Re: External Value of the Nobel

2002-10-12 Thread Peter J Boettke



The article in the Post was sour grades. The 
reality is that GMU has been entrepreneurial in recognizing slightly out of sync 
economists and creating a spot for them and their programs. Buchanan and 
Smith bucked the dominant intellectual trends of the profession to push forward 
their agendas. Tullock has done the same, and when Boulding taught here it 
was the same thing.

The reality is that 90% to 99% of out of sync 
work is accurately dismissed, but 10% to 1% of this work amounts to 
revolutionary in science. But in many ways we need the 90% of failed 
projects to get the 1 to 10% of truly innovative work. Now this is a risky 
strategy for most departments to follow and most shy away from it or get tired 
of supporting it.

Note a few things about GMU's strategy --- in 
both cases (Buchanan and Smith) while they were recognized the movement they 
represented was for a long time discounted and they were not teaching at what 
one would term top tier universities before moving to GMU. VPI was a good 
school, but certainly not Harvard or Chicago, and the same for Arizona. Both had 
left schools that were rising (U VA and Purdue) because of various factors 
relatively early in their careers. So the idea conveyed in the Post 
article is that these figures worked for years at prestigous universities and 
then only in retirement did they come to GMU is wrong.

Now on how that translates into increased 
value of a GMU degree. Well obviously it increases the name recognition of the 
program, but the question will always remain as to whether if a student was so 
good why would they go to GMU to their PhD --- this is similar to what happened 
at NYU when I taught there --- which went from 17 to 7 during my 8 years there 
in terms of the rankings, but it was know as a school where the faculty were 
'better' than the students such that basically 1 student each year would receive 
a top placement, but the others would not get jobs in academics. I believe 
the situation has improved quite a lot there since I was there in terms of 
placement -- so the faculty addressed this issue by increasing the admission 
requirements, etc.But if we did that, we wouldn't attract students 
interested in the out of sync. So right now, I'd say GMU does best when it 
caters to the out of sync and our students do best when they are the best out of 
sync economists on the market.

The reality is that GMU is a school that best 
serves the out of sync economist. We are clearly the best out of sync 
department in the world. Some of what goes on here is no doubt going to 
prove itself to have been a waste of intellectual resources, but other stuff 
will turn out to be absolutely cutting edge. We don't know that ex ante -- 
only ex post.

What we should value in James Buchanan and 
Vernon Smith's prizes is not just that they got recognized for there genius, but 
the way they pursued their careers. Here we have two brilliant men who 
fought against scientific prejudies and pursued their work and "forced" the 
mainstream of economic thought to pay attention. In short they 
demonstrated not only the courage of their convictions, but the courage to 
withstand the critique of their convictions. 

As for Vernon Smith -- one of the most amazing 
things about him is how open he is to new and unconventional ideas. He is 
75 and still trying to learn new things and incorporate them into his research 
program. It is very exciting to see him probing and 
questioning. As for Buchanan, we was willing (and still is) to ask 
big and deep questions about social philosophy in a discipline that rewards 
techniques and smarts and often reduces the worldly philosophy to exercises in 
mental gymnastics or social engineering.

A final point about the 'Austrian' 
implications of Buchanan and Smith. First, both are deeply knowledgable and 
respectful of 'Austrian' economics. Second, both have made contributions 
which in many cases can be understood as 'Austrian' --- in Buchanan it was 
subjectivism and his understanding of catallactics, and in Smith's case it was 
his testing of Hayek's notion of the use of information and he demonstration of 
the groping market. Third, both have pushed Austrian economics in new directions 
which people can follow --- Buchanan into political economy and Smith into 
neuroscience.

The missing element in mainstream economics is 
still a theory of change and with that a focus on the agent of change -- 
entrepreneurship. But the reality is that much of the progress in 
mainstream economics has been through the increasing recognition of points first 
pointed out by Mises and Hayek in the 1940s. The ideas are being 
incorporated if not recognition for the individuals who first developed the 
ideas. This is progress. And GMU is at the forefront of that 
progress and I would think that its graduates (such as JC Bradbury) would want 
to wear that label proudly and push those ideas more and more. I think GMU 
stands for a few things (a) 

Re: Krugman on productivity

2002-10-12 Thread Chris Macrae
Well since 85% of productivity of large companies is directly connected to
intangibles and these companies are almost completely blind to the human
qualities of what connects intangibles productivity : which you can test
from 2 simple exercises in the top left column thread at www.valuetrue.com
...
the chances of any growth - and when - are  determined by when transparent
corporate governance ushers in - and since that requires a mother of all
benchmarking to make Baldrige quality gap's narrowing in the 80's look like
child's play, I expect 2 years of deeper and deeper depression and social
crisis are sadly on the cards before the vain bureaucracies unlearn

This incidentally was the modal prediction that came about through
interviewing intangibles experts early in 2001 when Brookings published
Unseen Wealth and the European Union published an equally strongly worded
criticism of every blindness built into accounting monopolies built round
last term's number and Speculator Value Analysis
...and the rest has been history tracking the future so to speak

www.valuetrue.com Transparency Mapping
co-author Maps that Change Our World (2003)

http://www.normanmacrae.com/netfuture.html Preferred Future Histories
- Original Message -
From: Alex T Tabarrok [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: 11 October 2002 19:10 PM
Subject: Krugman on productivity


 Krugman finally gets back to economics and says something pretty smart
 about productivity, unemployment and growth.

 http://www.wws.princeton.edu/~pkrugman/jobs.html

 Alex

 --
 Alexander Tabarrok
 Department of Economics, MSN 1D3
 George Mason University
 Fairfax, VA, 22030
 Tel. 703-993-2314

 and

 Director of Research
 The Independent Institute
 100 Swan Way
 Oakland, CA, 94621
 Tel. 510-632-1366









A man for all markets (interview with Galbraith)

2002-10-12 Thread Alypius Skinner




http://www.observer.co.uk/business/story/0,6903,805309,00.html

A 
man for all markets At 93, the scourge of contemporary economics, JK Galbraith, is on the 
attack. The author of The Great Crash tells William Keegan that President Bush's 
moves against recession are no use at all Sunday October 6, 2002The Observer Recent reports had said Galbraith looked 
frail, and he has certainly not been too well. But when this was being explained 
to me in advance, he grabbed 

  
  

  


  

ADVERTISEMENT
  
the telephone and 
boomed: 'Keegan, I'm on the mend.' And certainly, when we spoke, his form of 
93-year-old frailty seemed pretty robust. (He is 94 next week.) 
He began with a paean of praise for Adam Smith, who, he said, had been 'too 
fully captured by the right-wing'. In Galbraith's view 'much of what he said had 
large encouragement for the careful and intelligent Left. He was ruined to an 
extent by his acolytes, many of whom had never read him.' 
Thoughts of Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiments moved Galbraith to the ethics 
of the present. 'I have written a long essay, "The Economics of Innocent Fraud" 
about things that, for self-interest or convenience, we hail as the truth but 
have no particular relevance to reality.' 
With an eye on the Bush administration Galbraith said one minor example of 
this was relevant now: 'You can't stimulate an economy by reducing taxes on the 
rich. That is popular for what it does for those who get the money, and not for 
what it does for the economy.' 
He has always been superb at attacking 'conventional wisdom', a phrase he 
coined, and his current target is worship of the US Federal Reserve. America is 
'having a somewhat painful recession, with no remedial action in sight of any 
consequence. The administration, in summary, has two lines of action: one is tax 
relief for the rich. The other is reliance on the Federal Reserve. It is at 
least consistent. Both are without effect.' 
This celebrated author feels his greatest achievement was not his books but 
his time as head of the body responsible for US price controls during the Second 
World War. He contrasts the success of this with the inflation that took place 
after the First World War, when the Fed was in charge. 'Historians never mention 
inflation as they did after World War One. But if - and I think this is the 
basic rule of all public service - if you succeed your work is forgotten.' 
Then came the rapier thrust: 'One of the most important things we did in 
those years was to set aside all reliance on central bank policy.' There will be 
more about the excessive reliance placed by governments and economists on 
central banks in the new book. 'But it will not be without admira tion for Alan 
Greenspan. We've never seen anything like his theatrical skills.' 
And European central banks? 'I've never been a close student of monetary 
policy in Europe, apart from the inescapable history of the Bank of England.' 
We returned to the present day. 'This is a very disagreeable time, and its 
burden is falling as usual on those least able to carry it. You pick up the 
newspaper any time, and on the financial pages you'll read of the constructive 
action some company or other is taking: in a commendable step it has just laid 
off 10 per cent of its workforce. There is no reflection on the discomfort that 
might follow from being so assigned to leisure, or what it might do if their 
children are going to college.' 
Galbraith has always written beautifully - a source of admiration and 
sometimes acute envy among fellow economists - and still speaks in measured, 
rounded sentences, choosing his words carefully, sometimes going back to 
substitute le mot juste. 
'Being so assigned to leisure' is a classic Galbraithian use of irony, and 
reminded me of his book, The Affluent Society. 'Things are bad enough,' he said, 
'so that I haven't noticed any great revival of interest in that book. Perhaps I 
should have a new edition with a new title. It could be "The Depressed Economy", 
and it would face the fact that only a reduced colony of booklovers could afford 
to buy it.' 
Which brought us to Galbraith's masterpiece The Great Crash, 1929. Surely 
there had been a revival of interest in that? 
'The Great Crash has been in print since the mid-Fifties, and it still 
outsells all of my other books' (he has published 30). 'It has a wonderful, 
built-in salesmanship: any time anyone complains as to what he or she is 
suffering in the stock market there is someone who always says, "If you think 
that is bad, why don't you read Galbraith on 1929"?' 
This reminds him of when he used to peruse bookshops to see how his latest 
was doing. He noticed that one title was never on sale in the old La Guardia 
airport in New York. 'One night the woman in charge asked me what I was looking 
for. I was a little ashamed, but came out with the title, The Great Crash. She 
never hesitated: "That certainly is not a book