Re: [EM] Re2: Fobes wrt IRV w. relatively few competitive candidates.

2013-05-31 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 01:44 PM 5/29/2013, David L Wetzell wrote:
I believe the diff IRV makes makes it worth it.  Given the current 
habits of the US, I don't see advanced-systems havinge sufficient 
additional value-added to justify switching from the extensive 
marketing campaign already in place for IRV.  If things evolve, it 
will be easier to switch from IRV, in part because of widespread 
habituation to IRV and how it'll make it harder for those who 
benefit from the status quo to divide and conquer advocates of reform.


This has been, of course, the FairVote argument for a long time. 
FairVote, however, did not merely market IRV. They also deprecated 
other systems, such that the President of FairVote Arizona, putting 
on her Arizona League of Women Voters President hat, lobbied against 
the recent Approval initiative based on old FairVote arguments that 
actually did not apply to the circumstances where Approval has been 
proposed, old and discredited arguments, which she did not 
understand, promoted by FairVote. That's the problem with a divisive 
marketing campaign!


And it can backfire.

IRV was known as a seriously defective single-winner voting system, 
since it was proposed as the Ware system. It's a make the world safe 
for major parties system. It breaks down badly when a third party 
starts to attain parity, or passes parity, as in Burlington.


The FairVote campaign oversold IRV, and there is a backlash, 
implementations are being rescinded. Previously, IRV was dumped for 
(unfair) political reasons, as in Ann Arbor, MI. Much rescinding of 
late has not been unfair like that. It's been based on substantial 
method failure.


Because FairVote focused only on IRV for single-winner elections, it 
was not prepared for this. It recommended IRV blindly, regardless of 
context. In Burlingon, it's obvious, instead of going back to a 
plurality-satisfied (40% ) runoff voting, a hybrid could have been 
proposed: Bucklin, using the same 3-rank ballot, can handle a 
three-party situation with ease, tending to find a majority, and if 
no majority were found, it's then possible to design an optimal 
runoff. FairVote should be *ready* with alternatives, and ready to 
recommend them, not just to slink away.


In Arizona, it's quite possible that IRV could be ruled 
unconstitutional, because of the most legal votes standard of the 
Arizona constitution. IRV discards and does not consider some legal 
votes. Some it counts, some it does not, treating ballots 
differently. It's a problem. Because court decisions with regard to 
voting systems do not always consider all the issues, I can't predict 
how the Arizona Supreme Court would rule.


If my argument here is legally supported, what, then, should FairVote 
Arizona recommend, short of amending the constitution? Is Arizona hopeless?


Hint: Bucklin counts all the votes, and uses them. (There could be an 
issue with unused ranks, but my sense is that this would pass muster, 
because all ballots are treated equally, and all ranks are either 
counted or not.)


Bucklin is American preferential voting. Yet FairVote used invented 
arguments to discredit Bucklin, not election science. FairVote 
supported the decision in Brown v. Smallwood, when that decision 
would just as easily have dumped IRV, the arguments would be quite 
similar. The decision was idiosyncratic, not supported anywhere else, 
and not supported by the current Minnesota court. The point is that 
FairVote distorted the information available to the public, pursuing 
a narrow campaign for a particular method.


The case can be made that FairVote has done significant damage to 
election reform in the U.S., by attacking runoff voting, widely 
recognized as more democratic than raw plurality. Instead of 
*improving* runoff voting, IRV gutted it as an expensive nuisance. 
Replacing it with an expensive single-ballot system missing most of 
the advantages of actual runoff voting.


I'm hoping that FairVote will begin to cooperate with the Center for 
Election Science. We have certain common goals, most notably 
proportional representation. The question of optimal voting system is 
often dependent on the specific circumstances of a jurisdiction, and 
that, as well, can be studied. Yes, political practicality is a 
crucial issue for an advocacy group, but if what is advocated is 
*actually harmful*, what then? We need clear-thinking activists *and* 
we need election science.


How about it, David? 



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] A simple thought experiment.

2013-05-31 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 02:52 PM 5/29/2013, David L Wetzell wrote:
Also, the bottom line is that when you're advocating for a change in 
which single-winner election rule alternative ought to be used, it's 
not right to dump the burden of proof on IRV advocates.  The amount 
of time spent marketing IRV already is a sunk cost and so the burden 
of proof for switching ought to lie on the challengers not the 
defenders of the status quo progressive electoral alternative to fptp.


Sunk cost for you, David. The rest of us are singularly unimpressed. 
We didn't ask you to spend that time and money. Voting systems 
scientists have been advising strongly against the method you adopted 
since the 19th century.


The voting system community, including *many* former IRV supporters 
and even FairVote activists, settled on a first voting system reform 
propoosal, not as the ideal voting system, but as a do-no-harm 
improvement, Count All the Votes. I.e,. Approval Voting.


It will not fix all problems. But it costs almost nothing.

It has an obvious problem, but that problem only arises because, with 
it, voters who support a minor party will be able to express a vote 
for their favorite party, and all analysts agree that they will do 
this, it is strategically sound. Approval always allows voting for 
your favorite.


However, once voters can do this, they will *also* want to be able to 
express a preference for their favorite, which they cannot do in 
Approval where they choose to support, say, their minor party 
favorite and to cast a vote in the major election.


This is the problem that IRV solves. However, the problem was solved 
long ago, with a voting system that does not have IRV's serious 
malfunctions: Bucklin. It's ranked approval voting. It actually uses 
a truncated Range ballot, this has often been missed by analysts. A 
voter who has a strong preference can skip ranks to express it, 
causing the second preference vote to show up in a later round of 
canvassing. I call that Limited Later-no-Harm protection. Voters 
will use this -- or bullet vote -- depending on preference strength, 
which is precisely how the system performs well in utility evaluations.


Bucklin was oversold, as was IRV recently, as a way to guarantee 
majorities. No voting system can do that except by restricting the 
freedom of the voter, in which case the majority is coerced or 
artificial. However, in contested public elections, Bucklin *did* 
find majorities even with many candidates on the ballot. Later, in 
party primary elections, with many candidates and bullet voting rates 
approaching 90%, it didn't find majorities. In that context, runoff 
voting makes *much more sense,* because what voters need is 
*information.* It's not about Later-no-Harm failure, an old 
speculation that FairVote enshrined as being The Reason why Bucklin 
didn't find majorities. And, given that, what would really have made 
sense would have been a Bucklin primary, with intelligent choice of 
runoff candidates if needed. And maybe a Bucklin runoff; with an 
advanced voting system, finding a optimal winner with three 
candidates should be possible.


Bucklin is *vastly* easier to canvass than IRV, it is just sums of votes.

So, David, sunk cost is also water under the bridge. What you have 
left is an organization with some established reputation. How you use 
that will determine if all the cost is truly sunk, or there is 
something that can be salvaged and used to build a brighter future. 



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Why LTPs/Am forms of PR matter for more local democracy...

2013-05-31 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 03:09 PM 5/30/2013, David L Wetzell wrote:
* LR Hare has one vote per voter and one candidate per party and one 
or two vice-candidates on the party-list who win the extra seats if 
a party's candidate wins multiple seats.  But the top candidate 
would have to beat the third place candidate by more than one-third 
of the vote to win two seats and (s)he'd have to beat the 2nd place 
candidate by more than two-thirds of the vote to win all three 
seats.  So if the vote %s were 40:30:20:10 then there'd be 3 
winners.  If they were 50:35:10:5 then the top candidate would win 
two seats and her/his vice-candidate would hold the second seat.  If 
they were 80:10:5:5 then the top candidate would win all three seats 
and get to choose two vice-candidates (or have her/his list 
specified before the election) but that outcome is not likely 
outside of Russia or other DINO areas.


Party-list PR is interesting, and STV is a very fair system for 
handling it. I'm not going to get into best system yet. If we are 
looking at a practical possibility in the U.S., we will need to 
answer that question. There is no sunk cost, so to speak.


Asset Voting was originally a tweak on STV. Most voters only know 
their favorite. I find it interesting that David assumes that an 
asset-like condition is possible, either by free choice of the 
candidate, or by a predetermined list. In the long run, I find the 
former to be the deepest reform because it can take us *beyond* the 
party system to something that can shade into direct/representative 
democracy, a profound transformation.


Possible in NGOs, immediately.

Now, the quota. It's clear that the Hare quota creates proportionally 
fair winners, generally the first two. What about that third seat? 
The Droop quota gives more voting power to the winners of the first 
two seats, effectively. It treats all seats equally.


The Hare quota gives minority representation better. In a two-party 
system, the Hare quota is more likely to elect a minority party 
candidate. It does not go too far in this. That candidate *will* be 
elected with fewer assigned voters, by definition.


In the Asset systems I've proposed, I've used the Hare quota, and 
*tolerate* the possible unfilled seat. I'd allow the unrepresented 
votes to be cast *directly* on Assembly issues. These are public 
voters, those votes could be cast over the internet without the 
security issues we associate with internet voting. (All votes would 
be public.) So the function of a *seat*, then, is representation in 
deliberation: in introducing motions, and in debating on the floor, 
this can be distinguished from amalgamation, actual choice.


However short of that, Hare will accomplish this goal better than 
Droop: a goal that the number of citizens who are represented in the 
Assembly be maximized. Hare will produce a *slight* bias toward 
minority representation over Droop. That's not going to give away the 
assembly to a minority party, just give them a voice.


Obviously, using larger districts will enhance this. But what about 
the desire of local representation? That can happen spontaneously. 
Under full Asset, people will very likely tend, most of them, to vote 
for someone local, and because full Asset does not waste votes, it's 
totally safe to vote without any restriction as to electability.


I know that I'd prefer a representative in an Assembly who lives 
relatively far from me, but who represents me more accurately, to one 
who is close but with whom I cannot communicate well. After all, 
there is the telephone and email and, even, snailmail.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] What are the approaches you advocate for?

2013-05-31 Thread Richard Fobes

On 5/30/2013 12:44 PM, David L Wetzell wrote:

...
dlw: If neither can dominate and we have some exit threat between them
and away from them, possibly changing the specific two parties at the
top or forcing them to merge with a growing (or regionally strong) third
party, then it'll be easier to check the influence of special interests
on both of them.
...
I also think that 3rd party aficionados will recognize that the
imperative is to incorporate the use of PR asap so as to mitigate the
cut-throat competition between the two major parties that prevents us
from making progress on so many issues that desperately need change and
to trust that as a result of the changed rules that both major parties
would be seriously changed for the better even if their names do not change.


Rather than giving up on voter control of the Republican and Democratic 
parties, I want to increase voter influence on these two parties.  That 
is why I promote reforming *primary* elections.


I agree that third-party candidates should win often enough to indicate 
the extent to which the main parties (which could be more than two at a 
distant future time) fail to be controlled by the voters.


Privately David asked:
 What are the approaches you advocate for?

For primary-election reform (which are single-winner contests) I promote 
VoteFair popularity ranking, which is mathematically equivalent to the 
Condorcet-Kemeny method.


(IRV cannot handle enough candidates for this purpose.  Approval voting 
would provide improvements here, but I'm not a supporter of approval 
voting for widespread use.)


For multi-winner use I promote VoteFair representation ranking.  It is 
unlike any other voting method I've seen.  Details are at:


http://www.votefair.org/calculation_details_representation.html

(STV is inferior to this method.)

In addition I advocate the use of VoteFair party ranking to identify 
political-party popularity.  Those results would be used to allow the 
two most-representative parties to offer two candidates in each race, 
and would limit less-popular parties to either one or zero candidates in 
each race.


(IRV cannot handle this kind of general election.  Let's say it's a 
Congressional election in which there are two Republican candidates, two 
Democratic candidates, one Green-party candidate, one [whatever] 
candidate, and no additional candidates.)


To solve the gerrymandering problem I advocate using VoteFair 
representation ranking in double-size districts (to elect the two most 
representative candidates in each district), plus having some additional 
seats filled based on party-based proportionality. ...


... But choosing the candidate for the proportional seats would NOT be 
done using any kind of party list, and instead would be based on which 
district-based candidate lost in their district yet demonstrated he or 
she is the most popular candidate (of the specified party) compared to 
the other losing candidates (of that party) in the other districts.


The full approach includes providing for a smooth transition to better 
elections.  And the approach includes a proposed Constitutional 
amendment for reforming Presidential elections, which involves 
complications that IRV advocates don't seem to be aware of.


(IRV advocates seem to think that after adopting IRV in more places, the 
details for dealing with IRV's limitations [especially its inability to 
handle three somewhat-equally popular political parties] can be worked 
out later.)


Broadly speaking, in the context of this discussion with David about 
FairVote (not VoteFair) strategy, I do not see either FairVote or IRV 
advocates promoting a full election system that works together.


Instead I hear let's use IRV here, and STV there, but stay with 
plurality voting there and there, and let's ignore the consequence of a 
third-party presidential candidate winning some electoral votes and 
preventing any candidate from winning a majority of electoral votes, and 
we're confident that everything will all work out.


IRV and STV have been tried elsewhere (notably Australia) and those 
governments are just as corrupt as the U.S. (single-mark-ballot-based) 
and European (PR-based) election systems.


Ironically most IRV advocates say they want third parties to grow, yet 
IRV cannot handle more than (let's say) 3 main candidates in a general 
election, so that will lead to a dead end if there should turn out to be 
four main parties.


Richard Fobes


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] apologies, m going on vacation til 16th,

2013-05-31 Thread David L Wetzell
I will gladly respond to Richard F and Abd Lomax shortly after then...
dlw

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info