Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-23 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Kathy Dopp wrote:

James,

Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters are
allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an election contest.
That may be true in Australia, but is not true in the US where
typically voters are allowed to rank up to only three candidates.


As a note: some methods (most discussed here, actually) also permit both 
truncation and equal-ranking. If one takes that into account, the 
formulas become more complex still.


Yet, on another level, this may not really matter. On the one hand, if 
there'll ever just be a few candidates, the amount of information to 
transmit is managable. On the other, setting a hard limit to, say, no 
more than 5 candidates may participate in this election is rather 
inelegant, and I would say, unfair, and if the potential number of 
candidates can grow to any number, it doesn't matter what formula is 
being used as long as it's superpolynomial (and so the values grow very 
large very quickly). Truncation or no truncation, equal rank or not, the 
number of unique orderings grow in that manner.


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-23 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 09:52 PM 1/22/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

now remember in the case we're discussing here, there is only two
candidates.  again, what consequence to the outcome of the election
(that is, who of A or B wins) occurs whether a ballot is marked
A (and B is last by default) or is marked AB?

there is none.


If there are only two possible choices, that's the case. However, in 
fully democratic elections, the only case where there are only two 
choices is election by motion. The question is of the form of 
Resolved: that A be elected to the office. Yes/No.


I will be putting together a document that compiles relevant rules 
and discussion from Robert's Rules of Order as it relates to voting, 
elections, ballots, and particularly preferential voting, because I 
consider an understanding of deliberative election process as 
essential to understanding voting system optimization. It is far more 
sophisticated than any voting system on the table, and the only 
problem is one of efficiency. While it is a method of election, in 
the general sense, it has been neglected because it is very difficult 
to study. It is not deterministic from a single set of preference 
profiles, even if they include preference strength information.


In public elections where write-in votes are allowed (which is so 
much the norm in the U.S. that it is preposterous to neglect it, and 
sometimes write-in candidates win), there are actually a practically 
unlimited number of optional votes. That *normally* write-in votes 
are largely irrelevant does not change this. The methods must allow 
for the possibility. So, as a compromise, canvassing methods may 
neglect the possible variety of write-in votes, and canvass them as 
if for a single candidate. But, then, if the number of votes for the 
single write-in candidate, were they all one candidate, possibly 
affect the result, it becomes necessary to count and report those 
individual write-in votes. I have not detailed how this would be 
done, and it is possible that, depending on conditions, it could be 
made more efficient than simply reporting every vote. But in some 
cases, reporting every vote might be necessary!



i'm not going to discuss this any more with Abd, because he's not a
straight shooter, but James, if you want to get into this, it's
pretty much cut and dried from the POV of Information Theory (a.la.
Claude Shannon).


This conclusion depends on understanding the situation to which the 
theory is being applied. That's what Robert misses. He makes 
simplifying assumptions without being aware that these assumptions 
are not applicable in the general case, but he does not specify the 
assumptions, nor does he take note of them when they are specified by 
others, including me, he merely concludes that I'm not a straight 
shooter, which would imply some deceptive intent, but he has adduced 
no evidence of that, merely his idea that I am wrong, which he has 
repeated over and over as if that would establish it as a fact, 
rather than a detailed examination of the evidence and arguments. His 
privilege, here.



1.  there are three eligible candidates, A, B, and C.
2.  a particular voter has A as his/her first preference.
3.  the same voter has B as the second preference.
4.  the same voter has C as the last preference.


The question is whether or not the vote ABC is different from AB, 
whether or not the difference is worth reporting, or, stronger, 
necessary to report. And that depends on details of the rules, which 
Robert has neither stated nor accepted, and he has denied, without 
evidence, comments that did specify exceptions to the rules he 
proposes, -- not made-up, but real-world exceptions.


I'll give the most notable: if a majority is required for election, 
and according to accepted parliamentary procedure, majority means 
more than half of all non-black ballots cast. Whether or not a 
candidate is eligible or not is irrelevant! Robert has adduced a 
preference profile, but has not specified one critical piece of 
information, in determining the relevance of an ABC vote compared 
to AB. Is the voter willing to accept the result of the election of 
C, or would the voter prefer that the election fail? In short, does 
the voter approve of the election of C? We cannot tell that from the 
raw preference profile without approval information.


I gave examples -- and analyzed Robert's examples -- where the two 
votes are different in consequence.


Now, let's narrow the question, being aware that we are now more 
narrowly specifying it. If the election is election by plurality, 
does the third preference vote make a practical difference? Not in 
determining the result, but it is still important in assessing 
election quality, and examples could be shown where this is important 
as public information. There are rarely IRV elections which are by 
plurality, where, if the counting is continued one more step, the 
election would be by a majority. Even though this is 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 12:25 AM
 On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:05 PM, James Gilmour wrote:
 
  N Unique Preference Profiles
  2 4
  3 15
  ...
 
  then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you 
 ostensibly need 
  4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.
 
 
  If there are two candidates, A and B, then the possible unique  
  preference profiles are:
  A   
  B   
  AB 
  BA
 
 
 
 what, on a ballot, is the consequential difference in meaning between  
 A and AB?  what effect does a ballot marked AB have over one  
 marked just A (or vise versa) in *any* election method that uses  
 ranked ballots?

In terms of preference profiles the question is completely irrelevant.  A 
and AB are two different preference profiles.  So
the possible numbers of preference profiles for given numbers of candidates 
are, I think, correctly stated in the table in my
earlier post.

How the STV counting rules handle the two preference profiles A and AB is 
a different matter.  Some STV counting rules handle
these two profiles identically.  But for some other STV counting rules the 
profiles A and AB are handled differently.  This
second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes to the 
bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been
determined.  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated differently 
from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable (exhausted)', but the 
AB ballot would be transferred to A.

This second rule is, of course, a stupid rule but that does not mean it has not 
been implemented in some jurisdictions, including,
sadly, Scotland.  It is also a highly undesirable rule because it means that my 
vote could, in some circumstances, be transferred to
the candidate I deliberately ranked last in the lowest possible place, e.g. 
12th out of 12 candidates.  Following on from the
concept of 'Later No Harm' (which underpins the whole of contingency voting, as 
in IRV and STV-PR), it is very important to be able
to give a voter the absolutely assurance that under no circumstances will her 
vote ever be transferred to the candidate she has
ranked 12th out of 12.  Sadly, the stupid transfer to the bitter end rule 
undermines this.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy
I think my post made clear that I was referring only to preference profiles.  
I was not dealing with the situation where some
artificial, and highly undesirable, restriction had been placed on the numbers 
of rankings the voters could mark.

I think my comments about the counting procedure adopted in Minneapolis should 
have indicated that I am well aware of the
restrictions that can be imposed.  But note that in Minneapolis the restriction 
was an artificial one imposed by the certified
counting machines available for use in the precincts.  There is nothing in the 
Minneapolis Election Ordinance that imposes such a
restriction.  So when Minneapolis can obtain certified counting machines that 
can deal with fully ranked ballots, there will be no
such restriction in practice.

James

 Behalf Of Kathy Dopp
 Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 12:43 AM
 Subject: Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)
 
 
 James,
 
 Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters 
 are allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an 
 election contest. That may be true in Australia, but is not 
 true in the US where typically voters are allowed to rank up 
 to only three candidates.
 
 I put the general formula that applies to *all* cases with n 
 candidates and with r rankings allowed in my paper on IRV 
 that I wrote a year or two ago:
 
 Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting 
 http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantR
 unoffVotingFlaws.pdf
 
 
 Because it's hard to write a summation, fraction formula, 
 etc. here I'll let you look it up. It's on page 6 of the doc 
 linked above.
 
 Cheers,
 
 Kathy
 
 
 
  From: James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk
  I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the 
  numbers of possible unique preference profiles for 
 increasing numbers 
  of candidates (N) as follows:
 
  N       Unique Preference Profiles
  2       4
  3       15
  4       64
  5       325
  6       1,956
  7       13,699
  8       109,600
  9       986,409
  10      9,864,100
  11      108,505,111
  12      1,302,061,344
  13      16,926,797,485
  14      236,975,164,804
  15      3,554,627,472,075
  16      56,874,039,553,216
  17      966,858,672,404,689
  18      17,403,456,103,284,400
  19      330,665,665,962,404,000
  20      6,613,313,319,248,080,000
 
 
  Where there are large numbers of candidates, the maximum possible 
  number of unique preference profiles will be limited by the 
 number of 
  voters.  Thus if there are 10,000 valid votes and 12 
 candidates, the 
  maximum possible number of preference profiles would be 
 10,000 and not 
  1,302,061,344.
 
  In practice the actual number of preference profiles would be even 
  lower, as significant numbers of voters would record identical 
  patterns of preferences.  Thus in the Meath constituency 
 for the D?il 
  ?ireann election in 2002 with 14 candidates (236,975,164,804 
  possibilities), there were 64,081 valid votes, but only 
 25,101 unique 
  preference profiles.
 
 
  The Minneapolis STV (RCV) ballots were all hand sorted to unique 
  preference profiles for each precinct and hand counted.  This was 
  unnecessary but feasible as the voters could not record more than 
  three preferences (rankings), no matter the numbers of 
 candidates. I 
  understand the full preference profiles, probably at 
 precinct level, 
  will be published on the City website, but they are not there yet.
 
  James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Kathy Dopp
OK James. As I said before, I agree with you that you were giving the
total number of profiles *if* voters were allowed to rank all
candidates, which they were not allowed to do in Minneapolis or
elsewhere in the US public elections if I am right.

Further, I think that Robert is correct, that one could collapse the
last N profiles into prior profiles if that is the system that is used
(allowing ranking all candidates), although I do not think that gives
any advantage, practically, to the counting process and may even
complicate it.

My formula provides the more practical number of how many profiles are
allowed to be cast by voters and how many profiles are needed if one
wants to count the number of votes cast for each profile and make IRV
precinct-summable for an actual election.

Obviously Condorcet counting methods are much simpler to make
precinct-summable than IRV, requiring far fewer number of sums per
precinct as the number of candidates increases.

I think one thing that some election methods experts sometimes fail to
consider are the election administration practicalities that are
crucial to whether or not a method is functionally practical to
provide public oversight over.

I am fully aware that it is voting system technology, costs, and the
increasing impracticality of manually auditing the election if the
full range of preference profiles is allowed, if one is making an
attempt to use paper ballots, that limits the number of choices a
voter may fill out.  I've studied this issue for 7 years now.

Cheers,

Kathy

On Fri, Jan 22, 2010 at 4:08 AM, James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk wrote:
 Kathy
 I think my post made clear that I was referring only to preference 
 profiles.  I was not dealing with the situation where some
 artificial, and highly undesirable, restriction had been placed on the 
 numbers of rankings the voters could mark.

 I think my comments about the counting procedure adopted in Minneapolis 
 should have indicated that I am well aware of the
 restrictions that can be imposed.  But note that in Minneapolis the 
 restriction was an artificial one imposed by the certified
 counting machines available for use in the precincts.  There is nothing in 
 the Minneapolis Election Ordinance that imposes such a
 restriction.  So when Minneapolis can obtain certified counting machines that 
 can deal with fully ranked ballots, there will be no
 such restriction in practice.

 James

 Behalf Of Kathy Dopp
 Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 12:43 AM
 Subject: Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)


 James,

 Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters
 are allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an
 election contest. That may be true in Australia, but is not
 true in the US where typically voters are allowed to rank up
 to only three candidates.

 I put the general formula that applies to *all* cases with n
 candidates and with r rankings allowed in my paper on IRV
 that I wrote a year or two ago:

 Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
 http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantR
 unoffVotingFlaws.pdf


 Because it's hard to write a summation, fraction formula,
 etc. here I'll let you look it up. It's on page 6 of the doc
 linked above.

 Cheers,

 Kathy



  From: James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk
  I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the
  numbers of possible unique preference profiles for
 increasing numbers
  of candidates (N) as follows:
 
  N       Unique Preference Profiles
  2       4
  3       15
  4       64
  5       325
  6       1,956
  7       13,699
  8       109,600
  9       986,409
  10      9,864,100
  11      108,505,111
  12      1,302,061,344
  13      16,926,797,485
  14      236,975,164,804
  15      3,554,627,472,075
  16      56,874,039,553,216
  17      966,858,672,404,689
  18      17,403,456,103,284,400
  19      330,665,665,962,404,000
  20      6,613,313,319,248,080,000
 
 
  Where there are large numbers of candidates, the maximum possible
  number of unique preference profiles will be limited by the
 number of
  voters.  Thus if there are 10,000 valid votes and 12
 candidates, the
  maximum possible number of preference profiles would be
 10,000 and not
  1,302,061,344.
 
  In practice the actual number of preference profiles would be even
  lower, as significant numbers of voters would record identical
  patterns of preferences.  Thus in the Meath constituency
 for the D?il
  ?ireann election in 2002 with 14 candidates (236,975,164,804
  possibilities), there were 64,081 valid votes, but only
 25,101 unique
  preference profiles.
 
 
  The Minneapolis STV (RCV) ballots were all hand sorted to unique
  preference profiles for each precinct and hand counted.  This was
  unnecessary but feasible as the voters could not record more than
  three preferences (rankings), no matter the numbers of
 candidates. I
  understand the full preference profiles, probably

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 1:42 PM
 
 OK James. As I said before, I agree with you that you were 
 giving the total number of profiles *if* voters were allowed 
 to rank all candidates, which they were not allowed to do in 
 Minneapolis or elsewhere in the US public elections if I am right.

In STV elections (STV, IRV, RCV) there should be NO restrictions of any kind on 
the number of rankings each voter may mark, up to
the limit of the number of candidates.  The voters should be completely free to 
mark as many or as few rankings as each wishes.


 Further, I think that Robert is correct, that one could 
 collapse the last N profiles into prior profiles if that is 
 the system that is used (allowing ranking all candidates), 
 although I do not think that gives any advantage, 
 practically, to the counting process and may even complicate it.

As I explained in my earlier post, whether or not you can do that depends on 
the version of the STV counting rules you have to use.


 My formula provides the more practical number of how many 
 profiles are allowed to be cast by voters and how many 
 profiles are needed if one wants to count the number of votes 
 cast for each profile and make IRV precinct-summable for an 
 actual election.

But if you do not report the complete preference profiles, down the last 
preference position (whether or not it is relevant to the
count), you reduce the transparency of the process.  The full ballot data 
should be published as soon as possible after the
election.  To provide complete information in the smallest size, the STV ballot 
data should be published as preference profiles,
i.e. COMPLETE preference profiles.  The BLT format is convenient for this.  The 
full ballot data from the 2007 STV-PR local
government elections in the City of Glasgow (Scotland) were published on the 
City Council's website as very soon after the count
closed on the day after polling.  They are still all there for inspection.


 Obviously Condorcet counting methods are much simpler to make 
 precinct-summable than IRV, requiring far fewer number of 
 sums per precinct as the number of candidates increases.

If you are going to do a manual sort of the ballots, then making three piles 
for each pair-wise comparison (AB, BA, neither
ranked) would involve less work than sorting to complete preference profiles.  
But if you have sensible processing equipment that
task is trivial and the difference irrelevant.


 I think one thing that some election methods experts 
 sometimes fail to consider are the election administration 
 practicalities that are crucial to whether or not a method is 
 functionally practical to provide public oversight over.

The practicalities of election administration are extremely important and as a 
returning officer for some elections, I am well aware
of that.  But electoral administration must not be allowed to put artificial or 
convenient limitations on the democratic process.


 I am fully aware that it is voting system technology, costs, 
 and the increasing impracticality of manually auditing the 
 election if the full range of preference profiles is allowed, 
 if one is making an attempt to use paper ballots, that limits 
 the number of choices a voter may fill out.  I've studied 
 this issue for 7 years now.

We have absolutely no problems with any of this in our STV public elections in 
the UK.  We always take all our paper ballots to one
counting centre for each electoral district.  In Northern Ireland, the ballots 
are sorted and counted manually, under scrutiny.  In
Scotland in 2007 we used optical scanning equipment and OCR to produce the vote 
vector for each ballot and the vote vectors were
then consolidated into preference profiles for the STV counting program.  All 
the ballot handling was done under scrutiny.  There
are always some who are unhappy with the results (defeated candidates and their 
supporters!), but the process has not been
challenged.

James

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Kathy Dopp
On Fri, Jan 22, 2010 at 11:10 AM, James Gilmour
jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk wrote:
 Kathy Dopp   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 1:42 PM
 My formula provides the more practical number of how many
 profiles are allowed to be cast by voters and how many
 profiles are needed if one wants to count the number of votes
 cast for each profile and make IRV precinct-summable for an
 actual election.

 But if you do not report the complete preference profiles, down the last 
 preference position (whether or not it is relevant to the
 count), you reduce the transparency of the process.  The full ballot data 
 should be published as soon as possible after the
 election.  To provide complete information in the smallest size, the STV 
 ballot data should be published as preference profiles,
 i.e. COMPLETE preference profiles.  The BLT format is convenient for this.  
 The full ballot data from the 2007 STV-PR local
 government elections in the City of Glasgow (Scotland) were published on the 
 City Council's website as very soon after the count
 closed on the day after polling.  They are still all there for inspection.

James, you are using a straw man argument with me, setting up a false
premise that I said something I never did, rather than responding to
my formula which is more broad and general than yours. I.e. your
formula is a subset of mine where r, the number of candidates voters
may rank is equal to the number of candidates. Recall it was Robert
who suggested collapsing and not reporting all of the exact
preferences specified by voters, not myself, although I agree with
Robert that if the number of candidates equals the number of rankings
allowed, it could be collapsed for any IRV counting method I've heard
of, although you say that there are methods I've never heard of where
it could not be collapsed.

To require, as you suggest that all election be administered in a way
that allows all voters to fully rank all candidates may sounds nice
and would eliminate one of the problems with IRV, but with so many
election contests on one ballot here in the US, it would be costly and
possibly impractical unless you insist on using inauditable, easily
hacked, electronic ballots and touchscreen devices rather than
auditable voter marked paper ballots.

As I said earlier, if paper ballots are required, the length of the
paper ballot must be unlimited if the number of candidates who can run
for office is unlimited and you want voters to be able to fully rank
(not that most voters would want to.)

Dealing with practical election administration issues seem to be very
low down on the totem pole for most electoral methods people it seems.



 Obviously Condorcet counting methods are much simpler to make
 precinct-summable than IRV, requiring far fewer number of
 sums per precinct as the number of candidates increases.

 If you are going to do a manual sort of the ballots, then making three piles 
 for each pair-wise comparison (AB, BA, neither
 ranked) would involve less work than sorting to complete preference profiles. 
  But if you have sensible processing equipment that
 task is trivial and the difference irrelevant.


Sorting ballots is not a logically coherent method of counting
Condorcet ballots James, so I'm not sure what you mean. Also, of
course three piles only works for the first round of sorting for an
IRV-type of count in the special case where there are three candidates
running for office, not for the general case of IRV and not for
Condorcet, so I have no idea what you're thinking about.

If you reread one of my recent emails, I describe the two methods for
handcounting IRV and the two methods for counting Condorcet.  The only
methods they have in common is to begin by sorting into all the unique
votes.  Sorting ballots into piles and confusing subpiles only works
for IRV and does not work for STV, except if there are no
transferrable votes or you want to cut up pieces of ballots or xerox
copies of ballots (what a confusing mess that would be.)




 I think one thing that some election methods experts
 sometimes fail to consider are the election administration
 practicalities that are crucial to whether or not a method is
 functionally practical to provide public oversight over.

 The practicalities of election administration are extremely important and as 
 a returning officer for some elections, I am well aware
 of that.  But electoral administration must not be allowed to put artificial 
 or convenient limitations on the democratic process.


Except in the case of such methods as IRV when the method is not only
wholly inconvenient and costly and virtually impossible to hand count
understandably and quickly and is also unfair and produces awful
outcomes.

A simpler method to administer is always preferable, other things
being equal, to a complex costly method such as IRV, but IRV does not
even provide any reason to use it since it fails more fairness
criteria than plurality, takes us backwards in election fairness 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Jonathan Lundell
On Jan 22, 2010, at 8:54 AM, Kathy Dopp wrote:

 As I said earlier, if paper ballots are required, the length of the
 paper ballot must be unlimited if the number of candidates who can run
 for office is unlimited and you want voters to be able to fully rank
 (not that most voters would want to.)

What point are you making here? If the number of candidates is unlimited, then 
so is the length of the ballot, but that's true for any method that lists the 
candidates, including fptp and Condorcet methods.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 03:57 AM 1/22/2010, James Gilmour wrote:

This
second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes 
to the bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been
determined.  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated 
differently from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable 
(exhausted)', but the AB ballot would be transferred to A.


You mean transferred to B, of course.

This second rule is, of course, a stupid rule but that does not mean 
it has not been implemented in some jurisdictions, including,

sadly, Scotland.


Not stupid, precisely because of the difference between AB and A. 
The former is an acceptance of the last listed preference, the latter 
is not. It makes a difference if a majority is required. Not if it is 
not, though it might make a difference with some methods. But not IRV.


 It is also a highly undesirable rule because it means that my vote 
could, in some circumstances, be transferred to
the candidate I deliberately ranked last in the lowest possible 
place, e.g. 12th out of 12 candidates.


Basically, if there are as many ranks as candidates, don't vote for 
that last one! That's your choice, unless full ranking is required, 
in which case you *can't* vote the truncated vote and it is 
irrelevant if it's counted or not.



  Following on from the
concept of 'Later No Harm' (which underpins the whole of contingency 
voting, as in IRV and STV-PR), it is very important to be able
to give a voter the absolutely assurance that under no circumstances 
will her vote ever be transferred to the candidate she has
ranked 12th out of 12.  Sadly, the stupid transfer to the bitter 
end rule undermines this.


Only because of voter ignorance, an ignorance which has sometimes 
been encouraged by activists.


The ballot instructions should state that one should not rank any 
candidate one is not willing to support over alternatives. If there 
are twelve candidates on the ballot, and write-in votes are not 
allowed (is that the truth there)?, and a majority is not required, 
there should only be eleven ranks, not twelve. Otherwise the ballot 
encourages the behavior you don't like.


But with write-in votes allowed, you need twelve ranks to cover a 
single allowed write-in. So that's thirteen candidates. And then the 
ballot instruction is important, because otherwise voters will 
imagine they are voting maximally against a candidate with a ranking 
of 12th. Instead, in these conditions, it's a vote for a candidate as 
against any possible write-in, including one the voter might well 
have preferred if aware that a write-in candidate had a prayer.


You are right, there is a problem, but it isn't with the rule that 
continues to the end, it's with voter education. If a majority is not 
required, though, it's moot. But with better preferential voting 
methods than IRV, there is indeed a difference between AB and A.


I'm not at all convinced that full ranking provides useful 
information beyond the first few ranks. With Bucklin, three ranks are 
pretty obviously enough. In reality, in Bucklin elections, udner some 
conditions, only a bit over 10% of voters even used additional ranks.


It's not about later-no-harm, it's about how much information the 
voters have. If they have a strong preference for a frontrunner over 
all others, truncating is a perfectly sensible vote. It gets even 
more sensible if it's a runoff system.


If your voting method does indeed require a majority, why in the 
world do you add that 12th preference? By adding it, you are 
contributing to the community acceptance of the result, by 
withholding it, you are asking for a possible second chance for your favorite.


If a majority is required, the absolute Later No Harm promise of IRV 
is false. That's been missed by focus on the method as deterministic. 



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 4:54 PM
 James, you are using a straw man argument with me, setting up 
 a false premise that I said something I never did, 

Kathy, I was not setting up any straw man argument with you or anyone else.  I 
simply stated what a preference profile is and the
possible numbers of such profiles.  Anything else is not a preference profile 
and is irrelevant.

Of course, no-one in their right mind (or not under legal restraint) would do a 
manual count of STV ballots by sorting to preference
profiles.  It is completely unnecessary and would extend time taken for the 
count very greatly.  Sorting STV ballots to preference
profiles makes sense only in computerised counting.


 To require, as you suggest that all election be administered 
 in a way that allows all voters to fully rank all candidates 
 may sounds nice

No, Kathy it is not something that sounds nice  -  it is an essential 
requirement for the proper implementation of democratic
choice.  Any artificiality imposed constraint on that is a restriction of that 
democratic choice.  But I am aware that factors of
administrative convenience outweigh such considerations in some jurisdictions 
 -  it must be so, else they would never be
tolerated.


 and would eliminate one of the problems with 
 IRV, but with so many election contests on one ballot here in 
 the US, it would be costly and possibly impractical unless 
 you insist on using inauditable, easily hacked, electronic 
 ballots and touchscreen devices rather than auditable voter 
 marked paper ballots.

No, Kathy, here in the UK we do NOT use any easily hacked, electronic ballots 
and touchscreen devices.  We use good old-fashioned
paper ballots which we mark with a stubby pencil secured to the polling booth 
by a short length of string!  It is very old
technology, but it works, and it is extremely flexible in that this voting 
method (paper and pencil) can be adapted to any voting
system (and we use five different voting systems for public elections in 
Scotland).  And of course, where electronic counting is
employed, we always have the original paper ballots should anyone demand an 
audit.


 As I said earlier, if paper ballots are required, the length 
 of the paper ballot must be unlimited if the number of 
 candidates who can run for office is unlimited and you want 
 voters to be able to fully rank (not that most voters would want to.)

Length has not been a problem.


 Dealing with practical election administration issues seem to 
 be very low down on the totem pole for most electoral methods 
 people it seems.

I cannot speak for any other EM member, but practical election administration 
is an important priority for me, especially as I am
the returning officer for some elections and the supervising officer for some 
others.


CUT

 Sorting ballots into 
 piles and confusing subpiles only works for IRV and does not 
 work for STV, except if there are no transferrable votes or 
 you want to cut up pieces of ballots or xerox copies of 
 ballots (what a confusing mess that would be.)

If by STV you mean STV-PR (a multi-seat election), this statement is 
nonsense.  IF you are sorting ballots into unique preference
profiles, that is as easily done for STV-PR as it is for IRV.  Of course, as I 
have already said, it makes no sense to do that in a
manual count of any IRV or STV-PR election.  And when it comes to the practical 
transfer of ballots in an STV-PR election there is
no problem at all, whether you are dealing with whole vote transfers on an 
exclusion or fractional transfers of a surplus.


  The practicalities of election administration are extremely important 
  and as a returning officer for some elections, I am well aware of 
  that.  But electoral administration must not be allowed to put 
  artificial or convenient limitations on the democratic process.
 
 
 Except in the case of such methods as IRV when the method is 
 not only wholly inconvenient and costly and virtually 
 impossible to hand count understandably and quickly and is 
 also unfair and produces awful outcomes.

IRV and STV-PR are quite easy to count by hand and the procedures and the 
outcomes are widely understood.  They have been doing just
that in Ireland and Malta since 1920, and in Northern Ireland again since 1973. 
 The multi-seat count may take longer than one
plurality count, but that one multi-seat count replaces several plurality 
counts.  And of course, there is no comparison at all in
what is achieved in terms of fair and democratic representation of the voters  
-  which should always be the deciding factor.



 A simpler method to administer is always preferable, other 
 things being equal, to a complex costly method such as IRV, 

But of course, other thing are not equal.  And there are higher priorities in 
achieving democratic representation than cost and
complexity.


 but IRV does not even provide any reason to use it since it 
 fails more fairness criteria 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 09:33 PM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:42 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


James,

Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters are
allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an election contest.


James didn't put forth any formulae.  but he did put forth a table  ,
which appears to be consistent with

 N-1
P(N)  =  SUM{ N!/n! }
 n=0

he, appears to miss the same point as Abd and you do.


Okay, now, three missing Robert's point against Robert's superior 
opinion, as he insists, that totally ignores the substantial and 
thorough arguments and evidence presented and focuses on alleged 
errors in details.




That may be true in Australia, but is not true in the US where
typically voters are allowed to rank up to only three candidates.


where do you get your information, Kathy?  that is *not* at all the
case in the IRV election in Burlington VT.

or is Burlington untypical?


Yes, it is. Most IRV elections in the U.S. are Ranked Choice 
Voting, typically referring to a three-rank ballot, even if there 
are more than two candidates plus the write-in option.


Burlington allowed ranking of all candidates on the ballot. There 
were six slots and six candidates on the ballot. This allows full 
ranking, however, it is misleading a bit, because it encourages a 
voter to rank all the candidates, including the lowest preference, 
imagining that this last ranking is a vote against the candidate, 
when, in fact, it is a vote for the candidate under some conditions, 
a vote against every write-in, unless the voter explicitly ranks the 
write-in, which then *is* a vote against the unranked candidate.


Imagine that there is some write-in campaign that brings up a real 
possibility with, say, a three-rank ballot. With that 6-rank ballot, 
almost impossible for the candidate to win, because of the knee-jerk 
full ranking that some voters will do. If voters truncate, fine. 



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Abd ul-Rahman Lomax   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 5:53 PM
  At 03:57 AM 1/22/2010, James Gilmour wrote:
 This
 second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes
 to the bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been
 determined.  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated 
 differently from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
 transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable 
 (exhausted)', but the AB ballot would be transferred to A.
 
 You mean transferred to B, of course.

Apologies - my example was incomplete.  To illustrate this stupid rule 
properly, I should have posited two candidates, A and B, (or
just two left after all others have been eliminated), with A the winner.  Then 
consider two ballots, one marked B and the other
marked BA.  In the last round of a count under the to the bitter end 
transfer rule, the ballot marked B would be
'non-transferrable (exhausted)', but the vote on the BA ballot would be 
transferred to A.  It is illogical to treat these ballots
differently in an STV (contingency choice) election and it offends the 
underlying concepts of 'Later No Harm' to transfer the BA
ballot to A.


 This second rule is, of course, a stupid rule but that does not mean
 it has not been implemented in some jurisdictions, including,
 sadly, Scotland.
 
 Not stupid, precisely because of the difference between AB and A. 
 The former is an acceptance of the last listed preference, the latter 
 is not. It makes a difference if a majority is required. Not if it is 
 not, though it might make a difference with some methods. But not IRV.

But my comments were exclusively in the context of STV elections (IRV, STV-PR, 
RCV).


   It is also a highly undesirable rule because it means that my vote
  could, in some circumstances, be transferred to
 the candidate I deliberately ranked last in the lowest possible 
 place, e.g. 12th out of 12 candidates.
 
 Basically, if there are as many ranks as candidates, don't vote for 
 that last one! That's your choice, unless full ranking is required, 
 in which case you *can't* vote the truncated vote and it is 
 irrelevant if it's counted or not.

That's why when running an STV election where we can use write in boxes for 
all preferences, I always provide one fewer preference
box than the number of candidates (as I see you recommended in a later part of  
your post).  But all of our ballots for public
elections have the candidates names printed on them.


Following on from the
 concept of 'Later No Harm' (which underpins the whole of contingency
 voting, as in IRV and STV-PR), it is very important to be able
 to give a voter the absolutely assurance that under no circumstances 
 will her vote ever be transferred to the candidate she has
 ranked 12th out of 12.  Sadly, the stupid transfer to the bitter 
 end rule undermines this.
 
 Only because of voter ignorance, an ignorance which has sometimes 
 been encouraged by activists.

No, not at all.  This is a piece of nonsense that some have introduced into STV 
counting, especially since electronic counting
became available.  It does not feature in any of the long-established versions 
of STV counting rules promoted in the UK.

James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 21, 2010, at 8:54 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


At 05:17 PM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

  and i believe that it is perfectly
practical when the number of *credible* candidates is small.  doesn't
matter what the voting system is.  IRV, or whatever.


Yes. But how small? Don't use the bogus numbers that aren't at all  
realistic given real-world election rules,


lotsa blather deleted and left unresponded

being 54 and having voted in every prez election since Carter-Ford  
(and aware of the 1968 election with Wallace-Nixon-Humphery), i have  
never once seen a presidential election in the US that had more than  
two candidates with any chance of winning, and no more than three  
candidates of national salience.


so my bogus number is 3, maybe 4 at the most.  individual precincts  
could total 40 different virtual piles.  doesn't matter what the  
counting method is, those precinct summable pile tallies are  
sufficient to completely describe the election for those 4.





  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.


Okay, three candidates, A, B, C, the ballot possibilities are, to
be complete, much more than 9. I'll assume that write-ins are
illegal and void the ballot. Some of the possibilities are legally
equivalent to others, and in actual IRV ballot imaging, they are
collapsed and reported the same, to the displeasure of voting
security people who do want to know the error rate, which
includes overvoting and exact overvoting patterns. So-called ballot
images are not, generally. They are processed data reducing a
ballot to legally equivalent votes. The reduced set is this:

A
B
C
AB
AC
BA
BC
CA
CB

Note that this assumes a 2-rank ballot.


no, it can be a 3-rank ballot where the voter declines to rate their
last choice.  3rd choice is left unmarked.


I meant something a little different. I address the possibility of  
a 3-rank ballot in the next section. The basic issue here is  
whether or not the third rank is irrelevant or not. If it's  
irrelevant, I claim, it's not really a three-rank ballot, it's got  
two relevant ranks and one that means nothing. Why was it even there?




blather.  you said absolutely nothing of substance.


It also assumes that majority vote isn't important.


bullshit.  it (the number of consequential ballot permutations) has
nothing to do with it (whether or not majority vote is important).


This is, in fact, serious ignorance. Bullshit, properly used,  
allows things to grow. Consider where the growth lies here.


If a majority is required, there is a difference in meaning between  
BCA and BC. I will assume the counting method described by  
Robert's Rules of Order for preferential voting. 3 candidates


Situation with truncated B vote:
35 AB
34 BC
31 C

C eliminated, votes become

35 AB
34 B

Majority basis is 100. 51 votes are required to win. No majority, B  
eliminated. I would guess that Robert doesn't consider this step  
because he is used to thinking of plurality IRV, no majority  
required, and the counting can stop with the last two in that case.  
A would win.


35 AB. A is plurality winner, no majority, election fails. Who  
would be the runoff candidates? Under Robert's Rules, the question  
is unanswerable and undeterminable from the first round results.  
It's a new election. Under top two runoff rules, the rules were not  
designed for a preferential ballot, but I'd suggest considering  
*every IRV vote* as an approval, then pick the top two in that.


so you're making up rules to prove a point.  chapter 13, section 45  
of RONR (regarding preferential voting) have *no* consequential  
difference between marking the last preference last or deducing the  
same preference is last because it is the *only* one remaining unmarked.


there is no consequential difference between.

  35  AB
  34  BC
  31  C

and

  35  AB
  34  BCA
  31  C

or

  35  ABC
  34  BCA
  31  C

end of discussion.



 Pay attention, Robert, there is far more here than you imagine.


the problem for you is that i *am* paying attention.  you're wrong  
and, by examination, that fact that you're wrong becomes manifest.


the rest of the blather is deleted without comment.

people need to warned that, although you fancy yourself an expert,  
you are not.  you make things up.  they should just ignore you.



--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 22, 2010, at 3:57 AM, James Gilmour wrote:


robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 12:25 AM

On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:05 PM, James Gilmour wrote:


N   Unique Preference Profiles
2   4
3   15

...

then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you

ostensibly need

4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.



If there are two candidates, A and B, then the possible unique
preference profiles are:
A   
B   
AB  
BA




what, on a ballot, is the consequential difference in meaning between
A and AB?  what effect does a ballot marked AB have over one
marked just A (or vise versa) in *any* election method that uses
ranked ballots?


In terms of preference profiles the question is completely  
irrelevant.  A and AB are two different preference profiles.  So
the possible numbers of preference profiles for given numbers of  
candidates are, I think, correctly stated in the table in my

earlier post.

How the STV counting rules handle the two preference profiles A  
and AB is a different matter.  Some STV counting rules handle
these two profiles identically.  But for some other STV counting  
rules the profiles A and AB are handled differently.  This
second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes  
to the bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been

determined.


so what consequential difference is that?

  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated differently  
from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable  
(exhausted)', but the AB ballot would be transferred to A.


now remember in the case we're discussing here, there is only two  
candidates.  again, what consequence to the outcome of the election  
(that is, who of A or B wins) occurs whether a ballot is marked  
A (and B is last by default) or is marked AB?


there is none.

i'm not going to discuss this any more with Abd, because he's not a  
straight shooter, but James, if you want to get into this, it's  
pretty much cut and dried from the POV of Information Theory (a.la.  
Claude Shannon).  it's a discipline within my purview (being an  
electrical engineer that does signal processing), but the fundamental  
fact comes early.  for information to be transmitted from one  
location (the voter and his ballot) to another location (the ballot  
counters), it is necessary that such information does not exist at  
the destination prior.  Information Theory is about the measure of  
how much information is contained in a message and how many bits one  
bests commit to a message.


the first three statements following provide a non-zero amount of  
information (providing the destination was originally ignorant of the  
same).  the fourth statement (given the first three) has a measure of  
information of precisely zero (which means that it is inconsequential  
whether the message is transmitted or not).


1.  there are three eligible candidates, A, B, and C.
2.  a particular voter has A as his/her first preference.
3.  the same voter has B as the second preference.
4.  the same voter has C as the last preference.

when i taught Information Theory (just once, almost two decades ago),  
i was sorta enamored of some of George Carlin's humor and found an  
interesting example i used to illustrate a similar point.  Consider a  
weather forecast (say on TV).  If it were to say tonight's forecast:  
snow, that would have some real information and the number of bits  
needed to encode it is greater than zero.  But now consider Carlin's  
Hippie-Dippie Weatherman, Al Sleet: Tonight's forecast: Dark.  
Continued dark throughout most of the evening, with some widely- 
scattered light towards morning. If you're not considering Joshua in  
the Old Testament, how much information is in that forecast?


in general, the number of bits inherent to a particular message,  
given the probability of occurrence of the message, is:


I(m) = -log2( p(m) )(base 2 log and p(m) is the probability)

if p(m)=1, there is no information content in the message.   
committing bits or words or time to saying it is redundant.



again, the number of piles *necessary* (for recording and  
transmitting the information) when there are precisely N distinct  
candidates is


   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=1

not

   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=0

the latter redundantly (and unnecessarily) divides N! piles into  
twice that number with no difference of information between the two  
piles of each pair.



this is not social science.  it's not politics.  it's not opinion.   
it's just math.


i think i am now going to bow out of this.

it's similar to the alien abduction controversy.  no matter how many  
people claim to be abducted by extra-terrestials and can provide  
vivid and detailed information of they're alleged abduction (and even  
scars, where they stuck the needles in), 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 01:55 PM 1/22/2010, James Gilmour wrote:

Abd ul-Rahman Lomax   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 5:53 PM
  At 03:57 AM 1/22/2010, James Gilmour wrote:
 This
 second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes
 to the bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been
 determined.  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated
 differently from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
 transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable
 (exhausted)', but the AB ballot would be transferred to A.

 You mean transferred to B, of course.

Apologies - my example was incomplete.  To illustrate this stupid 
rule properly, I should have posited two candidates, A and B, (or
just two left after all others have been eliminated), with A the 
winner.  Then consider two ballots, one marked B and the other
marked BA.  In the last round of a count under the to the bitter 
end transfer rule, the ballot marked B would be
'non-transferrable (exhausted)', but the vote on the BA ballot 
would be transferred to A.  It is illogical to treat these ballots
differently in an STV (contingency choice) election and it offends 
the underlying concepts of 'Later No Harm' to transfer the BA

ballot to A.


If truncation is allowed, there is a difference, as you know. 
However, if a plurality of ballots is sufficient for victory, it's 
irrelevant to the result. The real difference shows up when a true 
majority is required.


In Australia, they use the term absolute majority as the quota that 
must be reached, but that is with mandatory full ranking. So there is 
never majority failure, absent a tie, and a majority is always found 
when there are only two candidates still standing. Where truncation 
is permitted, which is in a few places in Australia, they change the 
quota to a majority of votes for candidates not eliminated. That, 
too, never requires that last counting step.


But we have been discussing the general case, and that case most 
notably includes elections as described in Robert's Rules of Order, 
Newly Revised, RRONR 10th edition, where a single-transferable vote 
method is described for single-winner (and a multiwinner variation is 
also described, a detail I won't address). RRONR never permits 
election without a majority unless a special bylaw has been passed 
allowing election by plurality. Which is strongly discouraged.


FairVote managed to confuse nearly everyone with their description of 
what is in Robert's Rules. They have slightly modified their rhetoric 
since I started nailing them on this, so that generally they aren't 
actually lying any more, but they still cherry-pick and create 
deceptive implications. If a majority is sought, and full ranking is 
optional, and the ballots are ones on which the voter writes 
candidates in order of preference, going to the last elimination is 
quite proper, for one has thereby found all the ballots containing a 
vote for the leader. If that is not a majority of all ballots, the 
election fails.


And, yes, this violates Later No Harm. If only a plurality is 
required, Later No Harm is not violated. LNH is incompatible with a 
majority requirement, unless voters are coerced or misled, that is 
one of the dirty little secrets of IRV.


In RRONR elections, the voters are not constrained to a list of 
candidates. In the normal procedure, the ballots are blank, and the 
voter writes down the names of candidates, ranking them. The voter 
may vote for *anyone*, including ineligible candidates or Donald 
Duck, or, more importantly, Mr. None of the Above.


Why does RRONR even propose the STV method? Good question! They 
propose it in cases where repeated balloting is not considered 
practical. But they think of it as a way to find a majority, and they 
advise the voters to rank all the candidates, cautioning that if 
they don't, it is possible that no candidate will get a majority, 
thus requiring the election to be repeated.


Now, this is what I've found in studying U.S. elections with IRV. In 
partisan elections, IRV sometimes works and finds a better winner, 
clearly more democratic, than FPTP or Plurality. In nonpartisan 
elections, however, at least in these public elections studied, IRV 
simply reproduces the results of Plurality. There is enough evidence 
to come to the conclusion that exceptions would be rare and typically 
close elections.


We have been discussing the election in Burlington, Vermont. There, a 
naive impression can be created that Plurality would have elected 
Wright, the Republican, he did get the most first preference votes. 
However, prior to IRV being adopted there, they used top two runoff, 
with a 40% requirement for election, otherwise a runoff was held 
between the top two. The runoff would have been between Kiss and 
Wright. Likely result would have been the same as with IRV.


The problem is that, while Kiss was a better winner than Wright, the 
eliminated Democrat, Montroll, was a beats-all winner, based on the 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
WARNING: this is a metacommunication, about the communication process 
here and elsewhere in voting system advocacy, not about voting methods, per se.


At 01:48 AM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 20, 2010, at 11:23 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

Variation on previous post. Silly time!

At 02:31 PM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 12:05 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


Robert, your slip is showing.


what slip?  i don't have nuttin' under me kilt.


We already knew that.


you do?  you keep saying that you can see it.


Yes, I said that. Slip is showing is a metaphor, stating that 
something relatively unmentionable is visible. I can see something. 
Others can see something. Do you see or know what we see? Perhaps you 
do, but you are defending yourself as if you cannot see it. Others 
who do see it might respond differently.


This is meta talk, it's about the communication, not election 
methods. I will therefore limit it to what's relevant to the 
*extended* purposes of this list, which include voting system 
advocacy, not merely theory.


If you are going to be a public advocate, you will be much more 
effective if you know how your actions and words will be seen, and if 
you can learn as much as possible about debate tactics and strategy.



Silly hat, Off.

Robert, if you want to be effective in public debate,


what makes you think i'm not effective?  do you actually think you
were effective?


1. I suspect you are less effective than you can be. You get caught, 
easily, in irrelevancies, distracting from the central points to be 
conveyed. As a public activist, to be effective, you must use polemic 
and all the skills of advocacy, which is different from discussion. 
Here, we discuss, and no collective decisions are actually made here. 
However, I inferred from behavior here what might happen in a public 
debate. If, in fact, some of this behavior carries over to public 
debate, you could get creamed. Unnecessarily. That is, over your own 
style and personality, not over the issue you are advocating.


2. Was I effective? In what? I'm engaged only in a diffuse kind of 
advocacy here. However, I've also repeated ideas that I've expressed 
here many times, and this is part of my own learning and polishing 
process. This is of benefit to those who find it useful to follow my 
discussions, to explore these topics repeatedly so that they become 
familiar, and so that deeper understanding spreads. It's my method 
and approach, and it certainly is not for everyone. Were I to do in a 
public forum, not a specialized forum like this, what I do here, I'd 
almost completely fail.


(3.) I have, however, come to the point that I'm sufficiently 
familiar with the issues that I'd engage, if invited, in public 
debate. I'm an effective speaker, making clear and direct contact 
with the audience. We'll see if that happens. I have made blog posts 
in public fora on these issues, they are far briefer, in general. The 
effort per word and per message is much higher for them.



i won't slap on the argumentum verbosium and explode the debate
about a single testable issue (like how many piles one needs if there
are 3 candidates) into pages and pages, that when i responded, my
post was rejected by the list server as too large.


Oh, we are crushed at the loss actually, usually it isn't exactly 
rejected, it is held for moderator approval, which can take some time. Depends.



I'd suggest avoiding setting up an immediate victory by the other
side by feeding him or her lines like that.


you're the one feeding lines.


Sure. Like a debate opponent might. Your slip is showing is a 
metacommunication to the audience, calling attention very briefly to 
the opponent's behavior, or sometimes to an issue of substance 
(possibly). As an ad hominem argument, it's irrelevant, but in real 
debate, it could be very important. People respond to the person, 
usually, more than to the substance. They judge the substance by the 
person. Only in careful deliberative process is this effect reduced much.



  who brought up the slip showing in
the first place?


Me. A stand-in for your debate opponent. However, it wasn't intended 
as a debate tactic, but as personal advice, which you could take or 
leave. You took it, in fact, but as if it were bait in a debate, and 
you also took, therefore, the hook and the line. And in so doing, you 
got jerked out of the water. My judgement. Yours might be different, 
but if you really want to know, ask someone neutral.



  how does one respond when facing: Your slip is
showing, now onto a verbose response that does not speak to the core
factual issues at all.


How? It's actually terminally easy. No response at all is probably 
the most efficient. A quick joke, though, may be even more efficient. 
Learn to think on your feet, if you have to puzzle over this, no 
response is better. Robert, your slip is showing was very efficient 
for me, it took, 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 21, 2010, at 3:24 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

WARNING: this is a metacommunication, about the communication  
process here and elsewhere in voting system advocacy, not about  
voting methods, per se.


At 01:48 AM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 20, 2010, at 11:23 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

Variation on previous post. Silly time!

At 02:31 PM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 12:05 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


Robert, your slip is showing.


what slip?  i don't have nuttin' under me kilt.


We already knew that.


you do?  you keep saying that you can see it.


Yes, I said that. Slip is showing is a metaphor, stating that  
something relatively unmentionable is visible. I can see something.  
Others can see something. Do you see or know what we see? Perhaps  
you do, but you are defending yourself as if you cannot see it.  
Others who do see it might respond differently.


better say what it is right now, or you're just blowing smoke (to  
make use of another metaphor).


1. I suspect you are less effective than you can be. You get  
caught, easily, in irrelevancies, distracting from the central  
points to be conveyed.


it wasn't me that amplified the length of text by a factor of 10.  i  
was trying to keep it focused and my mistake was responding to your  
asides.


As a public activist, to be effective, you must use polemic and all  
the skills of advocacy, which is different from discussion. Here,  
we discuss, and no collective decisions are actually made here.  
However, I inferred from behavior here what might happen in a  
public debate. If, in fact, some of this behavior carries over to  
public debate, you could get creamed. Unnecessarily. That is, over  
your own style and personality, not over the issue you are advocating.


blather.

(quoting Warren Smith.)

2. Was I effective? In what? I'm engaged only in a diffuse kind of  
advocacy here. However, I've also repeated ideas that I've  
expressed here many times, and this is part of my own learning and  
polishing process. This is of benefit to those who find it useful  
to follow my discussions, to explore these topics repeatedly so  
that they become familiar, and so that deeper understanding  
spreads. It's my method and approach, and it certainly is not for  
everyone. Were I to do in a public forum, not a specialized forum  
like this, what I do here, I'd almost completely fail.


more blather.

(3.) I have, however, come to the point that I'm sufficiently  
familiar with the issues that I'd engage, if invited, in public  
debate. I'm an effective speaker, making clear and direct contact  
with the audience. We'll see if that happens. I have made blog  
posts in public fora on these issues, they are far briefer, in  
general. The effort per word and per message is much higher for them.


sometimes effective public speakers are successful not because of  
their efforts to focus the issue, but because of their efforts to  
distract.  e.g. Sarah Palin.



i won't slap on the argumentum verbosium and explode the debate
about a single testable issue (like how many piles one needs if there
are 3 candidates) into pages and pages, that when i responded, my
post was rejected by the list server as too large.


Oh, we are crushed at the loss actually, usually it isn't  
exactly rejected, it is held for moderator approval, which can take  
some time. Depends.


i'm not messing with it further.  i just ask that you don't amplify  
the quantity of responses by a factor of 10 and bring your post to  
40K so that if anyone actually bothers to read through it and respond  
to most or all of the points, their effort goes into the trash can.   
since your name was in the To: header, you got that response, but no  
one else did.


what i have learned from that is to not play your argumentum  
verbosium game.  from now on, i must pick and choose, respond to  
only one point, delete all the other blather, and keep the issue  
focussed.


thus i am deleting and not bothering to engage in the other text.

care to discuss how many piles one needs (for precinct summability)  
when there are N candidates?  or N credible candidates?  that's what  
the issue was before it was buried in blather.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Jameson Quinn
People, please. This is not a debate class, and even if it were, no, I won
is really useless even if true. Please take this discussion off list, if you
find it important enough not to stop. There's practically no voting system
content left. As for what is left: we all know that the number of piles is
large, that full ballots can be transmitted, and we can work out the
implications to our own perhaps-incorrect satisfaction.

Respectfully to you both, but tired of this wordy debate,
Jameson

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson


i just want to settle the issue about how many piles one needs to be  
precinct summable when there are N candidates.


Kathy was pointing to Abd ul as the qualified actor who refuted the  
falsifiable assertion that i made that you needed only 9 piles for 3  
candidates.  She repeated labeled (without any justification other  
than citing Abd ul's blather) the math that i clearly presented as  
illogical.  Abd ul did nothing to support Kathy's assertion.


Kathy, fancying herself as an election security expert, continues to  
try to taint IRV as being insecure because it's not precinct  
summable.  and that is a demonstrably false claim.


i'll leave it to the experts here to judge who was trying to stay on  
topic and who was decreasing the signal-to-noise ratio with  
unnecessary text (with aim to distract from the core issue and to  
denigrate the other side).


r b-j

On Jan 21, 2010, at 3:56 PM, Jameson Quinn wrote:

People, please. This is not a debate class, and even if it were,  
no, I won is really useless even if true. Please take this  
discussion off list, if you find it important enough not to stop.  
There's practically no voting system content left. As for what is  
left: we all know that the number of piles is large, that full  
ballots can be transmitted, and we can work out the implications to  
our own perhaps-incorrect satisfaction.


Respectfully to you both, but tired of this wordy debate,
Jameson


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 01:48 AM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

the fact is, transmitting the content (to a central counting
location) of *every ballot* is the transfer of a finite amount of
information.  that is even *more* general than sorting to piles and
transmitting the tallies for piles.


Yes, of course. And this is an equivalent to carrying all the ballots 
to a central location, merely, if done, say, over the internet, faster.


But ... it raises some security issues. And with central counting 
there are other issues. This is a red herring, because we are talking 
about precinct summability, and when the number of candidates is very 
small, precinct summability isn't relevant, because the raw ballot 
data may be transmitted.


So, back to the real question: is precinct summability an important 
practical criterion to be applied to voting systems? A related 
question is the sensitivity of the method to small variations in 
votes. Noise, if you will. That can be seen with Yee diagrams, in the 
presence of chaotic regions in issue space, with IRV. But I won't 
address that here, beyond noting that IRV multiples the probability 
of ties, and many of the ties will drastically flip the overall 
result. With most other methods, there is only one relevant tie 
possible (beyond extraordinarily rare three-way ties) and when this 
happens, a coin flip doesn't change the expected voter satisfaction 
much, if at all. With IRV, the effect can be enormous, because the 
tie can affect a candidate elimination before all the votes for that 
candidate have been counted.



but breaking it down to piles regarding every conceivable permutation
of candidate preference is *still* breaking it down to a finite
number of piles.


Sure. Finite. I'll point out that a google is finite. With 
computers, this can be done even with moderately large numbers of 
candidates. It's still a problem with voting security, though. I've 
argued for Public Ballot Imaging, which would make available actual 
ballot images, transmitted from polling places, perhaps by fax or 
more likely through digital camera images -- no touching of ballots 
necessary except by election officers, all visible openly --, 
independently by voting watchdog organization through election 
observers, so that anyone can verify the count in a precinct or as 
many as they care, or can even just check one serialized ballot 
(serialized before counting) and mark it as reviewed, in a system 
that collects and displays such reviews. Many details omitted here!



  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.


Okay, three candidates, A, B, C, the ballot possibilities are, to be 
complete, much more than 9. I'll assume that write-ins are illegal 
and void the ballot. Some of the possibilities are legally equivalent 
to others, and in actual IRV ballot imaging, they are collapsed and 
reported the same, to the displeasure of voting security people who 
do want to know the error rate, which includes overvoting and exact 
overvoting patterns. So-called ballot images are not, generally. They 
are processed data reducing a ballot to legally equivalent votes. The 
reduced set is this:


A
B
C
AB
AC
BA
BC
CA
CB

Note that this assumes a 2-rank ballot. It also assumes that majority 
vote isn't important. If it's important, as it would be in an IRV 
election under Robert's Rules, we have some more possibilities. They 
are all the three-rank permutations.


ABC
ACB
BAC
BCA
CAB
CBA

Each of these is equivalent, for the purposes of finding a plurality 
winner, to a two-candidate combination.



  if you or
Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's
showing).


Well, I won't speak about Kathy, but in terms of practical elections 
in the U.S., she's right. You did not state enough information to 
establish your reduced count, and you actually added language that 
indicated that a larger total would be necessary. You used the 
qualifier credible to indicate that there might be candidates not 
credible, and you did not take care to define this. What you have 
asserted is true under two qualifications: there are only three 
candidates legally eligible to receive votes. And there are only two 
ranks on the ballot. If there are three ranks on the ballot, we have 
a poor situation, an invitation to voters to cast an irrelevant vote, 
if, in fact, that third rank has any effect on outcome, which, in the 
general case, it can. If it can affect outcome in some way, the piles 
must be reported separately.



  for 4 candidates the number of necessary piles is 40.


Under the restricted conditions, perhaps. I haven't checked the math. 
I distrust formulas compared to exhaustive enumeration, they take 
more work and there is more room for error. My lists, which I 
provided before, showed what is shown above, though it may be better 
explained this time.


The slip is an assumption that one's analysis is more complete than 
that of another, when it may be, instead, ignorant of some of the 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson

On Jan 21, 2010, at 4:26 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

But ... it raises some security issues. And with central counting  
there are other issues. This is a red herring, because we are  
talking about precinct summability, and when the number of  
candidates is very small, precinct summability isn't relevant,  
because the raw ballot data may be transmitted.


no, the problem is that the raw ballot data may be the only practical  
information to transmitt if the number of candidates is *large*, not  
very small.  when the number of candidates is very small, then it  
makes sense to transmit the tallies for piles because the number of  
piles, which are precinct summable, is manageable.


So, back to the real question: is precinct summability an important  
practical criterion to be applied to voting systems?


i would ask instead if precinct summability is important for  
security?  i believe that it is.  and i believe that it is perfectly  
practical when the number of *credible* candidates is small.  doesn't  
matter what the voting system is.  IRV, or whatever.



  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.


Okay, three candidates, A, B, C, the ballot possibilities are, to  
be complete, much more than 9. I'll assume that write-ins are  
illegal and void the ballot. Some of the possibilities are legally  
equivalent to others, and in actual IRV ballot imaging, they are  
collapsed and reported the same, to the displeasure of voting  
security people who do want to know the error rate, which  
includes overvoting and exact overvoting patterns. So-called ballot  
images are not, generally. They are processed data reducing a  
ballot to legally equivalent votes. The reduced set is this:


A
B
C
AB
AC
BA
BC
CA
CB

Note that this assumes a 2-rank ballot.


no, it can be a 3-rank ballot where the voter declines to rate their  
last choice.  3rd choice is left unmarked.



It also assumes that majority vote isn't important.


bullshit.  it (the number of consequential ballot permutations) has  
nothing to do with it (whether or not majority vote is important).


If it's important, as it would be in an IRV election under Robert's  
Rules, we have some more possibilities. They are all the three-rank  
permutations.


ABC
ACB
BAC
BCA
CAB
CBA

Each of these is equivalent, for the purposes of finding a  
plurality winner, to a two-candidate combination.


it's equivalent for the purposes of IRV or Condorcet or *any* method  
that relies solely on the relative rank of candidates.  those 6  
markings are equivalent to the corresponding 6 above.





  if you or
Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's
showing).


Well, I won't speak about Kathy, but in terms of practical  
elections in the U.S., she's right. You did not state enough  
information to establish your reduced count, ...


yes i did state enough information.  may i remind you?  i said that  
there is *no* consequential difference in these two marked ballots  
(in the case of N=3).  there is no consequential difference between a  
ballot marked AB to one marked ABC .  there is no election  
scenario, whether it's IRV, Condorcet, Borda or any other method  
using ranked ballots that will count those two ballots differently.   
there is no need to separate the AB and ABC into two piles.



  for N candidates, the number of piles necessary, P(N) is

   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=1

not

   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=0

which is appears to be the formula you and Kathy continue to insist
is correct.


Which it is under some conditions and yours is correct under some  
conditions. I assume. I haven't checked them because it's more work  
than I can put in now.


want me to spell it out.  it's a simple application of combinatorial  
analysis, what is the first chapter of my introductory probability  
textbook (of a course i took more than 3 decades ago).  you're doing  
it already for the specific case of 3 candidates A, B, and C.  if you  
want to look it up, look for language that says something like: how  
many unique ways can a group of n items be selected from a pool of N  
items when the order of selection is relevant?  and the answer to  
that is N!/n! .  but there is one more fact that you need to toss  
in.  and that fact is that all candidates unmarked or unranked are  
tied for last place.  if there is only one candidate left unmarked,  
we know how all N candidates are ranked, including the unmarked  
candidate.


everything else between is deleted without comment

A vote of ABC, is that the same as AB? Robert assumes, yes. But  
what about write-ins? ABC is equivalent to ABCW.


that's not 3 candidates.  that's four.  you just changed the  
premise.  that's an official logical fallacy.  a form of straw man.


if the write-ins are insignificant (usually the case) we can sweep  
them all into a single insignificant candidate and we have 4  
candidates and 40 piles.  but we'll see that 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Thursday, January 21, 2010 6:49 AM
 but breaking it down to piles regarding every conceivable permutation  
 of candidate preference is *still* breaking it down to a finite  
 number of piles.  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.  if you or  
 Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's  
 showing).  for 4 candidates the number of necessary piles is 
 40.
  for  N candidates, the number of piles necessary, P(N) is
 
 N-1
  P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
 n=1
 
 not
 
 N-1
  P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
 n=0

I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the numbers of 
possible unique preference profiles for increasing
numbers of candidates (N) as follows:

N   Unique Preference Profiles
2   4
3   15
4   64
5   325
6   1,956
7   13,699
8   109,600
9   986,409
10  9,864,100
11  108,505,111
12  1,302,061,344
13  16,926,797,485
14  236,975,164,804
15  3,554,627,472,075
16  56,874,039,553,216
17  966,858,672,404,689
18  17,403,456,103,284,400
19  330,665,665,962,404,000
20  6,613,313,319,248,080,000


Where there are large numbers of candidates, the maximum possible number of 
unique preference profiles will be limited by the number
of voters.  Thus if there are 10,000 valid votes and 12 candidates, the maximum 
possible number of preference profiles would be
10,000 and not 1,302,061,344.

In practice the actual number of preference profiles would be even lower, as 
significant numbers of voters would record identical
patterns of preferences.  Thus in the Meath constituency for the Dáil Éireann 
election in 2002 with 14 candidates (236,975,164,804
possibilities), there were 64,081 valid votes, but only 25,101 unique 
preference profiles.


The Minneapolis STV (RCV) ballots were all hand sorted to unique preference 
profiles for each precinct and hand counted.  This was
unnecessary but feasible as the voters could not record more than three 
preferences (rankings), no matter the numbers of candidates.
I understand the full preference profiles, probably at precinct level, will be 
published on the City website, but they are not there
yet.

James Gilmour



No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2636 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
07:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 21, 2010, at 6:30 PM, James Gilmour wrote:


robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Thursday, January 21, 2010 6:49 AM

but breaking it down to piles regarding every conceivable permutation
of candidate preference is *still* breaking it down to a finite
number of piles.  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.  if you or
Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's
showing).  for 4 candidates the number of necessary piles is
40.
 for  N candidates, the number of piles necessary, P(N) is

N-1
 P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
n=1

not

N-1
 P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
n=0


I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the  
numbers of possible unique preference profiles for increasing

numbers of candidates (N) as follows:

N   Unique Preference Profiles
2   4
3   15

...

then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you ostensibly need  
4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread James Gilmour
  N   Unique Preference Profiles
  2   4
  3   15
 ...
 
 then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you ostensibly need  
 4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.
 

If there are two candidates, A and B, then the possible unique preference 
profiles are: 
A   
B   
A  B
B  A

Anything that does not conform to this is an incorrect use of the term 
preference profile.

James Gilmour




No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2636 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
07:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:05 PM, James Gilmour wrote:


N   Unique Preference Profiles
2   4
3   15

...

then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you ostensibly need
4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.



If there are two candidates, A and B, then the possible unique  
preference profiles are:	

A   
B   
AB  
BA




what, on a ballot, is the consequential difference in meaning between  
A and AB?  what effect does a ballot marked AB have over one  
marked just A (or vise versa) in *any* election method that uses  
ranked ballots?


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Kathy Dopp
 ballot to legally equivalent votes. The reduced set is this:

 A
 B
 C
 AB
 AC
 BA
 BC
 CA
 CB

 Note that this assumes a 2-rank ballot.

 no, it can be a 3-rank ballot where the voter declines to rate their
 last choice.  3rd choice is left unmarked.

 It also assumes that majority vote isn't important.

 bullshit.  it (the number of consequential ballot permutations) has
 nothing to do with it (whether or not majority vote is important).

 If it's important, as it would be in an IRV election under Robert's
 Rules, we have some more possibilities. They are all the three-rank
 permutations.

 ABC
 ACB
 BAC
 BCA
 CAB
 CBA


 Well, I won't speak about Kathy, but in terms of practical
 elections in the U.S., she's right. You did not state enough
 information to establish your reduced count, ...

 yes i did state enough information.  may i remind you?  i said that
 there is *no* consequential difference in these two marked ballots
 (in the case of N=3).  there is no consequential difference between a
 ballot marked AB to one marked ABC .  there is no election
 scenario, whether it's IRV, Condorcet, Borda or any other method
 using ranked ballots that will count those two ballots differently.
 there is no need to separate the AB and ABC into two piles.

OK. I understand now why you are confused Robert:

 1. on the formula for the number of possible unique candidate
orderings for any rank choice voting method  you incorrectly assume
that the number of possible ballot rankings that a voter may fill out
is always equal to the number of candidates running for office and so
you can collapse N of the rankings, but this simply is not the case
in US IRV elections and it would just be unnecessarily confusing to
collapse rankings for the special (and unusual) case when there are
three candidates and three rankings, when a more general formula that
always applies to all situations regardless of the number of
candidates and allowed rankings could be used; and

2. on the fact that IRV and Condorcet must be reported similarly and
counted similarly, because there are different methods available to
count each one.

With Condorcet, you can easily count it with an NxN matrix and you
cannot count IRV that way at all generally (although I wouldn't put it
past you to find an unusual special case where you could).

With IRV, you can count it (albeit not easily depending on the number
of candidates) with sorting into piles, but you cannot count Condorcet
method that way.

You can count either Condorcet or IRV by sorting into unique vote
orderings, as I gave you the general formula for that works in all
cases earlier. However that would be a very difficult and
time-consuming way to count Condorcet since Condorcet is
precinct-summable in the far simpler n x n matrix.  It is the only way
to make IRV precinct summable using the formulas I gave you earlier or
you can look them up in my IRV report, unless you want to publicly
report all voters' individual choices. Minneapolis chose to use the
first method.

I.e. The counting methods available and ideally used for Condorcet and
IRV are different.

-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Kathy Dopp
James,

Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters are
allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an election contest.
That may be true in Australia, but is not true in the US where
typically voters are allowed to rank up to only three candidates.

I put the general formula that applies to *all* cases with n
candidates and with r rankings allowed in my paper on IRV that I wrote
a year or two ago:

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf


Because it's hard to write a summation, fraction formula, etc. here
I'll let you look it up. It's on page 6 of the doc linked above.

Cheers,

Kathy



 From: James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk
 I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the numbers of 
 possible unique preference profiles for increasing
 numbers of candidates (N) as follows:

 N       Unique Preference Profiles
 2       4
 3       15
 4       64
 5       325
 6       1,956
 7       13,699
 8       109,600
 9       986,409
 10      9,864,100
 11      108,505,111
 12      1,302,061,344
 13      16,926,797,485
 14      236,975,164,804
 15      3,554,627,472,075
 16      56,874,039,553,216
 17      966,858,672,404,689
 18      17,403,456,103,284,400
 19      330,665,665,962,404,000
 20      6,613,313,319,248,080,000


 Where there are large numbers of candidates, the maximum possible number of 
 unique preference profiles will be limited by the number
 of voters.  Thus if there are 10,000 valid votes and 12 candidates, the 
 maximum possible number of preference profiles would be
 10,000 and not 1,302,061,344.

 In practice the actual number of preference profiles would be even lower, as 
 significant numbers of voters would record identical
 patterns of preferences.  Thus in the Meath constituency for the D?il ?ireann 
 election in 2002 with 14 candidates (236,975,164,804
 possibilities), there were 64,081 valid votes, but only 25,101 unique 
 preference profiles.


 The Minneapolis STV (RCV) ballots were all hand sorted to unique preference 
 profiles for each precinct and hand counted.  This was
 unnecessary but feasible as the voters could not record more than three 
 preferences (rankings), no matter the numbers of candidates.
 I understand the full preference profiles, probably at precinct level, will 
 be published on the City website, but they are not there
 yet.

 James Gilmour


-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:42 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


James,

Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters are
allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an election contest.


James didn't put forth any formulae.  but he did put forth a table  
which appears to be consistent with


 N-1
P(N)  =  SUM{ N!/n! }
 n=0

he, appears to miss the same point as Abd and you do.


That may be true in Australia, but is not true in the US where
typically voters are allowed to rank up to only three candidates.


where do you get your information, Kathy?  that is *not* at all the  
case in the IRV election in Burlington VT.


or is Burlington untypical?

--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 05:17 PM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 21, 2010, at 4:26 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


But ... it raises some security issues. And with central counting
there are other issues. This is a red herring, because we are
talking about precinct summability, and when the number of
candidates is very small, precinct summability isn't relevant,
because the raw ballot data may be transmitted.


no, the problem is that the raw ballot data may be the only practical
information to transmitt if the number of candidates is *large*, not
very small.  when the number of candidates is very small, then it
makes sense to transmit the tallies for piles because the number of
piles, which are precinct summable, is manageable.


This is correct. I actually stated it oppositely, slip of the pen, so 
to speak. It's still a red herring, because the topic is precinct 
summability and the general use of precinct sums. The only precinct 
sum that can be used with IRV is the relevant-ballot-pattern summary, 
which becomes extremely large very rapidly. Forget about it with 
manual ballots and more than a quite small number of candidates. 
Remember, as well, that preferential voting, like top-two runoff, 
encourages lots of candidates to run, since they can do so with 
relative safety and get a payoff: some first rank votes that show 
support. They can turn that into cash in the next election when they 
are seeking the office again, or in other ways.



So, back to the real question: is precinct summability an important
practical criterion to be applied to voting systems?


i would ask instead if precinct summability is important for
security?  i believe that it is.


Good. So do I. Or was that a slip?


  and i believe that it is perfectly
practical when the number of *credible* candidates is small.  doesn't
matter what the voting system is.  IRV, or whatever.


Yes. But how small? Don't use the bogus numbers that aren't at all 
realistic given real-world election rules, and since we are talking 
about the U.S., there must be accomodation for every ballot candidate 
that gets any votes at all in the precinct, plus a write-in provision 
at a minimum, and God help the election officials if there are a 
*lot* of write-in candidates, with the sum being more than enough to 
alter the elimination sequence for the remaining candidate. 
Write-ins, in all the actual election reported counts, are counted as 
a category and then dropped when the total for all of them was 
insufficient to do other then batch-eliminate them, possibly with 
other candidates as I've seen. I.e., one assumes the simplest case, 
that all the write-in votes are for the same candidate.


Now, if it turns out that the write-ins are relevant, suppose that we 
set up some rule to lump all candidates with only one vote and report 
all the others explicitly. But the problem rapidly gets hairy. One 
has to report another candidate as relevant in addition to all the write-ins.


For voting system security issues, one must be able to count the 
votes manually, as part of an audit. I'm sure that Kathy could 
explain audit process, but, again, it gets very hairy rapidly with 
IRV, because vote samples aren't enough, given the sensitivity of the 
method to many small differences in vote patterns. What is actually 
being done? Only ballot images, with machines that collect and report 
them, in toto, from the precinct. In other words, the only solution 
in actual usage that doesn't involve toting all the ballots to a 
central location involves reporting ballot images. But this is 
precisely a system that is quite vulnerable to hacking and some very 
real voting security issues. If there are no paper ballots or at 
least bulletproof paper records that the voter personally verified, 
it's impossible to verify that there were no shenanigans. Precinct 
summable methods are not nearly as sensitive to manipulation as are 
IRV totals, it appears. It can only take a very small shift in voting 
patterns to shift an IRV result, under some conditions, and this 
isn't merely a very close election in terms of overall support for a 
candidate, it gets down to exact preference order and how it 
interacts with elimination sequence, which is determined sometimes at 
many places in the election process. And, note: if it's ballot 
images, these images don't include, generally, the actual write-in 
votes. If it turns out that write-ins need to be counted, only manual 
counting can do it, the name was hand written on a record, if I'm correct.




  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.


Okay, three candidates, A, B, C, the ballot possibilities are, to
be complete, much more than 9. I'll assume that write-ins are
illegal and void the ballot. Some of the possibilities are legally
equivalent to others, and in actual IRV ballot imaging, they are
collapsed and reported the same, to the displeasure of voting
security people who do want to know the error rate, which
includes overvoting and 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-20 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 20, 2010, at 11:23 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


Variation on previous post. Silly time!

At 02:31 PM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 12:05 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


Robert, your slip is showing.


what slip?  i don't have nuttin' under me kilt.


We already knew that.


you do?  you keep saying that you can see it.



Silly hat, Off.

Robert, if you want to be effective in public debate,


what makes you think i'm not effective?  do you actually think you  
were effective?


i won't slap on the argumentum verbosium and explode the debate  
about a single testable issue (like how many piles one needs if there  
are 3 candidates) into pages and pages, that when i responded, my  
post was rejected by the list server as too large.



I'd suggest avoiding setting up an immediate victory by the other  
side by feeding him or her lines like that.


you're the one feeding lines.  who brought up the slip showing in  
the first place?  how does one respond when facing: Your slip is  
showing, now onto a verbose response that does not speak to the core  
factual issues at all.


you and Kathy had no victory (if that is the way you like looking  
at it).  where it is about fact (derived or historically supported)  
regarding the focussed issue, you haven't done anything to touch it.


the fact is, transmitting the content (to a central counting  
location) of *every ballot* is the transfer of a finite amount of  
information.  that is even *more* general than sorting to piles and  
transmitting the tallies for piles.


but breaking it down to piles regarding every conceivable permutation  
of candidate preference is *still* breaking it down to a finite  
number of piles.  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.  if you or  
Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's  
showing).  for 4 candidates the number of necessary piles is 40.  for  
N candidates, the number of piles necessary, P(N) is


   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=1

not

   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=0

which is appears to be the formula you and Kathy continue to insist  
is correct.  and whether Kathy has an MS in Mathematics or not,  
whether you do or not, this error is demonstrable.  you and Kathy  
continue to insist that there is a consequential difference between  
ranking all candidates and ranking all but 1 and leaving one  
candidate unranked and i continue to say there is no consequential  
difference.  this is a difference of falsifiable claims that form a  
dichotomy.we can test which claim is correct.


In person, face-to-face, people would fall over laughing, and  
whatever value there was in your position would be lost.



you've never used humor to make a point?  or to make clear the  
lameness of an irrelevant reference?


whether one responds to an irrelevant distraction with humor or not  
changes nothing regarding the core issues.


certainly if a ridiculously large number of candidates are on the  
ballot, manually separating ballots into piles (without grouping  
together minor or non-credible candidates) is not practical.  even  
with 4 salient candidates, 40 piles gets pretty nasty for sorting by  
*hand*.  but 40 is still a pretty small number for a computer and a  
modern network.


a national election with 3 credible candidates can easily be  
precinct summable with 9 salient piles and 31 less important  
piles.  it doesn't matter if it is IRV, Condorcet, Borda or what.   
the issue of summing pile count is not dependent on what tabulation  
method is used (and what, *i* think, should be what the debate is  
about).


neither you nor Kathy have shown *any* problem of precinct  
summability regarding IRV or any other ranked-ballot method.


not that i am a defender of IRV.  but, you haven't laid a hand on it  
regarding precinct summability.  IRV has a few pathologies, which i  
think i understand better than either you or Kathy, simply from the  
lame and partisan arguments (and wholly verbose) i read coming from  
that direction.


even though *now* Kathy seems to be paying some attention to  
Condorcet, before this last week, i haven't noticed any such  
attention about that from her.  it was always just how bad IRV is,  
and that it's worse than any other method, including FPTP.  and when  
she (or you) says that, then i am convinced that she (or you) are  
simply anti-IRV partisans that don't really consider what the  
*commonly* *known* problems are that associated with the traditional  
FPTP (or even 2-round with runoff) methods for which motivated us to  
adopt IRV in the first place.


so, before pointing out that someone's slip is showing, it might be  
safer to adjust where one's own fig leaf is hanging.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info