Re: socialism historical?

2003-06-18 Thread Fred Foldvary
 So what label would you use?
 Fabio 

I would avoid using the labels capitalism and socialism.

Substitutes for capitalism:

1) private enterprise
2) free market; free enterprise; pure market
3) market economy
4) interventionism
5) mixed economy

Substitutes for socialism:

1) forced redistribution
2) command economy
3) government ownership
4) worker cooperatives; worker ownership of capital
5) forced collectivism

Fred Foldvary

=
[EMAIL PROTECTED]



Re: Health insurance for kids

2003-06-18 Thread Bryan Caplan
Jeffrey Rous wrote:
 When I was in grad school, my wife's health insurance policy through
 work allowed an employee to add a spouse for $1000 per year (I cannot
 remember the exact numbers, but these are close) or add a spouse and
 children for $2000 per year. And it didn't matter whether you had 1
 child or 10.

 Since she worked for UNC, I figured it was a political decision.
I'm pretty sure that it's not.  My wife's private insurance works the 
same way.  Unless regulations make the private sector copy the public 
sector.

 How can this be rational?

At least for male employees, it's plausible that those with more 
children are both older and therefore more experienced, and more 
responsible/stable holding age constant.  A guy with five kids is going 
to be very concerned about remaining employed.

 -Jeffrey Rous




--
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  The game of just supposing
   Is the sweetest game I know...
   And if the things we dream about
   Don't happen to be so,
   That's just an unimportant technicality.
   Jerome Kern and Oscar Hammerstein, *Showboat*




Re: Wage-Price Controls Under Nixon

2003-06-18 Thread Kevin Carson
Actually, they support state capitalism under the name of progressivism or 
putting people first or some equally inane goo-goo slogan.  Just about 
every part of the Progressive/New Deal agenda reflected the interests of big 
business in cartelizing and stabilizing the corporate economy;  it was just 
sold to the public as a progressive restraint on big business.

Please bear in mind that what was called socialism by democratic 
socialists in the 1920s would not have been recognized as such by most of 
the classical socialists of the nineteenth century.  The difference reflects 
the New Class takeover of the working class movement, by Leninists and 
Fabians, at the turn of the century.

Revisionist historians like Gabriel Kolko and James Weinstein called the 
phenomenon political capitalism or corporate liberalism.  Murray 
Rothbard agreed with their analysis.  Whatever you call it, it is organized 
capital acting through the state.  The court intellectuals of corporate 
liberalism (Art Schlesinger) like to depict the movement as an idealistic 
attempt to set countervailing power against the giant corporations.  And a 
lot of big business propagandists like to howl about how anti-business 
forces have won consistently.   But in fact, it is a case of Brer Rabbit 
hollering Please don't fling me in that briar patch!


From: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Reply-To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: Re: Wage-Price Controls Under Nixon
Date: Fri, 13 Jun 2003 21:58:42 EDT
I tend to agree with Marc, but it's worth note that while no avowed 
socialist
has ever gotten into the double-digits (Eugene V. Debs peaked at 6% in 
1912),
the Democratic Party has enacted virtually every plank in the 1928 
Socialist
Party platform, and the Republicans have come to accept virtually all of it
too.  Americans don't like to support something called socialism, but 
they
often support socialism by some other name.

David

In a message dated 6/13/03 7:04:45 PM, [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
writes:

Well, the average American is not so pro-freedom as, say, Walter 
Williams,
but considerably more so than the average Frenchman or German.

Really?  How do you measure this?

Well, we can start with the fact that in the first-round of a typical
presidential election in France, 2/3 of the votes go to candidates so far
to the Left they make Ralph Nader look moderate, and about 1/2 of these
votes, or 1/3 of the total, go to out-and-out Marxists of one sort or
another, candidates who are avowed Trotskyites, Stalinists, etc.  In U.S.
presidential elections, no avowed socialist has *ever* garnered more than
one or two percent of the vote.

Marc Poitras
_
Help STOP SPAM with the new MSN 8 and get 2 months FREE*  
http://join.msn.com/?page=features/junkmail




Re: socialism historical?

2003-06-18 Thread Kevin Carson
Socialism is a historical term whose use has evolved over time.  I believe 
it first appeared in an Owenite periodical, the London Cooperative Journal, 
in 1829 or 1830.

The beginning of the classical socialist movement was the Ricardian 
socialist movement.  They were inspired by two arguments of Ricardo's:  1) 
that the equilibrium value of commodities approximated producer prices when 
those commodities were in elastic supply, and that these producer prices 
corresponded to the embodied labor (including past labor embodied in 
capital);  and 2) that profit, interest and rent were deductions from this 
exchange-value.

From these doctrines, the Ricardian socialists deduced that profit, interest 
and rent derived from the exploitation of labor.  The term Ricardian 
socialist applied most directly to English writers like Hodgskin, Thompson, 
Grey and Bray; but the same deductions from Ricardo occured to Proudhon, 
Rodbertus, Marx, and Warren before the middle of the century.

Socialism is not by any means necessarily statist.  The market-oriented 
Ricardian socialist Thomas Hodgskin, and the American individualist 
anarchist Tucker (who resembled each other closely in many ways), believed 
that the free market was the best route to socialism.  They both viewed 
profit, interest and rent, not as natural outgrowths of a free market, but 
as the products of state-enforced privilege IN VIOLATION OF the free market.

The central defining features of socialism, as Tucker defined them in State 
Socialism and Anarchism, are:
1)  The belief that all exchange value is created by labor; and
2)  that labor is entitled to all it creates.

Tucker believed that this latter end could be best achieved by removing 
statist privileges like banking market entry barriers, legal tender laws, 
and enforcement of land ownership not based on occupancy and use.  The 
resulting free market in land and credit would reduce the return on these 
factors to the labor value of providing credit and the labor value of 
improvements on land (plus economic rent, of course).

I recently found a relevant statement on the issue by the Marxist Maurice 
Dobb, in his introduction to Marx's Toward a Critique of Political 
Economy.

As Dobb rightly pointed out, the orthodox Marxist doctrine is that surplus
value was a necessary outgrowth of wage labor, even in the freest of free
markets. Even in such a laissez-faire environment, the difference between
the value of labor-power and the value of labor's product would result from
the inherent nature of wage labor. Profits would result, Marx said, even if
all products were sold at exactly their values (i.e., the LTV describes how
the market works now, not the ideal for a future utopia). His whole
doctrine depended on the assumption that exploitation would result even in a
free market, where all commodities were sold at value. As Marx said: If
you cannot explain profit on this assumption [without bringing in state
coercion], you cannot explain it at all.
Dobb continues:

The point of this can the better be appreciated if it is remembered that
the school of writers to whom the name of Ricardian Socialists has been
given (such as Thomas Hodgskin, William Thompson and John Bray), who can be
said to have held a 'primitive' theory of exploitation, explained profit on
capital as the product of superior bargaining power, lack of competition and
'unequal exchanges between Capital and Labour' (this bearing analogy with
Eugen Duhring's 'force theory' which was castigated by Engels). This was
the kind of explanation that Marx was avoiding rather than seeking. It did
*not* make exploitation *consistent* with the law of value and market
competition, but explained it by departures from, or imperfections in, the
latter. To it there was an easy answer from the liberal economists and free
traders: namely, 'join with us in demanding *really* free trade and then
there can be no unequal exchanges and exploitation.'
In fact, what Warren, Tucker, and market-oriented Ricardian Socialists like
Hodgskin did was PRECISELY to take up this last challenge. But the way in
which they did so did not please most liberal economists. Benjamin Tucker
accepted Most's charge that he was merely a consistent Manchesterian, and
adopted that label as a badge of honor.


From: Fred Foldvary [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Reply-To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: socialism historical?
Date: Tue, 17 Jun 2003 11:40:43 -0700 (PDT)
--- [EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:
  government money, as it predates socialism, probably doesn't rightly
fall under the category of socialism. 
Does the meaning of socialism include a time frame, so that a policy that
is socialist after that time is not socialist before that time?
What is socialism, what year does it take effect, and why is the time
element involved?
Fred Foldvary

=
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
_
The new MSN 8: advanced junk mail protection and 2 

Re: socialism historical?

2003-06-18 Thread Fred Foldvary
--- [EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:
 You seem to confuse the concept of subordinating the individual to
 a greater human collective to subordinating the individual to the will of
 the tyrant.

But does not the practice of the subordination of the individual to the
collective go back to ancient times, indeed to pre-historical tribal
practice and belief?
Fred Foldvary

=
[EMAIL PROTECTED]



labor supply

2003-06-18 Thread Fred Foldvary
  labor supply elasticity is near-zero...
 Prof. Bryan Caplan

Does this take into account when workers can choose to work overtime, take
more or less vacation, retire earlier or later, have a second household
worker employed or not, have a second job or not, take time off without pay
or not?

Does this take into account that workers may migrate or change their
commute destination?

Also, if labor has a fixed supply, does this include the premium for human
capital?

Fred Foldvary



=
[EMAIL PROTECTED]



Kolko 40 Years Later

2003-06-18 Thread Bryan Caplan
Kevin Carson's remarks on Kolko reminded me that I recently reread Kolko 
and had some comments to share.

Just for background: Kolko's *Triumph of Conservatism* was written 
largely as a left-wing attack on mainstream liberalism.  Kolko's message 
was that most of the regulations and government interventions of the 
Progressive Era that supposedly gave capitalism a human face merely made 
matters even worse for the common man.  In his related volumes 
*Railroads and Regulation*, for example, Kolko argued that railroad 
regulation was designed by railroads themselves to keep rates UP under 
the fig leaf of consumer protection.

Kolko was subsequently dismayed that free-market economists from Stigler 
to Rothbard eagerly accepted his thesis, arguing that Kolko had shown 
that laissez-faire would have been better than what emerged.  And indeed 
that is largely what Kolko showed, though it scarcely occured to him 
that anyone would actually take the laissez-faire option seriously. 
Kolko's goal, rather, was to show the futility of trying to tame 
capitalism, in order to push mainstream liberals towards socialism.

But enough background.  On my re-read, I noticed the following.

1.  Kolko frequently fails to distinguish between government policies 
that directly helped business, as opposed to policies that directly hurt 
business, but reduced the risk of socialist revolution.

The whole idea of a government-enforced cartel, for example, is to raise 
profits above the laissez-faire level.  This is rather different from 
business consenting to moderate welfare state policies that reduce 
profits below the laissez-faire level, but arguably reduce the risk of 
total elimination of the profit system.

Now this point is important because if you take the risk of socialist 
revolution seriously, then ANY welfare state measure that falls short of 
expropriation could be said to help business.  This in turn makes 
Kolko's thesis rather trivial - or, more precisely, an expression of his 
deluded over-estimate of the risk of socialist revolution in the U.S.

2.  Kolko frequently fails to distinguish businesses' desire for 
*standardized* regulation as opposed to *more* regulation.  Very often, 
if you read Kolko carefully, it becomes apparent that businesses lobbied 
the federal government as a reaction to the costly patchwork of 
state-level regulation.  In other words, while the naive reading of 
Kolko makes business preferences look  like this:

federal regulation  state regulation  laissez-faire

His accounts are often perfectly compatible with:

laissez-faire  federal regulation  state regulation

3.  Kolko frequently fails to distinguish the do something motive from 
the cartelization motive.  In many cases, he explains that legislators 
were under public pressure to do something about a perceived problem - 
say business abuses.  Given these circumstances, businesses would 
naturally lobby to contain the damage - to push for cosmetic rather than 
substantive changes.  Again, this does not mean that business wanted 
regulation.  They could easily have had the preference ordering:

laissez-faire  cosmetic regulation  substantive regulation

4.  While Kolko discusses trends in concentration ratios and the like, 
rarely does he come close to replicating his results for railroads. 
There we have a clear mechanism for increasing railroad profits - rate 
regulation - along with a smoking gun - railroads lobbying for precisely 
that.

When Kolko moves to things like the FTC, however, he has nothing 
comparable.  What did the FTC actually DO to reduce competition?  Launch 
some politically-motivated antitrust cases?  That is hardly a plausible 
*mechanism* for setting up a sustainable cartel.

5.  Kolko fails to consider (excusable, perhaps, given that his work 
predates modern information economics) some plausible market failure 
rationales for how regulation would indirectly help the public BY 
directly helping business.  He goes over meat regulation in detail, for 
example, and shows how the meat industry lobbied heavily for federal 
meat regulation.  The main debate, says Kolko, was over who would foot 
the bill for meat inspections.

Now if this were a standard asymmetric information story, the meat 
inspections would raise demand for meat, initially benefiting the meat 
suppliers.  But this would attract entry, and ultimately it would be 
consumers who would benefit.  Tax versus business finance for inspectors 
would ultimately be an issue not of public-to-meat interest 
redistribution, but meat-eating public versus non-meating-eating public.

Now Kolko gives a number of facts that cut against this story.  But the 
idea that consumers might indirectly benefit from measures that directly 
benefit business is not on his radar.

6.  I still like Kolko's discussion of turn-of-the-century 
deconcencentration trends, but the rest of his work makes me wonder how 
trustworthy it is.  And the book has other great stuff that I 

Re: correction

2003-06-18 Thread Kevin Carson
But in areas where the supply of labor is relatively inelastic, such as 
scientific-technical workers, the state steps in by socializing the cost of 
education and training.  For example, that program so beloved of 
progressives who await the second coming of FDR:  the G.I. Bill.

In a partially analogous situation, where the local supply of manufacturing 
labor was rendered unnaturally inelastic by the laws of settlement, the 
state came to the rescue by acting as procurer of labor, selling workers 
from the parish poor houses in labor-rich areas to those in the labor-poor 
manufacturing areas.


From: Bryan Caplan [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Reply-To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED] [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: correction
Date: Wed, 18 Jun 2003 14:26:58 -0400
Of course I meant to say that labor supply elasticity is near-zero, not 
near-infinte.  Thanks to Alex for pointing it out.
--
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  The game of just supposing
   Is the sweetest game I know...
   And if the things we dream about
   Don't happen to be so,
   That's just an unimportant technicality.
   Jerome Kern and Oscar Hammerstein, *Showboat*


_
MSN 8 with e-mail virus protection service: 2 months FREE*  
http://join.msn.com/?page=features/virus




Re: socialism historical?

2003-06-18 Thread AdmrlLocke

In a message dated 6/18/03 2:03:39 PM, [EMAIL PROTECTED] writes:

But does not the practice of the subordination of the individual to the
collective go back to ancient times, indeed to pre-historical tribal
practice and belief?
Fred Foldvar
 

in the ancient world we clearly have a good deal of subordination of the 
individual to the strongest individual or to the priest-king (the strongest 
individual?) but I'm not so clear about subordination of the individual to the 
collective.  It became an article of faith in the 19th-century that pre-historic 
humans practiced primitive communism, but I'm not sure there's much evidence to 
support that faith.  We do know that when Americans came to some of the 
pacific islands that theory said should be practicing primitive communism that they 
actually had a complex system of private property, and that Americans imposed 
primitive communism on them to force them into the right stage of history.

David



Re: Wage-Price Controls Under Nixon

2003-06-18 Thread Kevin Carson
From: Bryan Caplan [EMAIL PROTECTED]

Kevin Carson wrote:


I'd say just the opposite, that SS is an important component of state 
capitalism; and like most regulations and welfare spending, it serves to 
cartelize the economy.

By acting through the state to organize pension programs, the large 
corporations effectively function as a state-enforced cartel (with the 
added virtue of non-defectability), and at least partially remove old age 
pensions as an issue of competion in personnel costs.
This is just silly.  If the situation was competitive initially, employers 
just switch to cash compensation.

Indeed, this is just a variation on the popular fallacy that employers 
really do pay half of SS just because the law says so, when in reality it 
depends on labor supply and demand elasticities (and since the former is 
near-infinite, employers pay essentially 0% whether the law says they pay 
0% or 100%).
Regardless of whether pension costs are really passed on to workers, the 
supply of pension benefits is nevertheless an issue of competition between 
employers unless it is cartelized.  Are you suggesting that collusion in 
regard to some aspect of competition is irrelevant to the total 
competitiveness of the situation?  Why, then, the recurring talk of fighting 
the Canadian national health in the WTO as giving a competitive advantage to 
Canadian employers against U.S. firms that provide private coverage to 
employees?  And although demand elasticities are quite finite in an 
oligopoly market, they are nevertheless there.  So remuneration of labor 
remains an issue of competition between firms as far as the consumer is 
concerned.

The principle remains:  when the state intervenes in any area of the free 
market, it is effectively removing that area from the realm of competition, 
to the same extent as if corporations came to the arrangement by private 
agreement.



--
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  The game of just supposing
   Is the sweetest game I know...
   And if the things we dream about
   Don't happen to be so,
   That's just an unimportant technicality.
   Jerome Kern and Oscar Hammerstein, *Showboat*


_
Protect your PC - get McAfee.com VirusScan Online  
http://clinic.mcafee.com/clinic/ibuy/campaign.asp?cid=3963




Re: Wage-Price Controls Under Nixon

2003-06-18 Thread AdmrlLocke
Post-modern liberalism didn't spring full-blown into being like Athena from 
the forehead of Zeus.  It evolved rather over time from classical liberalism 
through several fairly-distinct phases.

In the earliest stages of progressivism people still by and large believed 
in free markets and private property, but believed that left entirely to 
themselves, free markets produced monopolies which had to be broken by antitrust 
action.  These early antitrust progressive are sometimes known as Brandeisians, 
and we see their imprint heavily upon Wilson's New Freedom platform.  The next 
stage of progressivism invovled allowing the big businesses to remain 
unbroken, but regulating them with the federal government, a few we find heavily 
influencing TR's New Nationalism platform of 1912.  New Nationalism contained no 
explicit calls for cartelization, but it evolved into Hoover's New 
Individualism (a rather contradicatory name for what it described) in which government 
would, mostly informally, support the cartelization agreements of Big Business.  
Hoover's voluntary cartelization finally, by the New Deal, evolved into 
outright calls for goverment-forced cartelization that heavily animated the NIRA of 
1933.  It's worth note that the Brandeisians fought the NIRA bitterly, and 
their influence on the Supreme Court got it declared unConstitutional.  
Cartelization remained anathema to old Progressives right through the New Deal.

David Levenstam

In a message dated 6/18/03 12:24:15 PM, [EMAIL PROTECTED] writes:

Actually, they support state capitalism under the name of progressivism
or 
putting people first or some equally inane goo-goo slogan.  Just about

every part of the Progressive/New Deal agenda reflected the interests of
big 
business in cartelizing and stabilizing the corporate economy;  it was
just 
sold to the public as a progressive restraint on big business.

Please bear in mind that what was called socialism by democratic 
socialists in the 1920s would not have been recognized as such by most
of 
the classical socialists of the nineteenth century.  The difference reflects

the New Class takeover of the working class movement, by Leninists and

Fabians, at the turn of the century.

Revisionist historians like Gabriel Kolko and James Weinstein called the

phenomenon political capitalism or corporate liberalism.  Murray 
Rothbard agreed with their analysis.  Whatever you call it, it is organized

capital acting through the state.  The court intellectuals of corporate

liberalism (Art Schlesinger) like to depict the movement as an idealistic

attempt to set countervailing power against the giant corporations. 
And a 
lot of big business propagandists like to howl about how anti-business

forces have won consistently.   But in fact, it is a case of Brer Rabbit

hollering Please don't fling me in that briar patch!