordinarily fruitful in this sense.

But, again, I am nobody to speak of Canadian issues, at least while 
they do not have a relation with Argentinian issues. I try to be 
careful in this sense.

A hug,

Néstor Miguel Gorojovsky
[EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-09 Thread Nestor Miguel Gorojovsky

En relación a [PEN-L:1553] Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argen, 
el 9 Sep 00, a las 12:17, [EMAIL PROTECTED] dijo:

 
 It is for this reason or in this context that I say the Canadian
 economy is dependent.  And I agree that this is a very different form
 of dependency that Frank argues for Latin and South America which is,
 following Baran, based on an alliance between imperial capital and a
 local landed ('feudal") and military elite who retain control over the
 domestic political spoils and block the emergence of a truly
 national-bourgeois political state.
 

Within some weeks, I intend to post on this list a criticism of 
Frank's ideas that, if I am not wrong, will make the oceans swell and 
mountains tremble.

Néstor Miguel Gorojovsky
[EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-09 Thread Nestor Miguel Gorojovsky

En relación a [PEN-L:1549] Re: Re: Re: Canada, Australia, Argen, 
el 10 Sep 00, a las 3:37, Rob Schaap dijo:

 Australia, too, consciously nourished its (relative) independence,
 largely through mutually constitutive ties between Australia's
 government and bourgeoisie - ensuring that the latter would not serve
 as a compradorial local elite for foreign interests.  

This is EXACTLY what Peronism attempted to do here, and failed. 

Funny to see again how different are things in an imperialist country 
and in a colony. In more senses than one, Peronism, which is widely 
known outside Argentina (and particularly in the United States) as a 
Fascist South American overgrowth that remained alive for a decade 
after Nazism was swept away from Europe was in fact a domestic 
version of a Labour government in Australia. In fact, one of the 
parties on which Perón built his initial electoral victory in 1946 
was the Argentinian Labour party, a party based on the workers of the 
La Plata city foreign owned meat packing and slaughterhouse 
industries.

Failure, however, must not put us in a sobering mood as to the 
achievements of Peronism (re. Jim Devine's ideas that both Peronists 
and antiPeronists were bad for Argentina). Peronists achieved great 
things, for example (and missing lots):

*an impressive redistribution of wealth that, from the point of view 
of the bourgeoisie, sought to create a domestic market; from that of 
the workers, however it gave the Argentinian worker a level of living 
that was the envy of their Latin American counterparts (thus boosting 
by the way a wave of Latin American migration into Argentina that 
partly mitigated the alienating consequences of the European inflow 
of previous decades), and opened up the road to higher education to 
the children of the working class

*a huge wave of nationalizations cut short the multiple sources of 
capital outflow through the financial, commercial and industrial 
foreign control of pre-Peronist Argentina. It is interesting in this 
sense to note that the Spanish word "extranjerización", or 
"extranjería", has no English equivalent. A whole set of political 
and economical experiences is condensed in this assimetry.

*the State took it as a task of its own to develop industrial 
concerns not only in a simple "import substitution" schema, as it had 
been the case after the 1930 crisis, but also as a conscioulsy 
directed policy of independent and self-centered economic growth; the 
plants of this new and vast system were, on the other hands, located 
outside Buenos Aires, thus injecting new life to the up to then 
decaying cities of the Inland country

And lots more (nationalization of insurance, banking, generation of 
the conditions for domestic technological advance, social 
democratization of access to University, creation of a trading fleet 
in a country that depended basically on foreign trade, management of 
the nationalized railroads to boost entire regions, massive housing 
plans, and so on).

But Peronism was limited by its attempt to develop Argentina _as just 
another capitalist country_, an attempt tragically put to light by 
Perón in his later government (1973-74) when he said that he sought 
to turn Argentina into a "World Power, an Argentina Potencia". The 
bourgeois programme proved fatal, in the end, because our ruling 
oligarchy wasn't a feudal class, but a dependent _capitalist_ ruling 
class. So that Peronism never attacked its ECONOMIC positions (you 
begin by expropriation of  large estates, where do you end?). 

But this harshly abstract comment -on which antiPeronist Leftists 
build their whole nutty edifice that sets workers abstractly apart 
from national revolution, a building that unfortunately for these 
Leftists has never been inhabited by the Argentinian working class- 
must be made more concrete, because the actual going of history is -
in a semicolony- full of unexpected events. 

It was history, not an economic predestination which made that the 
movement be in a sense doomed, because in fact it could have 
generated its own, massive and powerful, Left wing, and at the first 
moments Perón himself tried to do it.. In fact, the ultimate reason 
for this attempt to have failed is, again,  partly because of the 
stupidity of local bourgeoisie, partly because of the constraints of 
a national-bourgeois programme with overwhelming proletarian support 
under the increasing pressure of imperialism in Latin America, and 
partly because of the tragic limitations of our anti-Peronist 
(abstractly "anti capitalist" thus, when the moment of trial came 
objectivelly -and sometimes subjectivelly- proimperialist) domestic 
"Left". 

In 1945, and not because he actually needed them, but in order to 
generate a front as broad as possible to oppose the antinational bloc 
that had gathered around the unbelievable American Ambassador 
Spruille Braden, Perón offered the 

Re: Canada, Australia, Argentina

2000-09-08 Thread Bill Burgess

I agree with Paul and Nestor's point about the difference in class 
structure, and Paul's work on Canada's WW1 financing is an excellent 
illustration of the consolidation of an indigenous bourgeoisie.

Nestor, I think, has put his finger on the critical difference -- neither
Canada nor Australia had a landed elite such that the role of
Canada and Australia vs GB was one of subsidiary (dependent?)
capital vs imperial capital.  In Argentina, there was an intervening
class, the landed aristocracy. (See, for instance, Baran on this)

I have not done comparable work for Australia and Argentina, but
for Canada the turning point, in my opinion, was the 1st World
War.  In Canada's case, Britain ceased to be a creditor to Canada
because of war created debts.  Canada financed the war from
borrowing from capitalists made rich by war profiteering on
government contracts to supply GB.  After the war, the state
helped smash labour and tax the working and middle class to pay
off capital debt incurred during the war, a classic case of (marxist)
primitive accumulation. (By the way -- more shameless promotion --
  I have written a paper on this.) The railways went bankrupt and
reneged on their obligations to British bond holders. Though
borrowing shifted after the war from GB to the US, it was not until
the "American boom in Canada" after the 2nd WW that American
(direct) investment in Canada came to dominate the resourse and
manufacturing industries.

However, by the mid 1980s the US-controlled share of all non-financial 
industres in Canada declined to levels below the post-WW2 buildup (the US 
share has risen slightly since then, as has foreign control in all countries).

I consider this 'repatriation' partial evidence that Canadian capital never 
lost _overal_ control of the domestic economy, which they originally 
gained, as I think Paul agrees, by around WW1. Just as a 'national 
bourgeoisie' was able to develop while formally still a British colony, it 
was able to survive and even gain relative strength despite extensive US 
ownership and control in _some_ industrial sectors. I don't think the 
Argentine bourgeoisie ever developed this kind of hegemony over the economy 
and state.

As a well known member of Bill Burgess's detested left-nationalist
cabal, I have also argued a form of Canadian dependency.

I winced here until I remembered how Paul has written far more and better 
than I have against some forms of Canadian dependency.

All one has to do is look at the Cdn
and Australian $s and see how they dropped in parallel as
"commodity currencies" (also NZ) to realize the dependency of the
Cdn/Oz/NZ economies on the imperial centre dominated by the US
but, in Oz/NZ also the Japanese economies.  Canada has
recovered somewhat better than Ozzieland in large part because
the US economy has done much better than Japan.  Since I don't
know where Argentina's markets are dominated by, I can't
comment.  However, one common denominator is grain -- more
particularly wheat.  We are all part of the Cairns group trying to get
the US and the UE to stop subsidizing agriculture so we can sell
our grain at a decent price.  Right now our agriculture is in the
tank.  This demonstrates, I would think, a certain dependence over
which neither Canada, Australia, nor Argentina have little control.

Where we differ is that Paul interprets this as Canadian and Australian 
dependence a la Frank. This would be appropriate for Argentina, but Canada 
and Australia are in the qualitatively different position of secondary 
imperialist countries. They get bullied by the US as do other secondary 
imperialist countries (e.g. in Europe, by the US and Japan, Germany, UK, 
etc.) but the politics of this relationship are very different than the 
politics of Frankian-like dependency.

Sorry to harp on this issue but I think the failure to distinguish between 
the two kinds of relations with bigger-power imperialism has long been a 
key failing of socialism in Canada (and I think the same applies to 
Australia and New Zealand).

Bill Burgess




[PEN-L:3462] Re: Canada (Ken)

1999-02-16 Thread Tom Walker

Ken wrote,

I don't claim that. I don't speak of the revolutonary demands of the
working class.
Perhaps u could quote where I say that...All these demands are reformist.
If they
had been revolutionary the ruling class couldn't have conceded them. 

The way you put it, Ken, was ambiguous enough for me to interprete it as
actual revolutionary demands of the workers but for you to have meant it
only as some future potential demands:

Ken: "While the welfare state may have saved capital from even more radical
demands and staved off revolutionary demands, the welfare state was more or
less forced upon the ruling class. [snip] The welfare state was a great
victory for the working class."

One can "stave off" either actual or only potential demands.

In the sense that the struggle achieved these concessions it was a victory...

The argument is not (or shouldn't be) about whether something that occured
in the past was a "victory", it is about the current status of the
institutions established by that "victory". Even genuine victories have a
nasty habit of turning into idols -- this is what I call small "s" stalinism.

Some of my best friends are paid employees of "progressive organizations"
and if I let them they will whine to me incessently about how hard it is to
get those institutions to do anything actually politically progressive. They
also have a tendency to award themselves medals for continuing to fight the
good fight within their bureaucratized organizations. Those imaginary awards
for valour are above and beyond their salaries. Just try to get support from
one of those organizations to do what is at any rate a resolution approved
annually at their convention and you'll see what the anarchists mean by the
formula, talk - action = 0

Meanwhile, there always seems to be enough cash in the kitty to hold yet
another of their sparsely-attended stale donut bake sales.


  Is that an executive summary of your game plan I hope..

Yup.

regards,

Tom Walker 







[PEN-L:3457] Re: Re: Canada (Ken)

1999-02-16 Thread Ken Hanly

Ill try to be brief butTom brings up a host of issues not easily addressed in
summary form
..

Tom Walker wrote:

 If Ken will pardon my unsympathetic executive summary, I find the following
 main points in his argument (which Paul Phillips "heartfully endorses"):

 1. The Canadian welfare state was shoved down the throats of the ruling
 class by the revolutionary demands of the Canadian working class. I am merely
 claiming

I don't claim that. I don't speak of the revolutonary demands of the working class.
Perhaps u could quote where I say that...All these demands are reformist. If they
had been revolutionary the ruling class couldn't have conceded them. They just
didnt come aboutwithout struggle to force concessions from capital. In the sense
that the struggle achieved these concessions it was a victory...

 2. Government monopolies, credit unions, union control of pension funds,
 worker-owned businesses and retail and producer co-ops are a threat to capital.

 and

 3. You don't get a socialist garden by cultivating the prettiest capitalist
 weeds. This doesn't even lead you along the path to a socialist garden.

 1. Perhaps it would interest Ken to look at some of the parliamentary
 discussions and policy papers that preceded adoption of such "working class
 victories" as the Canadian Pension Plan and Unemployment Insurance. Those
 programs are the ones I am most intimately familiar with and I have no
 reservation in pointing out that "linkage" between contributions and
 benefits was and is held to be of utmost importance in keeping those
 programs essentially "market-based" and intra-class in their income
 redistributive effects. The image of a recalitrant Canadian ruling class
 capitulating to the revolutionary fervor of the workers sounds like
 something out of a 1970s maoist pipe dream of the future. But Ken is saying
 that is what actually happened in Canadian history. Show me the documents, Ken.


Again you speak of the revolutionary fervor of the workers. If only that were the
case..and I didnt mention it.. it must be a function of your excitement. I readily
admit that the CPP has all sorts of warts and no doubt was designed as you claim.
But what leftist would ever claim that reformist victories result in programmes
untainted by capitalist interests? I would mention too that you cite just one
pension plan, the CPP, which is contribution based, but thereis also the OAS plan
which is not and would cover people who are not wage laborers. There is also a
supplement for low income people.
I have a good water supply but a limited supply of documents just at hand.
Perhaps
Paul or Bill Burgess have some...

 2. and 3. Government monopolies, credit unions, worker-owned businesses and
 retail and producer coops do business with private capital every hour of
 every day. Unions are in the business of COLLECTIVE BARGAINING with
 capitalist employers. I will simply point out that Ken's positions on 2 and
 3 are contradictory. How could the institutions Ken lauds be "a threat to
 capital" if they DON'T have any criteria for distinguishing between the
 ugliest and prettiest "capitalist weeds"?

Of course they do. How could they do otherwise I would like to know. And how does
itfollow that they are not a threat to capital? If they arent a threat why would
capital dearly
like to get rid of  publicly owned unions, weaken unions, etc. Why were credit
unions for so long limited in what they could.do..Wasnt it so they could not
compete with the banks?



 4. "The game plan. I grant you the proper game plan for a revolution doesnt
 seem clear."

 I will be presenting an executive summary of the game plan on Friday. I'll
 let you know what kind of reception it gets.

 regards,

 Tom Walker

  Is that an executive summary of your game plan I hope..

Cheers, Ken Hanly






[PEN-L:3448] Re: Canada (Ken)

1999-02-16 Thread Tom Walker

If Ken will pardon my unsympathetic executive summary, I find the following
main points in his argument (which Paul Phillips "heartfully endorses"):

1. The Canadian welfare state was shoved down the throats of the ruling
class by the revolutionary demands of the Canadian working class.

2. Government monopolies, credit unions, union control of pension funds,
worker-owned businesses and retail and producer co-ops are a threat to capital.

and 

3. You don't get a socialist garden by cultivating the prettiest capitalist
weeds. This doesn't even lead you along the path to a socialist garden.

1. Perhaps it would interest Ken to look at some of the parliamentary
discussions and policy papers that preceded adoption of such "working class
victories" as the Canadian Pension Plan and Unemployment Insurance. Those
programs are the ones I am most intimately familiar with and I have no
reservation in pointing out that "linkage" between contributions and
benefits was and is held to be of utmost importance in keeping those
programs essentially "market-based" and intra-class in their income
redistributive effects. The image of a recalitrant Canadian ruling class
capitulating to the revolutionary fervor of the workers sounds like
something out of a 1970s maoist pipe dream of the future. But Ken is saying
that is what actually happened in Canadian history. Show me the documents, Ken.

2. and 3. Government monopolies, credit unions, worker-owned businesses and
retail and producer coops do business with private capital every hour of
every day. Unions are in the business of COLLECTIVE BARGAINING with
capitalist employers. I will simply point out that Ken's positions on 2 and
3 are contradictory. How could the institutions Ken lauds be "a threat to
capital" if they DON'T have any criteria for distinguishing between the
ugliest and prettiest "capitalist weeds"?

4. "The game plan. I grant you the proper game plan for a revolution doesnt
seem clear."

I will be presenting an executive summary of the game plan on Friday. I'll
let you know what kind of reception it gets.

regards,

Tom Walker 







[PEN-L:3374] Re: Canada

1999-02-15 Thread Bill Burgess

At 06:20 PM 13/02/99 -0800, Tom W. wrote:

There's one point that I would differ with Bill on. 

I agree that left nationalists have offered a lot of tactical advice. But I
think "fighting" the bourgeoisie is too pugilistic and indiscriminate a term
for what the left should be doing. The left should be "cultivating" the
bourgeoisie. By this term, I mean the left should figuring out how to weed
out the parasitic varieties; and how best to select, tend, prune, train and
harvest the fruitful ones.

OK, "fighting" is a crude term. But how can the 'left' "select, prune,
train" and especially "harvest" without political power? Or do you have in
mind some kind of tactical alliance with the most promising capitalist
plants against the bourgeois weeds and deadwood? The NBER study suggests
the latter are the family-controlled corporate pyramids, so I guess this
alliance is exactly opposite to the one you said the left has beein
pursuing in the last couple of decades with 'rentier' capitalism. Boy, that
really is swimming against the stream! 

On a related point, I appreciate not wanting to identify "indigneous"
capitalists with the interest of the nation, but isn't the real point that
they identify with the Canadian state because it defends their interests at
home and abroad? Canadian nationalists often suggest the government has
been captured by foreign or 'continental' or 'global' capital, but what is
the evidence for this?

Bill 






[PEN-L:3390] Re: Canada

1999-02-15 Thread michael

I confess that I think that the NBER paper that Doug brought to our
attention might be on to something.  I remember a time almost 20 years ago
that I visited Toronto for the first time.  I did not see much poverty.
The city seemed very well run.  Maybe I was naive, but it seemed a stark
contrast from the US.

I recall reading some papers around that time about the kind of
concentrated ownership that Canada had.  It seemed that the Canadian
capitalists were far more enlightened that the U.S. capitalists.  Canada
seemed to evoke the Business Week version of capitalism rather than the
more Hobbesian Wall Street Journal version.

Since then, Canada has fallen under the sway of a more U.S. verion of
capital and is paying the price -- at least some are.
 -- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]






[PEN-L:3398] Re: Canada (Bill)

1999-02-15 Thread Tom Walker

Bill Burgess wrote,

OK, "fighting" is a crude term. But how can the 'left' "select, prune,
train" and especially "harvest" without political power? Or do you have in
mind some kind of tactical alliance with the most promising capitalist
plants against the bourgeois weeds and deadwood? The NBER study suggests
the latter are the family-controlled corporate pyramids, so I guess this
alliance is exactly opposite to the one you said the left has beein
pursuing in the last couple of decades with 'rentier' capitalism. Boy, that
really is swimming against the stream! 

I wouldn't suggest for a moment that a different strategy would be easier.
But to continue your metaphor, if the left wants to spawn, it's going to
have to _learn_ to swim against the stream.

regards,

Tom Walker 







[PEN-L:3399] Re: Canada (Doug)

1999-02-15 Thread Tom Walker

Doug Henwood wrote,

Here's an idea - social democracy is more compatible with "monopolized"
ownership structures than most social democrats would like to admit, and is
undermined by U.S.-style financial and corporate governance arrangements.
It's probably very difficult for U.S. social dems to admit to this, given
this country's love of small business and populist, anti-centralizing
political traditions.

Doug's idea is right on the (Bis)mark.

regards,

Tom Walker 







[PEN-L:3403] Re: RE: Re: Re: Canada

1999-02-15 Thread Peter Dorman

Well yes, but not exactly.  Example: the Lander banks in Germany.  These
are publicly owned at the state level and make loans to local small
businesses.  They play an important role in the social market model--and
the EU (or some elements therein) wants to abolish them.

By the way, this is a very important topic.

Peter Dorman

Max Sawicky wrote:
 
 
  Here's an idea - social democracy is more compatible with "monopolized"
  ownership structures than most social democrats would like to
  admit, and is
  undermined by U.S.-style financial and corporate governance arrangements.
  It's probably very difficult for U.S. social dems to admit to this, given
  this country's love of small business and populist, anti-centralizing
  political traditions.
 
 Financial and corporate governance arrangements can be
 quite different in this context.
 
 In the latter case, monopoly mitigates the imperative of
 profit maximization per se.  In this realm, I think you
 are right that social democracy has an interest in seeking
 collaborationist arrangements with corporations, which I
 would say can be either good or bad for workers.
 
 Liberalizing financial arrangements are a whole different
 matter and would seem to be the real challenge to social
 democracy.  We see that under neo-liberalism, social
 democracy either caves in and transforms to Clintonism
 (e.g., U.S., perhaps Australia/New Zealand, UK), or
 is forced into a more antagonistic posture.
 
 The indifference to localism, populism, and anti-
 centralism is generic not only to social-democracy,
 but to much of the left as well.  My impression is
 that these traditions have much less currency in
 Europe so there is nothing to neglect.
 
 mbs






[PEN-L:3418] Re: Re: Re: Canada (Doug)

1999-02-15 Thread Michael Perelman



Damn it, Ken Hanly.  Stop popping my bubbles.  I used to be very impressed with what
I saw in Canada.  Why then did it lack the mean streak that I see on this side of
the border?  Did I miss something?

Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Chico, CA 95929
530-898-5321
fax 530-898-5901






[PEN-L:3427] Re: Re: Re: Canada (Ken)

1999-02-15 Thread ts99u-1.cc.umanitoba.ca [130.179.154.224]

Date sent:  Mon, 15 Feb 1999 22:28:24 -0600
From:   Ken Hanly [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Send reply to:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject:[PEN-L:3424] Re: Re: Canada (Ken)


Now here is something I can agree with and heartfully endorse.  
Traditionally the social democrats have relied on regulation of 
capital as their method of  control.  This is why foreign ownership 
was so difficult -- it put capital beyond their regulatory grasp -- but 
also made foreign ownership an important issue (as it still is).  
Ken, however,  has laid out the issue succinctly.

 I don't think that it is altogether true that social welfare programs were
 brought in
 to serve contingent ruling class interests. If that were so why did the ruling
 class consistently oppose progressive measures every step of the way? Minimum
 wages, UI and improvements to it, pensions, closed shop legislation, pay equity,
 you name it. While the welfare state
 may have saved capital from even more radical demands and staved off
 revolutionary demands, the welfare state was more or less forced upon the ruling
 class. Surely Capital railed against the welfare state, and enlisted all its
 legions of flacks and PR people to try to
 defeat those promoting the welfare state every step of the way. The welfare
 state was a
 great victory for the working class.
 The ruling class didnt suddenly decide they didnt need the welfare state any
 more--although the
 disintegration of actually existing socialism may have been a factor in
 precipating the assault
 against the welfare state. In my view the welfare state was a feature of the
 Social Structures
 of Accumulation of what has been called the Golden Age of Capitalism...
 Burgeoning debt,
  problems in maintaining adequate levels of capital accumulation, plus many
 other factors
 such as increased global competition among capitals, the growth of the Asian
 tigers, etc.
 led to Capital's forceful attack on the welfare state.
 You are right the constellation of class forces has changed in that
 global capital
 has the upper hand at them moment. However, not all struggles against cutbacks
 and attacks
 by capital have failed. If anything the greatest failure has been with social
 democratic parties
 who have sacrificed any pretense of being the leaders in the counter-atttack
 against global
 capital and are bending over backwards to show that they are "responsible" i.e.
 they will
 kiss corporate ass just as well as any old-line party or as in the UK and NZ and
 I guess OZ too
 actually leading the way for global capitalism.
 The welfare state is not gone. Its reduced. If there had been no
 struggle the situation would be much worse than it. The left may think that all
 is lost but the right knows damn well that the welfare state is still popular.
 There are plenty of aging conservative voters in
 Manitoba. Prior to an election here the Conservatives are pumping money back
 into our health care system--after savage cuts of course. They know, and the
 polls show them this,
 that people want the health care system and want it improved. While the social
 democrats
 in power in the province next door refuse to pay nurses a decent wage and do
 away entirely with the provincial pharamacare plan, the Conservative govt. in
 Manitoba is pumping
 more money into the system and contented itself with raising the kick-in limits
 in the pharamacare plan.
 The game plan. I grant you the proper game plan for a revolution doesnt
 seem clear.
 At least in advanced capitalist societies, revolution doesnt seem to be on the
 agenda for the moment. This doesn't mean that capital cannot be opposed though.
 I will
 concentrate upon issues not specifically directed to gay and lesbian rights,
 aboriginal or race
 issues, or the quesion of  separatism.
 Oppose privatisation of all kinds. Some opposition to privatisation has
 been successful
 and any widespread opposition will make governments provincial or otherwise to
 think twice
 about trying it. Although provincial govt. here privatised the provincial phone
 company there
 was a great deal of opposition and the govt. lost a lot of support. They have
 not moved to privatise
 Manitoba Hydro or the auto insurance monopoly.
 Privatisation of hte phone company gave  a perfect opportunity for the
 NDP to have as a plank that they would take the phone company back into the
 public sector. If they have such a plank, they certainly
 have been mighty quiet about it. The NDP should be pressing for privatised firms
 to be taken back into the public sector. Again no bloody leadership, rather the
 NDP goes with the flow
 doing some privatisation itself as in Saskatchewan where the public road
 construction sector
 was privatised. In Saskatchewan though there is still a publicly owned bus
 company providing service throughout the province. SaskPower still co

[PEN-L:3424] Re: Re: Canada (Ken)

1999-02-15 Thread Ken Hanly

I don't think that it is altogether true that social welfare programs were
brought in
to serve contingent ruling class interests. If that were so why did the ruling
class consistently oppose progressive measures every step of the way? Minimum
wages, UI and improvements to it, pensions, closed shop legislation, pay equity,
you name it. While the welfare state
may have saved capital from even more radical demands and staved off
revolutionary demands, the welfare state was more or less forced upon the ruling
class. Surely Capital railed against the welfare state, and enlisted all its
legions of flacks and PR people to try to
defeat those promoting the welfare state every step of the way. The welfare
state was a
great victory for the working class.
The ruling class didnt suddenly decide they didnt need the welfare state any
more--although the
disintegration of actually existing socialism may have been a factor in
precipating the assault
against the welfare state. In my view the welfare state was a feature of the
Social Structures
of Accumulation of what has been called the Golden Age of Capitalism...
Burgeoning debt,
 problems in maintaining adequate levels of capital accumulation, plus many
other factors
such as increased global competition among capitals, the growth of the Asian
tigers, etc.
led to Capital's forceful attack on the welfare state.
You are right the constellation of class forces has changed in that
global capital
has the upper hand at them moment. However, not all struggles against cutbacks
and attacks
by capital have failed. If anything the greatest failure has been with social
democratic parties
who have sacrificed any pretense of being the leaders in the counter-atttack
against global
capital and are bending over backwards to show that they are "responsible" i.e.
they will
kiss corporate ass just as well as any old-line party or as in the UK and NZ and
I guess OZ too
actually leading the way for global capitalism.
The welfare state is not gone. Its reduced. If there had been no
struggle the situation would be much worse than it. The left may think that all
is lost but the right knows damn well that the welfare state is still popular.
There are plenty of aging conservative voters in
Manitoba. Prior to an election here the Conservatives are pumping money back
into our health care system--after savage cuts of course. They know, and the
polls show them this,
that people want the health care system and want it improved. While the social
democrats
in power in the province next door refuse to pay nurses a decent wage and do
away entirely with the provincial pharamacare plan, the Conservative govt. in
Manitoba is pumping
more money into the system and contented itself with raising the kick-in limits
in the pharamacare plan.
The game plan. I grant you the proper game plan for a revolution doesnt
seem clear.
At least in advanced capitalist societies, revolution doesnt seem to be on the
agenda for the moment. This doesn't mean that capital cannot be opposed though.
I will
concentrate upon issues not specifically directed to gay and lesbian rights,
aboriginal or race
issues, or the quesion of  separatism.
Oppose privatisation of all kinds. Some opposition to privatisation has
been successful
and any widespread opposition will make governments provincial or otherwise to
think twice
about trying it. Although provincial govt. here privatised the provincial phone
company there
was a great deal of opposition and the govt. lost a lot of support. They have
not moved to privatise
Manitoba Hydro or the auto insurance monopoly.
Privatisation of hte phone company gave  a perfect opportunity for the
NDP to have as a plank that they would take the phone company back into the
public sector. If they have such a plank, they certainly
have been mighty quiet about it. The NDP should be pressing for privatised firms
to be taken back into the public sector. Again no bloody leadership, rather the
NDP goes with the flow
doing some privatisation itself as in Saskatchewan where the public road
construction sector
was privatised. In Saskatchewan though there is still a publicly owned bus
company providing service throughout the province. SaskPower still controls gas
and electricity. The auto insurance industry is still public.
Retail and producer co-ops should be supported as well as Credit Unions.
Neo-liberalism hasnt destroyed these. They are thriving at least in Manitoba and
Saskatchewan. Indeed, Credit Unions can capitalise upon banks' attempts to
downsize and add on various fees for services. I havent used a bank for years.
The left in Canada had
a well-organised and successful campaign to block a major bank merger. A waste
of time.
Let them merge and cut back branches and get credit unions to fill the gap. At a
conference
I was at there was paper given by two guys who made a living showing businesses
how to
profit when competitors restructure and downsize. They 

[PEN-L:3420] Re: Canada (Ken)

1999-02-15 Thread Tom Walker

I understand there were Social Democrats in late 19th century Germany, too.
I do not mean to push the comparison, other than in the sense that not all
welfare state programs are manna from heaven. They are brought in to serve
contigent ruling class interests (in response to popular pressure, of
course) but it is rather feeble to defend the welfare state in retrospect as
a great workers' victory once the ruling class has decided it doesn't need
them anymore. The bourgies are telling us, by their deeds not their words,
that the constellation of class forces has changed. Our bleak experience in
opposing the social program cuts confirms what the bourgies are telling us.
So what's the game plan?

regards,

Tom Walker 







[PEN-L:3419] Re: Canada (Michael)

1999-02-15 Thread Tom Walker

Michael Perelman wrote,

Damn it, Ken Hanly.  Stop popping my bubbles.  I used to be very impressed
with what
I saw in Canada.  Why then did it lack the mean streak that I see on this
side of
the border?  Did I miss something?


Yeah. Maybe you should have visited some place like Davis Inlet or Mount
Currie or Alkali Lake.

regards,

Tom Walker 







[PEN-L:3415] Re: Re: Canada (Doug)

1999-02-15 Thread Ken Hanly

 There has never been a social democratic government in power in Canada at the
Federal
Level. Except for the Rae govt. in Ontario. most provincial social democratic
govts have not been in the area of Canada where the wealthy inheritor firms
are...Ontario,  and the Maritimes
Irvine and McCains, but in the west.
Heir controlled firms are noted for their anti-labor stance and support
for conservative and protectionist policies.
It is true that both capital and the general public are (or were) much
less worried about big government than US citizens. Social democratic
governments in the provinces embrace not monopoly ownership per se but
government monopoly as in the medicare first promoted in Saskatchewan and
eventually adopted federally, or in the auto insurance programmes, govt.
monopolies in Saskatchewan first, and now in BC. and Manitoba. all put in place
by social democratic regimes. The hydro companies in Saskatchewan and Manitoba,
govt. monopolies, WHeat Board monopoly trading in selected grains.. but this has
nothing to do with old heir capital. Those old farts are aghast at all these
things.. Both people and old heir capital look to govt. to advance their
interests and protect them from international capital and the vagaries of the
market. So we have or had, all sorts of different boards meant to control
production chicken boards, milk board, etc. all meant to ensure producers a
reasonable return and of course quite counter to free markets.
These policies were not implemented by some fatherly Bismarck. THey were
implemented
because popular movements lobbied for these things, and social democrats had
them as planks in their platform. They would not have been elected and
re-elected if they had not
followed these policies. Some of these policies were adopted by Liberal and
Conservative Federal Regimes because they were scared skinny that the social
democrats might win power
federally..Nothing like the autocratic social programmes of Bismarck.
I seem to recall looking at statistics that show that Canadian voters
participate less in
local elections more in Provincial elections and more still in Federal
Elections--this may not
hold for Quebec. The opposite is the case in the US. In municipal elections here
unless they really do something stupid or a big issue comes up councillors often
remain unopposed or win hands down.
By the way the Bronfman trust case mentioned by someone earlier is not
settled yet.
A taxpayer got a Manitoba lawyer Arne Pelz to file suit in court to force the
Bronfman trust
to pay taxes on the several billion dollars transferred to the US to avoid
taxation. Every 20 years these trusts are assessed for taxation as if they had
been sold and the capital gain is
taxed. The Bronfman's tried to move the fund to the US to avoid this. IN order
to do this
they attempted to have the transaction exempted under a provision that is meant
to apply
to US funds coming into Canada!! The exemption was at first denied. Then later
this was
overruled. Someones head should roll. The court case will claim that Revenue
Canada did
not follow its own rules. Should be very interesting.. This is  your typical
heir capital.
Other great heir capitalists live in the Bahamas((or maybe Bermuda)) because
Canada is such a high tax socialist country. We owe nothing to these people but
our chains.

Cheers, Ken Hanly

Tom Walker wrote:

 Doug Henwood wrote,

 Here's an idea - social democracy is more compatible with "monopolized"
 ownership structures than most social democrats would like to admit, and is
 undermined by U.S.-style financial and corporate governance arrangements.
 It's probably very difficult for U.S. social dems to admit to this, given
 this country's love of small business and populist, anti-centralizing
 political traditions.

 Doug's idea is right on the (Bis)mark.

 regards,

 Tom Walker







[PEN-L:3396] Re: Re: Re: Canada

1999-02-15 Thread Jim Devine

Doug writes: Here's an idea - social democracy is more compatible with
"monopolized"
ownership structures than most social democrats would like to admit, and is
undermined by U.S.-style financial and corporate governance arrangements.
It's probably very difficult for U.S. social dems to admit to this, given
this country's love of small business and populist, anti-centralizing
political traditions.

I agree: if firms have more monopoly power (including more insulation from
international trade competition), they are more able to make concessions to
labor and the like. 

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
http://clawww.lmu.edu/Faculty/JDevine/jdevine.html






[PEN-L:3394] RE: Re: Re: Canada

1999-02-15 Thread Max Sawicky

 
 Here's an idea - social democracy is more compatible with "monopolized"
 ownership structures than most social democrats would like to 
 admit, and is
 undermined by U.S.-style financial and corporate governance arrangements.
 It's probably very difficult for U.S. social dems to admit to this, given
 this country's love of small business and populist, anti-centralizing
 political traditions.

Financial and corporate governance arrangements can be
quite different in this context.

In the latter case, monopoly mitigates the imperative of
profit maximization per se.  In this realm, I think you
are right that social democracy has an interest in seeking
collaborationist arrangements with corporations, which I
would say can be either good or bad for workers.

Liberalizing financial arrangements are a whole different
matter and would seem to be the real challenge to social
democracy.  We see that under neo-liberalism, social
democracy either caves in and transforms to Clintonism
(e.g., U.S., perhaps Australia/New Zealand, UK), or
is forced into a more antagonistic posture.

The indifference to localism, populism, and anti-
centralism is generic not only to social-democracy,
but to much of the left as well.  My impression is
that these traditions have much less currency in
Europe so there is nothing to neglect.

mbs






[PEN-L:3393] Re: Re: Re: Canada

1999-02-15 Thread michael

I absolutely agree with what Doug said below, which is what I was hinting
at.
 Here's an idea - social democracy is more compatible with "monopolized"
 ownership structures than most social democrats would like to admit, and is
 undermined by U.S.-style financial and corporate governance arrangements.
 It's probably very difficult for U.S. social dems to admit to this, given
 this country's love of small business and populist, anti-centralizing
 political traditions.
 
 Doug
 
 


-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]






[PEN-L:3392] Re: Re: Canada

1999-02-15 Thread Doug Henwood

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

I confess that I think that the NBER paper that Doug brought to our
attention might be on to something.  I remember a time almost 20 years ago
that I visited Toronto for the first time.  I did not see much poverty.
The city seemed very well run.  Maybe I was naive, but it seemed a stark
contrast from the US.

I recall reading some papers around that time about the kind of
concentrated ownership that Canada had.  It seemed that the Canadian
capitalists were far more enlightened that the U.S. capitalists.  Canada
seemed to evoke the Business Week version of capitalism rather than the
more Hobbesian Wall Street Journal version.

Here's an idea - social democracy is more compatible with "monopolized"
ownership structures than most social democrats would like to admit, and is
undermined by U.S.-style financial and corporate governance arrangements.
It's probably very difficult for U.S. social dems to admit to this, given
this country's love of small business and populist, anti-centralizing
political traditions.

Doug






[PEN-L:3338] Re: Canada

1999-02-13 Thread Bill Burgess


Paul Phillips wrote about one claim of the NBER paper on Canada: 

This strikes me as odd because Canada has a higher proportion of 
foreign investment than any other industrial country I believe.

Yes, inward FDI is high in Canada. But it is even *higher* in the U.K.,
Netherlands, and Australia, if measured by FDI stock over GDP in 1994,
according to OECD data. 

It is past time the left dropped the nationalist fixation on foreign
ownership in Canada. Ken Hanley provided a great parody of the preposterous
regression method in the NBER study, but the study does make some points we
should pay more attention to. For example, Ken wrote:  

The relative weakness of R  D may be partly explained by the fact that
a great deal of our industry is branch plants of US and other foreign
investors. The R and D takes place mainly
in the home base country often the US, not in the branch plants.

In fact, the NBER paper offers evidence that it is Canadian heir-controlled
firms that do relatively little R and D. I don't know how much a "great
deal of our industry" is, but US control of corporate assets in all
non-financial industries in Canada was only 15.9% in 1995, and 11.4% of
corporate assets in all industries, according to Statistics Canada. In
1993, total foreign control of assets of the largest 25 enterprises in
Canada was only 3.6%. 

I know Ken said the weakness of R and D is only "partly" explained by US
branch plants, but I think the NBER paper shows we need to spend more time
talking about Canadian finance capital and less about the foreign boogyman.
 I've quoted these figures before on Pen-l, and I am admittedly dense, but
I don't think my claim that US control in Canada is usually exaggerated has
been refuted. 

Ken asked what the NBER study meant by rent-seeking behavior. I only
skimmed the paper, but it seems to be the usual argument - family-contolled
firms use their power to rip off other shareholders and close connections
to government to gain preferential regulation. On the latter they cite the
example of how the Bronfman family were allowed to transfer $2 billion in
family wealth to the U.S. in 1991 without paying tax on capital gains,
something even the Auditor General questioned publicly. 

One of their main points is the widespread 'pyramiding' of corporate
ownership in Canada. They point out that unlike in the U.S., companies in
Canada do not pay tax on dividends received from other firms they own. They
argue that corporate pyramids promote transfer pricing, preferential
financing, barriers to entry, etc. It actually reminded me of the good old
left-wing rhetoric about how Canada is run by "50 big shots". Until the
1960s when nationalism took hold, we generally understood (IMHO correctly)
that the real problem is these home-grown capitalists, not foreigners. 
   
(Ken also wondered if the NBER paper was referring to "toothless review
mechanisms for foreign investment" when they associated less openness to
foreign investment with large heir wealth. The study used someone else's
evaluation of Canada's relative openess to foreign investment, and I didn't
see any description of the latter's criteria, but one would expect it would
include the full range of issues. The study's comparison was for 1988,
before the FTA, but well after the toothless Trudeau-era Foreign Investment
Review Agency was morphed into Investment Canada, whose mandate is to
actually "promote" foreign investment.) 

Tom Walker argues that the problem with left perspectives is the failure to
recongize the 

predominantly
rentier nature of "indigenous" Canadian capitalism.

"Rentier" here sounds like it could be super-centralized, super-rich
family-dominated organization of capitalism the NBER paper not
innappropriately calls the "Canadian disease". If so, I agree with both,
but I prefer the old fashioned 'finance capital', and I don't see why Tom
is shy about calling it indigenous. 

Unfortunately, there is also some truth in Tom Walker's suggestion that

The Canadian left has now reduced itself
to whining incessently for a return to an implicit bargain with the big
brother rentiers.
 
I don't think there ever was a real 'bargain' with big brother rentiers,
and Ken is right that the left a-la-social democracy is now outdoing itself
to prove it is fiscally responsible. But left-nationalists have spent a lot
of time over the past couple of decades offering tactical tactical advice
on how to be a  better bourgeoisie - invest more in R and D, become more
competitive in world markets, etc., instead of figuring how to fight the
bourgeoisie. Maude Barlow and the Council of Canadians is more of the same
pie in the sky. 

Bill Burgess







[PEN-L:3316] Re: Canada

1999-02-12 Thread Tom Walker

Doug Henwood asked,

Any experts on Canada want to comment?

"Inherited Wealth, Corporate Control and Economic Growth: The
 Canadian Disease"

I don't know if this makes me an "expert on Canada", but I was on the radio
this morning debating the four-day week with the vice president of the B.C.
Business Council, so at least somebody *in* Canada thinks I'm an expert on
something.

My debating point with Jock Finlayson is relevant to the question of the
Canadian Disease and the implicit prescription of Capital market openness.
Get ready for this one Pen-lers, because it's a curve ball that you might
not see sneak across the plate. My argument for the four-day week is/was and
will be based on grounds of efficiency and competitiveness, not kindness and
compassion. Orthodox Marxism-Taylorism-Fordism-Keynesianism-Nylandism.

Here's how it plays: long hours of work and high unemployment impose a tax
on efficient, well managed firms and their employees and provide a subsidy
to inefficient, poorly managed firms and their employees. The result is
aggregate levels of output, productivity and employment lower than would be
the case with shorter hours of work. That's Canada. The payroll tax
structure in Canada couldn't have been better designed to subsidize poor
management and penalize good management. It is the most regressive in the OECD.

Large, chronic labour market surpluses create a moral hazard for firms to
buy labour power at less than its cost of production, use it inefficiently
and pass on the costs of doing so to society. In Canada, this moral hazard
is enshrined as a cardinal virtue. 

And don't get me going on the Canadian labour movement and Canadian left's
response to what Morck and colleagues call the Canadian disease: with
friends like that, who needs enemies.
 
Without addressing the absence of intra-firm labour market competition in
Canada -- that is to say without a full-employment policy -- capital market
openness is only about rearranging the deck chairs on the titanic. The smart
money might well flee, but there's still nothing in it to discipline the
stupid money.


"Inherited Wealth, Corporate Control and Economic Growth: The
 Canadian Disease"

  BY:  RANDALL MORCK
  University of Alberta
   DAVID A. STANGELAND
  University of Manitoba
  Department of Accounting  Finance
   BERNARD YIN YEUNG
  University of Michigan

Paper ID:  National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper
   No. 6814
Date:  November 1998

 Contact:  RANDALL MORCK
   Email:  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
  Postal:  University of Alberta
   Edmonton T6G 2R6, Alberta   CANADA
   Phone:  (780)492-5683
 Fax:  (780)492-3325
 Co-Auth:  DAVID A. STANGELAND
   Email:  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
  Postal:  University of Manitoba
   Department of Accounting  Finance
   Faculty of Management
   Winnipeg, MB   CANADA, R3T 5V4
 Co-Auth:  BERNARD YIN YEUNG
   Email:  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
  Postal:  University of Michigan
   701 Tappan Street
   Ann Arbor, MI 48109-1234  USA

Paper Requests:
 Full-Text Availability at http://www.nber.org/wwp.html Papers
 can be downloaded online for $5. Hard copies are $10 plus
 $10.00/order outside the USA. Prepayment required. NBER orders:
 Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED] Checks, Mastercard, Visa and American
 Express to 1050 Massachusetts Ave., Cambridge, MA 02138.
 Phone:(617)868-3900. Fax:(617)349-3955. For NBER Subscriptions
 Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED] or write to "Subscriptions" at address
 above.

ABSTRACT:
 Countries in which billionaire heirs' wealth is large relative
 to G.D.P. grow more slowly, show signs of more political
 rent-seeking, and spend less on innovation than do other
 countries at similar levels of development. In contrast,
 countries in which self-made entrepreneur billionaire wealth is
 large relative to G.D.P. grow more rapidly and show fewer signs
 of rent seeking.

 We argue that this is consistent with wealthy entrenched
 families having objectives other than creating public
 shareholder value. Also, the control pyramids through which they
 are entrenched give wealthy families preferential access to
 capital and enhanced lobbying power. Entrenched families also
 have a vested interest in preserving the value of existing
 capital. To investigate these arguments, we use firm-level
 Canadian data and cross country data. Heir-controlled Canadian
 firms show lower industry-adjusted financial performance, labor
 capital ratios, and RD than other firms of the same ages and
 sizes. Cross country data show that countries with more
 billionaire heirs' wealth are less open to inward foreign direct
 investment and have lower private-sector RD spending.

 We argue that concentrated, inherited corporate control
 impedes growth, and dub this "the Canadian disease." Further
 research is needed to determine the international incidence of
 this condition.

 Finally, 

[PEN-L:3313] Re: Re: Canada

1999-02-12 Thread Ken Hanly

  Just to add to Paul's suggestions:
As Paul notes there is a large proportion of foreign investment
in Canada. Perhaps
they are referring to the relalitively toothless review mechanisms for
foreign investment.
The relative weakness of R  D may be partly explained by the fact that
a great deal of our industry is branch plants of US and other foreign
investors. The R and D takes place mainly
in the home base country often the US, not in the branch plants.
  The whole exercise though is a piece of sophisticated crap,...


Lets do  the same thing and find the correlation between the two and
levels of unionization,
degree of health care coverage...strength of social safety net. Couldn't
we come up with
an American disease
I suppose if there is anything positive in this, it is that we
should introduce hefty
estate taxes to be spent to enhance public programmes since obviously
left in the hands of
heirs, capital doesn't function very well. Is that what the study
concludes :)

   Cheers, Ken Hanly
P.S What rent seeking behavior are the authors talking about?

Paul Phillips wrote:

 Doug,
 I wonder if they standardized for industry.  Many of the heir
 controlled firms that I can think of are in old 'traditional'
 industries.  (They have to be relatively old to be heir-controlled.)
 If they didn't, this could explain a lot of what they found.

 But:
  Cross country data show that countries with more
   billionaire heirs' wealth are less open to inward foreign direct
   investment and have lower private-sector RD spending.

 This strikes me as odd because Canada has a higher proportion of
 foreign investment than any other industrial country I believe.

 Paul
 Paul Phillips,
 Economics,
 Universityof Manitoba

  Date:  Fri, 12 Feb 1999 10:22:37 -0500
  To:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
  From:  Doug Henwood [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  Subject:   [PEN-L:3298] Canada
  Reply-to:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  Any experts on Canada want to comment?
 
  "Inherited Wealth, Corporate Control and Economic Growth: The
   Canadian Disease"
  
BY:  RANDALL MORCK
University of Alberta
 DAVID A. STANGELAND
University of Manitoba
Department of Accounting  Finance
 BERNARD YIN YEUNG
University of Michigan
  
  Paper ID:  National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper
 No. 6814
  Date:  November 1998
  
   Contact:  RANDALL MORCK
 Email:  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Postal:  University of Alberta
 Edmonton T6G 2R6, Alberta   CANADA
 Phone:  (780)492-5683
   Fax:  (780)492-3325
   Co-Auth:  DAVID A. STANGELAND
 Email:  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Postal:  University of Manitoba
 Department of Accounting  Finance
 Faculty of Management
 Winnipeg, MB   CANADA, R3T 5V4
   Co-Auth:  BERNARD YIN YEUNG
 Email:  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Postal:  University of Michigan
 701 Tappan Street
 Ann Arbor, MI 48109-1234  USA
  
  Paper Requests:
   Full-Text Availability at http://www.nber.org/wwp.html Papers
   can be downloaded online for $5. Hard copies are $10 plus
   $10.00/order outside the USA. Prepayment required. NBER orders:
   Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED] Checks, Mastercard, Visa and American
   Express to 1050 Massachusetts Ave., Cambridge, MA 02138.
   Phone:(617)868-3900. Fax:(617)349-3955. For NBER Subscriptions
   Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED] or write to "Subscriptions" at address
   above.
  
  ABSTRACT:
   Countries in which billionaire heirs' wealth is large relative
   to G.D.P. grow more slowly, show signs of more political
   rent-seeking, and spend less on innovation than do other
   countries at similar levels of development. In contrast,
   countries in which self-made entrepreneur billionaire wealth is
   large relative to G.D.P. grow more rapidly and show fewer signs
   of rent seeking.
  
   We argue that this is consistent with wealthy entrenched
   families having objectives other than creating public
   shareholder value. Also, the control pyramids through which they
   are entrenched give wealthy families preferential access to
   capital and enhanced lobbying power. Entrenched families also
   have a vested interest in preserving the value of existing
   capital. To investigate these arguments, we use firm-level
   Canadian data and cross country data. Heir-controlled Canadian
   firms show lower industry-adjusted financial performance, labor
   capital ratios, and RD than other firms of the same ages and
   sizes. Cross country data show that countries with more
   billionaire heirs' wealth are less open to inward foreign direct
   investment and have lower private-sector RD spending.
  
   We argue that concentrated, inherited corporate control
   impedes growth, and dub this "the Canadian disease." Further
   research is needed to determine the international incidence of
   this 

[PEN-L:3302] Re: Canada

1999-02-12 Thread Paul Phillips

Doug,
I wonder if they standardized for industry.  Many of the heir 
controlled firms that I can think of are in old 'traditional' 
industries.  (They have to be relatively old to be heir-controlled.) 
If they didn't, this could explain a lot of what they found.

But:
 Cross country data show that countries with more
  billionaire heirs' wealth are less open to inward foreign direct
  investment and have lower private-sector RD spending.

This strikes me as odd because Canada has a higher proportion of 
foreign investment than any other industrial country I believe.

Paul
Paul Phillips,
Economics,
Universityof Manitoba

 Date:  Fri, 12 Feb 1999 10:22:37 -0500
 To:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
 From:  Doug Henwood [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject:   [PEN-L:3298] Canada
 Reply-to:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

 Any experts on Canada want to comment?
 
 "Inherited Wealth, Corporate Control and Economic Growth: The
  Canadian Disease"
 
   BY:  RANDALL MORCK
   University of Alberta
DAVID A. STANGELAND
   University of Manitoba
   Department of Accounting  Finance
BERNARD YIN YEUNG
   University of Michigan
 
 Paper ID:  National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper
No. 6814
 Date:  November 1998
 
  Contact:  RANDALL MORCK
Email:  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
   Postal:  University of Alberta
Edmonton T6G 2R6, Alberta   CANADA
Phone:  (780)492-5683
  Fax:  (780)492-3325
  Co-Auth:  DAVID A. STANGELAND
Email:  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
   Postal:  University of Manitoba
Department of Accounting  Finance
Faculty of Management
Winnipeg, MB   CANADA, R3T 5V4
  Co-Auth:  BERNARD YIN YEUNG
Email:  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
   Postal:  University of Michigan
701 Tappan Street
Ann Arbor, MI 48109-1234  USA
 
 Paper Requests:
  Full-Text Availability at http://www.nber.org/wwp.html Papers
  can be downloaded online for $5. Hard copies are $10 plus
  $10.00/order outside the USA. Prepayment required. NBER orders:
  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED] Checks, Mastercard, Visa and American
  Express to 1050 Massachusetts Ave., Cambridge, MA 02138.
  Phone:(617)868-3900. Fax:(617)349-3955. For NBER Subscriptions
  Mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED] or write to "Subscriptions" at address
  above.
 
 ABSTRACT:
  Countries in which billionaire heirs' wealth is large relative
  to G.D.P. grow more slowly, show signs of more political
  rent-seeking, and spend less on innovation than do other
  countries at similar levels of development. In contrast,
  countries in which self-made entrepreneur billionaire wealth is
  large relative to G.D.P. grow more rapidly and show fewer signs
  of rent seeking.
 
  We argue that this is consistent with wealthy entrenched
  families having objectives other than creating public
  shareholder value. Also, the control pyramids through which they
  are entrenched give wealthy families preferential access to
  capital and enhanced lobbying power. Entrenched families also
  have a vested interest in preserving the value of existing
  capital. To investigate these arguments, we use firm-level
  Canadian data and cross country data. Heir-controlled Canadian
  firms show lower industry-adjusted financial performance, labor
  capital ratios, and RD than other firms of the same ages and
  sizes. Cross country data show that countries with more
  billionaire heirs' wealth are less open to inward foreign direct
  investment and have lower private-sector RD spending.
 
  We argue that concentrated, inherited corporate control
  impedes growth, and dub this "the Canadian disease." Further
  research is needed to determine the international incidence of
  this condition.
 
  Finally, heir-controlled Canadian firms' share prices fell
  relative to those of comparable firms on the news that the
  Canada-U.S. free trade agreement would be ratified. A key
  provision of that treaty is capital market openness. Under the
  treaty, heir-controlled Canadian firms' labor capital ratios
  rose, while the incidence of heir-control fell. We suggest that
  openness, especially of capital markets, may mitigate the ill
  effects of concentrated inherited control. If so, capital market
  openness matters for reasons not captured by standard
  international trade and finance models.
 
 






Re: Canada

1997-12-28 Thread Bill Burgess


Doug Henwood wrote:
 
 I hear this from a lot of Canadians - the implication being that Canada
 didn't have a debt problem. With a structural budget deficit of over 5% of
 GDP in 1991, net government interest payments also over 5% of GDP, and the
 second-highest net government debt position in the G-7 (after Italy), I'd
 say those are numbers too big to ignore. With a net international
 investment position of -41% of GDP in 1996, I'd say that Canada still has a
 debt problem. When you've got a big debt, your creditors call the shots,
 no? Or am I missing something here?

I think the OECD numbers include government enterprises, and in Canada
this means the provinically owned Hydros, who are very large borrowers,
and so skew the comparison a bit if comparable utilities are not
government owned. 

However there is no doubt that Canadian capitalism is a big
borrower. It is also true that there was a tendency in the campaign
against free trade to promote a near-conspiracy theory that the Bank of
Canada interest rate hikes were part of a secret side deal to the FTA
itself. In other words, the job losses were blamed on 'free' trade rather
than reflecting something more fundamental about Canadian capitalism. 

Still, the articles at the time (including in the WSJ, that Tom Walker
referred to) which compared Canada to Mexico and some other 'third' world
countries are absurd. Linda McQuaig's book provides a great description of
how this was a deliberate campaign to 'convince' us of the need for
austerity. Canada may be a big borrower but it is also itself a major
lender. Total outward FDI is only 5% less than inward FDI. And while total
foreign liabilities are 1.7 times those of total foreign
assets, this ratio has not increased *dramatically* compared to previous
decades. Net foreign liabilities were 42% of GDP in 1996, but they also
hit 42% in 1961. I don't have the figures at hand, but I'd be surprised if  
Canada's net foreign liabilities as a share of GDP have increased much 
more than that of the OECD average. 

Bill Burgess   







Re: Canada

1997-12-27 Thread Tom Walker

Doug Henwood wrote,

I hear this from a lot of Canadians - the implication being that Canada
didn't have a debt problem. With a structural budget deficit of over 5% of
GDP in 1991, net government interest payments also over 5% of GDP, and the
second-highest net government debt position in the G-7 (after Italy), I'd
say those are numbers too big to ignore. With a net international
investment position of -41% of GDP in 1996, I'd say that Canada still has a
debt problem. When you've got a big debt, your creditors call the shots,
no? Or am I missing something here?

No, the implication isn't that Canada didn't/doesn't have a debt problem.
The implication is that the source of the debt/deficit problem has been
misrepresented and the dimensions of the problem have been used as a pretext
to fry other fish. About 10% of federal government debt in Canada represents
program spending in excess of revenues, the rest is interest on debt. That's
about $540 billion interest on $60 billion of spending.

Canada's debt is the product, not of profligate spending on social programs
but of a decade and a half of right-wing fiscal and monetary policies --
high interest rates and tax give aways to corporations and high income
individuals. One might speculate that social spending was maintained as long
as it was in order to 1. smooth over the impact of the tax and monetary
policies and 2. wait as political support for the social programs eroded
(partly in response to changes in those programs).

For several years, the Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives has put out
an alternative federal budget that would have reduced the deficit _faster_
than the announced schedule of the (finance minister) Martin deficit
reduction but without the immense inequities. Obviously, this overlooks the
political pressures that support those inequities. Maybe a fair tax system
and a full employment policy in Canada would be sufficient grounds for a
U.S. blockade.



Regards, 

Tom Walker
^^^
Know Ware Communications
Vancouver, B.C., CANADA
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
(604) 688-8296 
^^^
The TimeWork Web: http://www.vcn.bc.ca/timework/





Re: Canada II

1997-12-27 Thread Tom Walker

Valis wrote,

In our Tom we have a raconteur smack in the tradition of Khrushchev,

I always wanted to be a raconteur but I never felt quite avuncular enough.

Regards, 

Tom Walker
^^^
Know Ware Communications
Vancouver, B.C., CANADA
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
(604) 688-8296 
^^^
The TimeWork Web: http://www.vcn.bc.ca/timework/






Re: Canada

1997-12-27 Thread Doug Henwood

Tom Walker wrote:

The WSJ is only too modest. A key part of the massive propaganda campaign to
help sell the austerity program was a Wall Street Journal article claiming
that Canada was about to "hit the debt wall". That, coupled with a "leaked"
IMF memo was trumpeted through the Canadian media as proof positive the sky
was falling. They went along and they went along and they went along until
they met a Wall Street fox . . . "We're going to tell the king the sky is
falling," said Chicken Little, Ducky Daddles, Turkey Lurkey and Canada
Goosey Loosey.

I hear this from a lot of Canadians - the implication being that Canada
didn't have a debt problem. With a structural budget deficit of over 5% of
GDP in 1991, net government interest payments also over 5% of GDP, and the
second-highest net government debt position in the G-7 (after Italy), I'd
say those are numbers too big to ignore. With a net international
investment position of -41% of GDP in 1996, I'd say that Canada still has a
debt problem. When you've got a big debt, your creditors call the shots,
no? Or am I missing something here?

Doug







Re: Canada II

1997-12-27 Thread valis

On Sat, 27 Dec 1997 Tom Walker recounted, in conclusion:

They went along and they went along and they went along until
 they met a Wall Street fox . . . "We're going to tell the king the sky is
 falling," said Chicken Little, Ducky Daddles, Turkey Lurkey and Canada
 Goosey Loosey.
 
 "Follow me", said the Wall Street fox, "I know a short-cut to the king's
 palace."

And I'll bet that short-cut runs right through www.butcherblock.com.
In our Tom we have a raconteur smack in the tradition of Khrushchev,
who populated his political parables with barnyard creatures and wildlife.
However, I'm not sure this is a good example of continuity.

valis







Re: Canada

1997-12-27 Thread Tom Walker

From the Wall Street Journal article on Canada,

Last-minute bad news helped Mr. Martin sell his
controversial program. As the finance minister was about
to stand to address a cabinet meeting where he expected
opposition to the proposals, he was handed a note saying
the Bank of Canada had boosted short-term interest rates
a full percentage point in response to the peso crisis.

The WSJ is only too modest. A key part of the massive propaganda campaign to
help sell the austerity program was a Wall Street Journal article claiming
that Canada was about to "hit the debt wall". That, coupled with a "leaked"
IMF memo was trumpeted through the Canadian media as proof positive the sky
was falling. They went along and they went along and they went along until
they met a Wall Street fox . . . "We're going to tell the king the sky is
falling," said Chicken Little, Ducky Daddles, Turkey Lurkey and Canada
Goosey Loosey.

"Follow me", said the Wall Street fox, "I know a short-cut to the king's
palace."

Regards, 

Tom Walker
^^^
Know Ware Communications
Vancouver, B.C., CANADA
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
(604) 688-8296 
^^^
The TimeWork Web: http://www.vcn.bc.ca/timework/






Re: Canada

1997-12-26 Thread Sid Shniad

Doug,

this is a classic case in which the operation was a success, but the
patient died. It would be amusing if it weren't so tragic to see the
maintstream media commentators doing back-to-back stories praising the
government for its neoliberal economic policies, only to switch to
heartfelt observations about how mean things are getting on Canada's
streets, how the number of homeless is burgeoning, how Vancouver has the
highest incidence of drug-related HIV infection in the developed world,
etc.

Happy Neoliberal Holidays to All, and to All a Good Night

Sid
 
 Hey all you Canadians. You're always complaining about how bad things are
 up there in the Great White North. Today's Wall Street Journal sets the
 record straight - Canada is the envy of the G-7, a true austerity success
 story!
 
 Doug
 
 
 
  The Wall Street Journal Interactive Edition - December 26, 1997
 
 Canada Endured Tough Choices
 To End a Damaging Recession
 By LARRY M. GREENBERG, ROGER RICKLEFS and MARK HEINZL
 Staff Reporters of THE WALL STREET JOURNAL
 
 TORONTO -- Fluke Transportation Group Ltd., a trucking
 company once owned by three brothers named Fluke, could
 always get a lift from its pithy slogan: "If it's on
 time, it's a Fluke."
 No slogan, however, could protect the Hamilton, Ontario,
 concern from Canada's devastating recession and
 austerity program of the early and mid-1990s. "I was
 really worried," says Ron Foxcroft, president and chief
 executive. "Employees came in every week saying a
 different neighbor got laid off. We had to cut costs to
 the bone."
 
 Spurred by its trials, the company refocused its
 operations and took advantage of free trade with the
 U.S. to push export business. Today, Mr. Foxcroft says,
 "we are just booming." The company, which had all of
 three trucks 15 years ago, now has 200 trucks and 500
 trailers.
 
 Like Mr. Foxcroft and his company, Canada is back. The
 nation's recession was nearly twice as severe as its
 U.S. counterpart, but by some measures, its recovery has
 been even more successful.
 
 Though the recession technically ended in early 1991,
 its effects hindered Canada for years. Corporate
 restructuring was so severe that the unemployment rate
 rose for two years after the recession was over and
 reached 11.5% in 1993. Then the country had to endure a
 brutal program of government spending cuts to curb
 soaring budget deficits. The economy had a negative
 quarter as recently as 1995.
 
 Yet Canada today is growing more rapidly than any Group
 of Seven country and has an even lower inflation rate
 than the U.S. Economists expect Canada to achieve a
 balanced budget in the current fiscal year, ending March
 31 -- well ahead of the U.S. "We have the strongest
 economy in the G7 this year, and I think there is a good
 chance we'll have the strongest next year," says Sherry
 S. Cooper, chief economist of Nesbitt Burns Inc.,
 Toronto, the Bank of Montreal's securities arm.
 
 Some economists fear that Canada won't maintain the
 momentum, predicting the economy will slow next year
 because of Asia's financial problems, which have reduced
 the prices Canada gets for its huge exports of mining
 and forest products. Even Dr. Cooper has lowered her
 forecast for economic growth next year to 3.6% from 4%,
 and other economists are predicting growth of as low as
 2.8%.
 
 Still, for now, signs abound that the Canadian economy
 is improving. The nation's central bank, the Bank of
 Canada, predicted in November that the economy would
 grow 4% this year. Job growth remains strong, as do
 retail sales. Meanwhile, the consumer price index has
 risen just 0.9% in a year.
 
 Sidelined for Years
 
 To get to their current state, Canadians had to struggle
 through a recession followed by an austerity program far
 tougher than anything Americans have suffered in the
 postwar era. People thrown out of work were often
 sidelined for years. Steelworker Shane Thomson lost his
 job at Dofasco Inc. in 1992 when the Hamilton steel
 producer laid off 2,000 employees. He didn't find steady
 work again until 1994. Even then, his new employer laid
 him off and rehired him twice in two years as its orders
 ebbed and flowed. "There were no luxuries, that's for
 sure," the father of three says of those lean years.
 
 Businesses also took a beating. According to industry
 figures, about 25% of Canada's manufacturers and about a
 third of its retailers closed their doors between 1989
 and 1992. A decade ago, 22 companies made carpeting in
 Canada. But between the recession and increased
 competition from the U.S., only five are left, says W.
 Leslie Single, chairman and chief executive of Crossley
 Carpet Mills Ltd., in Truro, Nova Scotia.
 
 'You Lose Sleep'
 
 "In 1993, there was some question whether or not our
 company would survive," Mr. Single recalls. The company
 was losing money, its employment had plunged 

Decline and fall (was Re: Canada)

1997-12-26 Thread valis

Dennis R Redmond concluded:
 It's like watching the Roman provinces going belly-up, one by one, only
 starring Japan and Central Europe as the heathen MicroGoths who are just
 beginning to grasp that the masters are now the servants. Let's just hope
 they show us more mercy than we've shown to Latin America.

Money is not the whole story.  Never was.
Indeed, why should the home of Beavis and Butthead expect any leniency?
That would be just another symptom of its cultural inferiority.

One night in the early Sixties I lay on an upper bunk in a Dutch youth
hostel listening to utter contempt being heaped upon "the Jeezuzz country"
through a whole evening in at least four languages.  Both vilifiers and
targets were numerical fringe elements then; now each is fleshed out.
We have fallen beneath a certain critical threshold here and are now
producing more brute animals than people.

There are moments when I feel that the highest expression of patriotism
due America is the wish for its quick and merciful death, since it would
resist revolution with all the manic strength of its ignorance and guilt.  

   valis








Re: Canada

1997-12-26 Thread Dennis R Redmond

On Fri, 26 Dec 1997, Doug Henwood cross-posted from a WSJ story:

 Canada Endured Tough Choices To End a Damaging Recession
 By LARRY M. GREENBERG, ROGER RICKLEFS and MARK HEINZL
 Staff Reporters of THE WALL STREET JOURNAL
 The country's growth rate declined to 2.3% in 1995 from
 4.1% in 1994 and slid to 1.5% in 1996.

One small note: Canada's much-trumpeted growth rates are pretty sickly
when you consider the demographic factor -- Canada has one of the highest
rates of population growth of any industrialized nation (around 1.3% or
so, I assume due to plentiful immigration). Put another way, real Canadian
wealth per capita went nowhere in 1996, and has crawled along at
1.5-2% rates in the 1990s -- not counting currency fluctuations. 

 Meanwhile, the decline of the
 Canadian dollar to 70 U.S. cents from a recent peak of
 about 89 cents in 1991 has given Canadian exporters a
 big advantage. (The U.S. takes about 83% of Canada's
 exports.)

Counting currency fluctuations, approximately 19% of the Canadian
economy vanished into the nether gulfs of the foreign exchange markets, to
be reborn elsewhere as more highly valued yen and euros. So that 2% annual
increase in per capita GDP growth was really a 3% annual decrease. This is
how neocolonies of former Empires fall to pieces: piece by piece. 

 Moreover, household debt has soared to 97% of disposable
 personal income from 65% in 1991, Mr. Myers notes. The
 personal savings rate has plunged to less than 1% from
 8.5% two years ago. 
[text cut]
 In addition, the unemployment rate has remained at 9%
 nationally despite the economic boom. While the boom
 creates jobs, restructuring eliminates them. And total
 government debt still equals about 100% of GDP, compared
 with 64% in the U.S., the Organization for Economic
 Cooperation and Development reports.

So all that austerity didn't work, after all; instead, a wild rentier
credit boom, massive American trade deficits, a shame-faced, backdoor
Keynesianism and of course an expansive American Federal Reserve policy
were necessary to prevent our other protectorate (the first one being
Puerto Rico) from completely imploding. 

It's like watching the Roman provinces going belly-up, one by one, only
starring Japan and Central Europe as the heathen MicroGoths who are just
beginning to grasp that the masters are now the servants. Let's just hope
they show us more mercy than we've shown to Latin America.

-- Dennis







[PEN-L:8963] Re: Canada and Cuba

1997-03-17 Thread Tom Walker

Bill,

Congratulations on completing your comprehensives!

Regards, 

Tom Walker
^^
knoW Ware Communications  |
Vancouver, B.C., CANADA   |  "Only in mediocre art
[EMAIL PROTECTED]   |does life unfold as fate."
(604) 669-3286|
^^
 The TimeWork Web: http://mindlink.net/knowware/worksite.htm 







[PEN-L:8956] Re: Canada and Cuba

1997-03-17 Thread Bill Burgess

Paul Phillips argues that I share Jesse Helm's criticism of Canada on
Cuba and that it hurts Cuba and Canada to suggest the latter's policy is
motivated by imperialist greed.

Well, I think Helms is right that Canada is putting it's own commercial
interests first. I think it is also worth putting the Helms-Burton
initiative in the context of growing trade tensions between the US and
its competitors including Canada but especially Europe. 

The main disagreement Paul and I have is that he argues that
Canada's position ("our position") has been to support Cuba's right to
self-determination. I wish this was true (and have long worked for it to
be so), but it is not.

Like other imperialist powers the Canadian government opposes the
extraterritoriality of Washington's Cuba policy and shares the opinion of
most that the US embargo is not an effective tactic against Castro.
However, it shares Washington's basic aims in Cuba and has said so many
times, including while voting for the annual UN resolution against the US
embargo (where, incidently, it always focuses its criticism on the
extraterritoriality issue; I have never seen a clear statement opposing
the embargo in principle). Canada's ambassador to the US recently said
Canada agreed with the US on the need to establish "democracy, a free
market and human rights" in Cuba. I think we should recognize that these
words really mean "a return to capitalist exploitation".

When Foreign Affairs Minister Axworthy visited Cuba recently he played up
the human rights angle. This shows that Canada has come into line with the
December EU resolution on Helms-Burton that stated that a "democratic
system of government must be installed in Cuba as a matter of priority"
and that expanded aid and trade to Cuba would "depend on improvements in
human rights and freedom". This is not defence of self-determination, it
is using slanders on human rights to attack the Cuban revolution.

I'm sure Paul would agree how genuine the Canadian government's concern
for human and political rights is in s. Korea or Somalia, for example. Why
give them so much credit on Cuba? He points to the aid to Cuba financed
by the Canadian government, but it is an old story that where aid flows,
investments follow more easily. There is a widespread myth that Canada is
some kind of semi-colony that can identify with fellow victims of
imperialism. The truth is that Canadian investments abroad are even larger
than those of the US in relative terms.

I'm all in favour of Cuba taking every advantage of the split between the
US and Canada, and milking every diplomatic statement for all its worth.
However, it is our job here in Canada to be more frank about the
situation. I'm sure we agree
we should do everything we can to pressure the government for policies
favouring more trade and aid. But I don't think we can be very effective
here if we believe the government shares our support for the Cuban
people. 

Finally, Steve Zahnister suggests the US policy is idiotic even from a
capitalist viewpoint, and is the result of internal US politics. I think
this approach is a serious mistake too. I think it minimizes how
consistant and deep the (bipartisan) hostility to Cuba has been since
1959, and so how important they feel it is to defeat the example of the
Cuban revolution. The problem is that Steve's approach tends to also
minimize the importance of solidarity with the Cuban revolution for us in
the US and Canada.



Bill Burgess
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
home (604) 255-5957
fax c/o (604) 822-6150






[PEN-L:3307] Re: Canada Warns (fwd)

1996-03-11 Thread Ajit Sinha

A
 [The Boston Globe]

  Canada warns it will fight US anti-Castro measure


Way to go Canada!!

But tell me how much of this is principled stand and how much of it is
simply money?

Cheers, ajit sinha



Re: [PEN-L:3307] Re: Canada Warns (fwd)

1996-03-11 Thread Chris Johnston

On Mon, 11 Mar 1996, Ajit Sinha wrote:

  [The Boston Globe]
 
   Canada warns it will fight US anti-Castro measure
 
 
 Way to go Canada!!
 
 But tell me how much of this is principled stand and how much of it is
 simply money?

I'll take this one.  To answer the question directly, 0.0001% of the former
and 99.% for the latter.  The Canadian government clearly sees trade
opportunities at stake, and has probably long been snickering that the more 
American companies are locked out by the embargo the more Canadian interests
can exploit the Cuban market and resources.  There's little real sympathy 
for Castro or the Cuban people, and a procession of humanitarian aid 
organizations and others attempting to establish friendlier relations with
Cuba has had little official help over the years.  Axworthy (external affairs
minister) implied last week that it was simply a choice of the carrot over
the stick and that freer trade and an opening up of Cuban markets would 
eventually erode Castro's base of support and bring him down.  Hurrah
for Canada, eh!

Cheers,
Chris Johnston
(in St. Catharines, Ontario)



[PEN-L:2609] Re: Canada-Chile joint TU Statement

1996-01-26 Thread Blair Sandler

At 8:49 PM 1/24/96, [EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

Who will give me what odds that either government will pay the
slightest regards to human rights or international conventions?

Paul: I'll give you any odds you want that the Canadian government will pay
the slightest regards to human rights or international conventions. They'll
look at it; they might mention it, and then they'll move on as if they
hadn't seen it.

Is that a bet?

Blair

;-)




Re: Canada, via Barron's

1994-12-11 Thread DJ


On Sat, 10 Dec 1994, Doug Henwood wrote:

 .. 2) by the Calgary-based business writer George Koch, called "Canada's 
 Newt: How Alberta's premier aims to cut government spending." It 
 celebrates the budget cutting led by Ralph Klein, who is prortrayed in an 
 accompanying cartoon as holding an ax. Government spending is being cut 
 by 20% in nominal terms, and the aim is to cut the provincial 
 government's spending from 18.3% of provincial product to 14.3% by 1997. 
 According to Koch, Klein is quite popular, with an approval rating of 61%.
 
 Any comments?
 
I am not at all sure why Ralph Klein gets so much approval. I know people 
in Alberta who complain bitterly about what he has done to social 
programs and I know the federal government is not happy with the fact 
that he has opened clinics for health care which actually charge some 
fees. Yet, from what I can gather, the polls are accurate - he has 
engendered the most hatred and the most loved response form different 
groups of people. Alberta has th elowest tax rates in all of Canada and 
has the most resources of any province in Canada, yet the people there 
seem relieved to get rid of debt - they were also the last province to go 
into debt (BC was about the same time). Maybe it is a mind set but I can 
assure you that the ROC (Rest of Canada) does not think along the same 
lines. If there is to be separation in Canada's future, I see it as being 
more feasible for Alberta to go than for Quebec (having lived in Alberta 
three years.




Re: Canada, via Barron's

1994-12-10 Thread Ellen Dannin ([EMAIL PROTECTED])

And something else you should be aware of - Alberta's premier has taken 
Roger Douglas of New Zealand, the progenitor of the eponymous Rogernomics 
- as his model. Douglas' book was way up on the best seller lists in 
Canada for a long time.  Douglas goes about billing himself as a 
socialist who is willing to make hard choices and face hard realities.  
One migh add that he is hardly a socialist, but Madison AVenue is all.

Ellen J. Dannin
California Western School of Law
225 Cedar Street
San Diego, CA  92101
Phone:  619-525-1449
Fax:619-696-