Re: THE GAME OF GO AND THE CHINESE WAY OF WAR

2004-07-07 Thread Peter Dorman




OK, I'll bite. Isn't go a Japanese game? There were many articles
written around the time of WWII on what this game might tell us about
Japanese military strategy. China had a version of chess that was much
slower and more deliberate than what we know in the west -- a "river"
runs through the board, etc.

Peter (who played go for a while, but found it too complicated and
settled for chess instead)

Michael Perelman wrote:

  Didn't Mao write about Go?

On Wed, Jul 07, 2004 at 02:32:26PM -0400, Funke Jayson J wrote:
  
  
THE GAME OF GO AND THE CHINESE WAY OF WAR
A close study of the Chinese board game "go" can provide insights into the distinctive Chinese conception of warfighting, according to a new study published by the Army War College.
Go is the oldest board game in the world.  With its emphasis on fluidity and long-term strategy, author David Lai says, it differs from chess (absolute conquest), poker (bluffing and risk-taking), boxing (force on force) and football.
Go players compete, using black and white stones on multiple fronts, to encircle territory on the board, penetrating the other's territory in a dynamic contest that embodies principles articulated by Sun Tzu in his "Art of War."
"A little knowledge and experience of the game of go will be a valuable addition to the American political and military wisdom; and it will take U.S. political and military leaders a long way in understanding the Chinese way of war and diplomacy."
See "Learning From the Stones: A Go Approach to Mastering China's Strategic Concept, Shi," by David Lai, U.S. Army War College, May 2004: http://www.fas.org/man/eprint/lai.pdf

Jayson Funke

  
  
--
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail michael at ecst.csuchico.edu
  





ignorance

2004-07-07 Thread Peter Dorman
From an article in today's New York Times, Europe Reluctantly Deciding
It Has Less Time for Time Off:
To be sure, Europe's dogged pursuit of free time goes on. Sweden is
undertaking a two-year study of the social effects of a 30-hour workweek
 proving that Thorstein Veblen and his theories about the leisure class
still exert a bigger pull on the European imagination than Adam Smith does.
Would such screaming ignorance of major intellectual figures be
acceptable in any field other than economics? (And for one of them,
based just on the title of a book, no less)
Peter


Re: Bush's rapid shifting of position

2004-06-27 Thread Peter Dorman
A significant constituency on the left has materialized in recent years,
propelled by anti- (alter-) globalization actions, mobilizations
against the Iraq war, etc.  This demographic has been discovered by the
entertainment industry, which is ready to sell to them.  To say this is
not to denigrate the work of Moore et al., but to explain why it is
being promoted in the mainstream.  Still recommended after all these
years: The Consciousness Industry by Hans Magnus Enzensberger.
Peter
Perelman, Michael wrote:
I cannot remember a time with so many left documentaries getting screen
time -- even ignoring Michael Moore.  Supersize this, control room, the
corporation 
Maybe our time is coming.  And then, maybe not.
Michael



Re: Marxist Fianancial Advice

2004-06-23 Thread Peter Dorman
I did a brief review of this lit for a paper I wrote recently.  Some
comments:
1. If market efficiency has any substantive relationship to real
factors (as revealed ex post), unpredictability of price movements is
necessary but not sufficient for efficiency.
2. The only defensible claim about financial markets is that they are
unpredictable in the their first moment (directionality).  Schiller et
al., as well as common sense, suggest that the higher moments
(overshooting) are predictable.  This is just another way of saying that
an informed observer (like Doug) can tell you when the market is over-
or undervalued (with better than 50% probability) but not when to get
out or in.
3. If people make consistent errors of judgment (there is lots of
evidence that they do), today's price could always be the best estimator
of tomorrow's and yet the market would be inefficient according to some
objective standard.  In other words, both today's price and tomorrow's
can be irrational.
None of this is very profound, but sometimes the semantics of this topic
obscures the more-or-less simple underlying concepts.
Peter
Doug Henwood wrote:
Devine, James wrote:
BTW, the stock market is basically unpredictable _even though_ it
doesn't fit the efficient markets hypothesis.

Again, I must turn into a pedant and ask just what you mean by that.
There are several forms of the EMH. Quoting myself from Wall Street,
characterizing Eugene Fama's review:
Fama distinguished among three varieties of the EMH: the weak,
semi-strong, and strong forms. The weak form asserts that the past
course of security prices says nothing about their future
meanderings. The semi-strong form asserts that security prices
adjust almost instantaneously to significant news (profits
announcements, dividend changes, etc.). And the strong form asserts
that there is no such thing as a hidden cadre of smart money
investors who enjoy privileged access to information that isn't
reflected in public market prices.

This isn't entirely nonsense, is it? Would you argue that stock
prices don't adjust almost instantaneously to fresh news? Would you
argue that there isn't a strong element of randomness in prices? If
you say the market is basically unpredictable, then you're
subscribing to at least part of the EMH.
The anomalies that have been identified over the years - that low P/E
stocks outperform high P/E ones, for example - imply that stocks are,
at least to some degree, predictable. The same with Shiller's work on
overreaction, which implies that speculators who bet against extremes
of mob psychology (which is essentially the strategy of both Keynes
and Soros) are part of a smart money cadre that aren't trading on the
basis of nonpublic information, but on an unpopular analysis.
You could say that the market efficiently reflets the often
nonsensical consensus of investors, which is something EMH types
wouldn't agree with. Even some dissidents have a problem with
irrationality. The first time I met Joseph Stiglitz was late in the
dot.com mania. I was very curious to hear his analysis of that
lunacy. But his info theory still holds that investors are rational,
just not all equally informed. So he wondered aloud, Why do people
buy those stocks?
Doug


Re: Economists barred from court?

2003-06-27 Thread Peter Dorman
This is also an example of the consequences of pop philosophy of
science.  A crude positivism that would have no takers at all among
specialists in the field rules the courtroom.  But don't worry about
economics.  All heterodox types will be excluded from the hearing, and
the judge will rule that neoclassical doctrine is generally accepted.
Not a problem.
Peter

ps: My bugaboo has been the hedonic value of life literature, which
plays a big role these days in policy and litigation, but is, in my
opinion, indisputably junk science.
Eugene Coyle wrote:

This column from the WSJ, 6/27/03 leads to two thoughts.

First, the law somehow always gets twisted to favor business over people.

Second, I don't see how orthodox economists will be allowed to testify
in court if judges are competent.
Gene Coyle



SCIENCE JOURNAL
By SHARON BEGLEY
'Junk Science' Ban Also Keeps
Jurors From Sound Evidence
Ellen Relkin was sure that junk science played no part in her case.
Her client, Lisa Soldo, a healthy mother of a newborn, suffered a
massive intracranial hemorrhagic stroke at age 28, soon after starting
on a drug prescribed to suppress lactation, and was left severely brain
damaged. Ms. Relkin, at attorney with the Manhattan law firm Weitz 
Luxenberg, thought science showed that this tragedy was no coincidence.
At the very least, she figured a jury should hear the evidence.
None ever did. Thanks to a landmark Supreme Court decision handed down
10 years ago Saturday, science in the courtroom has undergone a radical
overhaul.
True, some very bad science has been kept out. Says Jerome Kassirer,
former editor of the New England Journal of Medicine, It was pitiful
how people with few credentials, who made a career out of courtroom
testimony, were hired to be expert witnesses. That's much rarer now.
But legitimate scientific evidence has also become rarer. Judges are
dismissing testimony by physicians as anecdotal, setting standards for
scientific evidence higher than what doctors and researchers use, and
barring testimony when scientists in different disciplines disagree. In
some cases backed by legitimate science, science-and-law scholars told
me, judges have ruled that the evidence wasn't good enough, or
unambiguous enough, for a jury to hear, and so have dismissed the case
before trial.
Plaintiff attorneys deplore the situation, while corporate lawyers
generally applaud it. The surprise is how few saw it coming. In its 7-2
decision in Daubert v. Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals Inc., the Supreme
Court ruled that, to be admissible, expert testimony must be based on a
testable theory or method that had passed peer review, had a known error
rate and standards, and reflected generally acceptable science. It
instructed judges to be gatekeepers, barring testimony that falls short.
At the time, the ruling was seen as a blow to business, as it rejected
a strict standard that kept dubious scientific evidence out of the
courts, reported this newspaper.
As a matter of law, Daubert applies to civil and criminal cases. But few
criminal defendants can afford a pretrial Daubert challenge to expert
testimony, says Margaret Berger of Brooklyn Law School. So faulty
science still finds its way into criminal cases. Example: Prosecutions
in some child sexual-abuse cases still rely on therapist interviews that
can be badgering and suggestive, which produce misinformation.
The real impact has been in civil cases involving claims of harm from a
pharmaceutical or other chemical. In these cases, some judges have ruled
that without epidemiological studies, plaintiffs cannot prove causation.
Others have ruled that doctors' testimony -- that a patient developed
heart trouble after taking a drug, got better after stopping it and
relapsed after going back on it -- doesn't pass Daubert muster.
That, says Dr. Kassirer, shows ignorance of how science works: In
medicine, we make judgments about cause and effect based on all kinds of
evidence -- biological plausibility, physiology, animal studies and case
reports. There are many valid ways to assess causality; this kind of
information ought to go to a jury.
Several judges have thrown out cases in which epidemiology fails to find
a twofold increase in risk from the chemical at issue, even though
journals publish papers that take seriously risks below this arbitrary
cutoff. Others have found inadmissible models commonly used by
scientists to assess exposure.
Some judges see scientific disagreement as proof the science is
unreliable. That's what Ms. Relkin faced in her Parlodel case. In 1994,
with many young women on the drug having had heart attacks, strokes or
seizures, and under pressure from the FDA, Sandoz (now part of Novartis)
stopped selling Parlodel as a lactation suppressant.
Soon after receiving the case in 1998, a Pennsylvania judge empanelled
three independent experts to assess the reliability of the scientific
evidence on Parlodel. They split. The pharmacologist said the science
was sound; the 

Re: Monbiot on the WTO

2003-06-25 Thread Peter Dorman
There are two aspects to the WTO power structure that lead it to deviate
from even a moderately acceptable level of democracy.  The first has to
do with the behind-the-scenes manipulation, which Patrick referred to.
It is only formally a one-country, one-vote institution.  The second
has to do with the role of the WTO in imposing the interests of some
sectors of each member country's ruling class on the rest.  This is the
part that gets modeled in all those formulaic political economy of free
trade papers.  Those who own or run particular industries often have
their own desired trade barriers; the WTO, in principle, exists to lean
against them in order to reduce trade barriers generally.  In practice,
this has been highly uneven, with much more protection permitted in some
sectors than others.  But the main point is that the WTO serves as a
quid pro quo mechanism for the market access folks everywhere: your
country must accord market access here in order to get market access
there.  And market access reflects one set of political interests among
many.  What demonstrators have been demonstrating against is the steady
push, utilizing the WTO as a vehicle, for the market access interests of
those who profit from exports in every country against all the other
social/economic/environmental interests that conflict with them.  By its
very nature, the WTO is a club to be used against democracy.
I agree, however, that there are many levels of hell, and the IMF
occupies a rung that makes the WTO's look like, well, Lake Geneva (where
it actually sits).
Peter

Doug Henwood wrote:

Peter Dorman wrote:

rgely powerless.  It
benefits from the importance of being unimportant.  The WTO is fatally
flawed because it rests on the foundation of trade ministers, the
designated corporate gofers within any government.  On top of that, it
is the product (as are all really important international organizations,
unlike the ILO, UNESCO, etc.) of global power imbalances.


Yes, but...it is a one country, one vote institution, and as Bhagwati
argues, for that reason, not a favored instrument of the U.S. or the
other G7 countries.  Its entire budget, as he pointed out, is smaller
than the IMF's travel budget. Unlike the IMF, though, it's ruled
against the U.S. It seems to me less dangerous than the Bretton Woods
Institutions.
Doug


Re: Monbiot on the WTO

2003-06-24 Thread Peter Dorman
Here are some thoughts on Monbiot and some of the pen-l responses.

1. I think Monbiot came to the right answer, but mostly for the wrong
reasons.  He is in grave danger of falling in with Oxfam and other
internationally minded NGOs who have bought into the notion that what
poor countries most need is unfettered access to rich country markets.
From there it is one short step to signing on to the Cairnes group,
etc.  He hasn't looked deeply enough into *why* poor countries are so
desperate for export markets.  In other words, he hasn't incorporated an
understanding of the post-debt-crisis financial framework into his
analyis of trade.  He is quite right to argue for a transformation of
poor countries from resource to industrial exporters, but this makes
sense developmentally only in terms of a coherent domestic
transformation on all levels: domestic markets, domestic capabilities,
etc.  If industrialization serves mainly as an export-directed
phenomenon, bereft of local linkages, for the purposes of servicing
debt, then free trade in such products is part of the problem, not the
solution.
2. Obviously (to me anyway), if the gross financial and trade imbalances
need to be fixed, and if some unspecified debt reduction and capital
flow regulatory framework is the answer on the finance side, then an
international organization that coordinates trade balances -- keeps them
within acceptable bands that have been openly negotiated -- is the
answer on the goods and services side.  In my make-believe world, this
is above all what the WTO would be doing.
3. The institutional problem of environmental and social standards is
huge.  The ILO (which I will be working for once again over the summer)
is admirable in many ways, but only because it is largely powerless.  It
benefits from the importance of being unimportant.  The WTO is fatally
flawed because it rests on the foundation of trade ministers, the
designated corporate gofers within any government.  On top of that, it
is the product (as are all really important international organizations,
unlike the ILO, UNESCO, etc.) of global power imbalances.  I cannot
begin to imagine anything good coming from this organization under these
circumstances.  The sort of democratic and accountable global governance
we need will require much more radical changes at the national level in
the US and other great power countries.  In the meantime, I believe
there is lots of unutilized potential for creating shadow institutions
(paralleling the WTO, IMF etc.) from below, based on hard-nosed
negotiation between groups representing democratic interests in
different countries.  To really be effective, these alternative groups
would have to actually take concrete positions on specific issues as
they arise; i.e. they would have to cooperate on a detailed program and
not just on their opposition to the status quo.  This is something
effective political groups have always done on a local and national
level; now global capitalism has forced the same necessity on us
internationally.
4. In the end, I think there really is a case for substantial
relocalization, but it should be the result of a sane trading framework,
not an imperative imposed on it.  Once the debt treadmill is smashed,
and once the false economies based on hyper-exploitation of populations
and resources are ended, most of the impetus for destructive trade will
cease.  Then it will be enough to build up healthy local economies on
their own merits, through the methods some communities are beginning to
pioneer.
I apologize for the soapbox tone of this e-mail.  I guess I must be
pretty opinionated about this stuff.
Peter


Re: 'Straussians' in the news; the world trembles (II)

2003-06-18 Thread Peter Dorman
Actually, I bring a Dewey perspective to questions relating to
democracy.  Virtue is not something people simply have, nor is it likely
to be the product of cloistered study.  Ordinary, somewhat virtuous
people can produce more or less beneficial social groups depending on
the ways they constitute themselves.  The conflation of individual and
social qualities appears to be a key theoretical failing of the
Straussians.  Worse, they (or at least the ones I have known) have
fallen into the trap of implicit superiority: because they pronounce on
the virtue of others, they are above such considerations.  There is a
history of some Marxists falling into a similar trap with respect to
false consciousness.  (I who am in a position to judge who is subject
to false consciousness am therefore free of such delusions.)  All
versions of the ubermensch mindset are profoundly dangerous.
Incidentally, the reason classics have been studied for centuries is
that people have found contemporary relevance in them.  You don't think,
for instance, that Martha Nussbaum (to take just one prominent example)
finds contemporary meaning in the ancient Greeks?  Strauss' claim to
fame is his contention that all those ancient texts were written in
code, and that he was the first to recognize this and divine their true
meaning.
Peter

David S. Shemano wrote:

In addition to this list, I receive the Strauss list, which is
maintained at Yahoo Groups.  I have also read quite a bit of Strauss.
Strauss took Marx very seriously as a philosopher.  One of his books,
On Tyranny, contains an exchange of letters with Alexandre Kojeve
regarding, among other things, the progression of history (Fukuyama's
End of History is in many ways a popularization of this exchange).
The Marx chapter in the Strauss edited History of Political Philosophy
is also very respectful.
Strauss's major accomplishment, to me at least, was to successfully
argue that ancient philosophy had more than historical relevance.  In
other words, Strauss attacked the historicist notion that there is no
point to studying the ancients for the truth of their arguments
because we come after them and, therefore, know more than them, or
that because they lived in an ancient slave society, they could not
possible have anything important to say to us living in a
technologically advanced capitalist society.  Therefore, if a serious
Straussian questions political democracy, it is not pop-Nietzche, but
following the ancients in asking Who Should Rule? as a fundamental
question of political philosophy, and the ancients had very critical
things to say about political democracy.  This is not to say
that (all) Straussians necessarily agree with those criticisms, but
that Straussians believe those criticisms must be taken seriously and
cannot be dismissed a priori, because there is the possibility that
those criticisms are correct.
As the Straussian conspiracy apparently controls the White House, I
would encourage anyone interested to join the Strauss list to know
thine enemy and bring a Marxist perspective to the various topics
discussed.
David Shemano



Re: 'Straussians' in the news; the world trembles (II)

2003-06-18 Thread Peter Dorman




To follow up on Jim's fourth point, networks are very important in staffing
political positions. There are many social networks out there, most of them
invisible to those on the outside. When a new administration takes power,
it relies on the networks it's tied into for recruitment. This is unavoidable;
there is no other way to identify people who are not only ideologically but
also personally compatible with the new management team. The Straussians
have provided one such network for the Bushies. (They have also drawn on
the Kissinger clique, the Bush/Rove Texas mafia and many other networks.)
Why the sudden attention given to the Strauss crew? Certainly the oddness
of an academic faction based on the study of classics is part of the story,
but also the legendary cynicism and corruption of this crowd is relevant.
(Remember all the publicity surrounding Bellow's book about Bloom?) It
would be a mistake, however, to attribute too much importance to this one
influence. As far as I can tell, the Bush administration is less ideas-driven
than most, and that's saying a lot.

Peter

Devine, James wrote:

  
  
  three points:
  
  1. It's important to distinguish Strauss from the Straussians.
(Similarly, Marx is quite different from the Marxians, while Friedman is
different from the Friedmaniacs, though not much.) Strauss was a scholar
who came up with a lot of scholarly interpretations, many of which were controversial,
whereas (as I understand it) many of the Straussians share a culture of elitism
and secretiveness. It should be mentioned that they are far from the only
ones who are elitist and secretive.
  
  BTW, those kind of attitudes have been shared by various
left groupings at times.For example, as noted in an article from the NY-based
Jewish daily FORWARD that was posted to pen-l awhile back, some of the "neo-conservatives"
were once (marginally) on the left, associated with the Social Democrats,
USA, an elitist and secretive (i.e., sectarian) grouping.
  
  2.Strauss andStraussians have nothing close to a monopoly
on respect for ancient philosophers. I work at a Jesuit-sponsored university
where the philosophy department puts a big emphasis on the importance of
ancient philosophy (while rejecting the modernist view that new philosophy
has superceded the old). However, as far as I know, there are no Straussians
in the department. (I'll ask.) 
  
  3. No one on this list, as far as I know,believes in any
kind of Straussian conspiracy. Instead, I'd guess that the consensus is either
that (1) the Straussians are unimportant or (2) Straussians and Straussianism
simply provide an ideological cover (in certain circles) for what the Bush
administration would do anyway, based on the various vested interest groups
(fractions of the capitalist class) that the administration represents and
their strategy ofcreating a permanent lock on governmental power for their
clique. 
  
  BTW, I haven't seen it noted that a lot of Straussians flocked
to Washington to serve the Reagan administration. They are like that, servants
to power, when that power is very "conservative" (i.e., overtly and strenuously
serving the rich).
  Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
  http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine
  
  

-Original Message-
From: David S. Shemano   [mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
Sent: Wednesday, June 18, 2003 9:46   AM
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: Re: [PEN-L]   'Straussians' in the news; the world trembles
(II)



In addition to this list, I receivethe Strauss list, which is   maintained
at Yahoo Groups. I have also read quite a bit of   Strauss. Strauss took
Marx very seriously as a philosopher. One of   his books, On Tyranny, contains
an exchange of letters with Alexandre Kojeve   regarding, among other things,the
progression of history (Fukuyama's End   of History is in many ways a popularization
of this exchange). The Marx   chapter in the Strauss edited History of Political
Philosophy is also very   respectful.

Strauss's major accomplishment, to me at least,was to successfully
  argue that ancient philosophy had more than historical relevance. In
 other words, Strauss attacked the historicist notion that there is no point
to   studying the ancients for the truth of their arguments because we come
after   them and, therefore, know more than them, or that because they lived
in an   ancient slave society, they could not possible have anything important
to say   to us living in a technologically advanced capitalist society.
 Therefore, if a serious Straussian questions political democracy, it is
not   pop-Nietzche, but following the ancients in asking "Who Should Rule?"
as a   fundamental question of political philosophy, and the ancients had
very   critical things to say about political democracy. This is not to
say   that(all) Straussians necessarily agree with those criticisms, but
that   Straussians believe those criticisms must be taken seriously and cannot
be   dismissed a 

Re: WTO--hypocrisy, yada yada yada

2003-06-17 Thread Peter Dorman
How can this absurdity be peddled so openly and repeatedly?  EU ag
subsidies the biggest single contributor to Third World poverty?  Unreal.
Peter

Ian Murray wrote:

The International Herald Tribune | www.iht.com
Europe's trade hypocrisy: The West pays to keep the rest poor
Philip Bowring IHT
Tuesday, June 17, 2003
Europe's trade hypocrisy

snip

Having missed an opportunity as host of the Group of Eight summit
meeting in Evian to lead Europe away from its annual agricultural
subsidies of $50 billion - the biggest single contributor to Third World
poverty - France is now stitching up the European Union's reform plans.



Re: 'Straussians' in the news; the world trembles (II)

2003-06-17 Thread Peter Dorman
The issue is not what Strauss himself did or did not say.  There is a
definite culture among contemporary Straussians (divided as they are)
that promotes deceit and an ubermensch self-conception among the adepts.
It disdains democracy due to the inability of the vast majority to
attain, or even comprehend, virtue.  It is definitely not a dominant
ideology on the right, but it contributes to and justifies the cynicism
of rightists in power toward everyday morality.  Anyone who has ever had
to deal with these people first hand comes away feeling soiled.
Peter

Kenneth Campbell wrote:

'Straussians' in the news; the world trembles (II)

Clifford Orwin
National Post
Tuesday, June 17, 2003
In yesterday's column I began to address the allegations that a sinister
cabal of Straussians dominates American foreign policy and was
responsible for the war against Saddam. Many would have you believe that
it's a fundamental principle of this sect to practise deceit against
non-members the better to rule over them. Central to the Straussian
vision is a docile citizenry, kept uninformed and easy to manipulate
through perpetual fear of external attack (Linda McQuaig, The Toronto
Star, May 25).
Not that Ms. McQuaig has ever read a word of Strauss. It's clear from
her column that she hasn't. She's just repeating what other leftish
journalists have been saying.
But where there's so much smoke, there must be fire, right? Well, don't
count on warming your hands over it. Yes, a few figures in the Bush
administration once took courses with the late Leo Strauss (1899-1973),
whose defence of liberal democracy I discussed yesterday. Of these few,
however, only one, Deputy Secretary of Defence Paul D. Wolfowitz, is in
a position to make policy, and even he is only in a deputy position to
make policy. As Peter Berkowitz has pointed out, this whole scenario of
a Straussian takeover of the U.S. government is wildly implausible. It
supposes that President Bush, Vice-President Cheney, Secretary of State
Powell, Secretary of Defence Rumsfeld, and National Security Adviser
Rice, non-Straussians by all accounts, are stooges and dupes [of their
subordinates].
It's also worth noting that of the supposed Straussians in the
administration, Wolfowitz, by far the most influential, is also the
least a Straussian. A student of math and science as an undergraduate,
he switched to national security studies. While he did take a couple of
courses with Strauss, his mentor was the late Albert Wohlstetter, a
logician and operations analyst with no connection to Strauss.
Wolfowitz is an imposing figure. As even his detractors concede, he
combines an incandescent intelligence with great dedication to public
service. He has served loyally in five administrations, Democrat and
Republican alike. Yes, he has President Bush's ear. He's earned it. But
others also have Mr. Bush's ear. Rumours of a coup ( Straussian or
otherwise) have been greatly exaggerated.
Much of what has appeared in the press is sensationalism pure and
simple. I mean not just the accusation that the Bush administration
engaged in massive deception in the months prior to the war against
Saddam, but the claims that in doing so it was following the teaching of
Strauss.
The question of whether the administration misled the public, or was
itself misled, will doubtless be subject to further scrutiny. It still
remains to be shown that it engaged in any deception of anyone. But our
present concern is the further assertion that if deception did occur it
must have been due to the influence of Strauss.
All right, then. Have you ever wondered why politicians aren't
completely truthful? Why they always use the truth selectively, in the
service of partisan rhetoric, and occasionally misplace it entirely?
Well, now you know. They've been corrupted by reading a certain scholar
of ancient political philosophy. Well, my goodness, this couldn't have
occurred to them on their own, could it? Politicians didn't use to
dissemble, did they?
As if this weren't dumb enough already, there's another crucial problem
with it. There's simply no basis for it in Strauss. When journalists
attribute these views to him, they never quote him. They can't. Strauss
never argued that democratic leaders should deceive their peoples. The
statesmen he admired were ones of impeccable integrity.
Yes, Strauss did write about a certain mode of deceit, which he called
esoteric writing. Indeed he claimed to have rediscovered this practice
after centuries of oblivion. But this kind of prevarication was
practised not by rulers on the ruled, but by certain of the ruled on the
rulers. Strauss first expounded this theme in his Persecution and the
Art of Writing. The art in question was precisely a response to
persecution, the resort of the powerless and unconventional (including
philosophers, who as such are both of these). It was not a technique of
wielding power. A recent example is the Aesopian writing that
dissidents practised under Communism. 

Re: Hobsbawm on the American Empire

2003-06-17 Thread Peter Dorman
OK, this is for the sake of discussion, since I wouldn't presume to
advise UFPJ.  First, I think that, just by being who they are, they pose
a question to groups involved in economic globalization.  If, say,
Public Citizen works with UFPJ, they necessarily weaken their ties to
corporate protectionists.  Second, UFPJ should focus on strengthening
democratic, or proto-democratic, multilateralism.  So the solution to
subsidies and other barriers to trade in agriculture is neither simply
more restriction at the national level or, even less, free trade, but
working for intenational coordination of subsidies and market controls
-- basically resurrecting NIEO (New International Economic Order, a
pretty good idea from the 1970s).  To the maximum possible extent, this
program should be based on the ideas put forward by grass roots farmer
and peasant organizations around the world.  Managed debt relief (in a
big, Jubilee South way) would be another example of this.  Strengthening
international environment treaties, labor rights etc.  In other words,
the alternative to neoliberal globalization would not be nationalism but
internationalism.  That would definitely exclude the Pat Buchanans of
this world.
How does this sound?

Peter

Yoshie Furuhashi wrote:

This is a difficult question.  The global justice movement has, in
general, been willing to align itself with old-fashioned
protectionist interests in the US.  They have more money than we do
and more access to media and politicians.  Activists recognize that
the interests involved are fundamentally opposed, but they have
taken this route anyway.  We saw this around NAFTA, China/WTO, etc.
I have been arguing (to those who will listen to my harangue) that
this strategy is a mistake.  The political costs outweigh the
benefits, IMO.  We alienate soft supporters of justice-oriented
initiatives who are worried about protectionism; they think that, if
liberalization is defeated, the most reactionary business interests
will be the ones who pick up the pieces. My view is that every
alliance risks a corresponding alienation.  You have to decide who
you want to reach out to, and who you are willing to write off.  As
a political matter, I would rather extend myself to hesitant
left-liberals than cozy up to a North Carolina textile baron. (And I
am very willing to piss off liberals in other contexts...)
Peter


One of the action priorities that came out of the United for Peace
and Justice conference in Chicago (June 6-8, 2003) is as follows:
*   UFPJ Action Priorities

2) Campaign to Unite the Peace and Global Justice Movement

This campaign calls on UFPJ to initiate a comprehensive grassroots
educational campaign that makes the links between military and
economic empire-building by confronting corporate globalization, the
global economic agenda of the ruling elite. The campaign includes
coordinated days of action during the Sept. 10-13 WTO meeting in
Cancun, including a commemoration of 9/11 and a Global Day of Action
Against Mobilization and War on Sept. 13. The campaign also calls for
UFPJ to mobilize for the Nov. 19-21 FTAA meeting in Miami and the
Nov. 22-23 School of the Americas protest.
http://www.unitedforpeace.org/article.php?id=1755   *

Suppose, for the sake of discussion, that you are either on the UFPJ
steering committee or advising them, helping UFPJ develop a campaign
out of the above action priority.  What actions, demands, and talking
points would you recommend with regard to the Sept. 10-13 WTO meeting
in Cancun and the Nov. 19-21 FTAA meeting in Miami?
--
Yoshie
* Calendars of Events in Columbus:
http://www.osu.edu/students/sif/calendar.html,
http://www.freepress.org/calendar.php,  http://www.cpanews.org/
* Student International Forum: http://www.osu.edu/students/sif/
* Committee for Justice in Palestine: http://www.osudivest.org/
* Al-Awda-Ohio: http://groups.yahoo.com/group/Al-Awda-Ohio
* Solidarity: http://solidarity.igc.org/


Re: 'Straussians' in the news; the world trembles (II)

2003-06-17 Thread Peter Dorman




I will admit (actually I said it in an earlier e-mail) that my knowledge
of Straussian mores comes from my own experience and not from any sort of
systematic study. It may well be that I encountered an unrepresentative
sample, although (1) grad students I talked to who had been dragooned into
studying the stuff and had gone to a number of Straussian conferences described
the whole scene in similar terms, and (2) it is now being echoed by a number
of media people, who presumably heard it from someone (and not me).

Even so, I wouldn't expect that every Straussian, everywhere would share
these traits.

Peter

andie nachgeborenen wrote:

  There's a big range. I had two Straussian teachers in Michigan polisci.
One was a liberal feminist, utterly commited to democracy. She didn't blink
when I wrote a paper defending what I took to be Lenin's ideal of direct
democracy in SR. The other Straussian teacher of mine was very conservative,
but absolutely fair and honest, a level-headed, extremely sharp, and scholarly
guy. I was the class commie -- in those days I was _very_ Red and out --
and all he insisted was that I argue for my views. (He didn't get tenure.)Gavve
me the misimpression that Straussians were just people who read classic texts
very carefully. Well, some of them are.
  
  Later, I had an experience with the while range of Straussians, speaking
at a conference on Marxism at Kenyon College in Ohio. I was on a panel with
one fella, in history, I think, who was just like my old teacher, very conservative
but smart, decent, and fair. Then there were some clowns from polisci who
were touting the sort of scary pop-Nietzschean elitism that is at issue here.
I argued that the living essence of Marxism was the extension of democracy
to the economy. The historian argued that there was a difference between
political and economic democracy, the first being a good and the latter a
bad idea -- good in theory, bad in practice. The polisci types said, What's
so great about democracy? Excellence requires elite rule. I said that I thought
the differences between us were to great to be fruitfully discussed. jks
  
  Peter Dorman [EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:
  The
issue is not what Strauss himself did or did not say. There is a
definite culture among contemporary Straussians (divided as they are)
that promotes deceit and an ubermensch self-conception among the adepts.
It disdains democracy due to the inability of the vast majority to
attain, or even comprehend, "virtue". It is definitely not a dominant
ideology on the right, but it contributes to and justifies the cynicism
of rightists in power toward everyday morality. Anyone who has ever had
to deal with these people first hand comes away feeling soiled.

Peter
  
  Do you Yahoo!?
  SBC
Yahoo! DSL - Now only $29.95 per month!




Re: Empire and Current Account

2003-06-16 Thread Peter Dorman
But I think the idea is not to pay very much for them -- certainly less
than they pay for what they get from you.  And in capitalist empires
there is also the issue of the Keynesian demand constraint.
The other question is interesting.  Throws a new light on the GNP v GDP
business...
Peter

Ellen Frank wrote:

This reminds me of a question I have long had to
which one of you out there may have an answer.
How did imperial Europe account for trade with
colonies in the 1800s?  Was Congolese rubber
sent to Belgium counted as a Belgian import or was
it treated as internal trade within Belgium?
I would think the whole point of an empire is to extract
resources and labor from one's colonies, not the
other way round.
Ellen

PEN-L list [EMAIL PROTECTED] writes:


John Gray (not the author of Men are from Mars)
thinks that the really strange thing about the current
situation is that the USA is the first empire to be
running a structural current account deficit rather
than a surplus.  I rather think that I agree with him,
although I have not checked his assertion that Britain,
Spain, Rome etc all exported capital.
dd





Re: Hobsbawn on the American Empire

2003-06-16 Thread Peter Dorman
This is a difficult question.  The global justice movement has, in
general, been willing to align itself with old-fashioned protectionist
interests in the US.  They have more money than we do and more access to
media and politicians.  Activists recognize that the interests involved
are fundamentally opposed, but they have taken this route anyway.  We
saw this around NAFTA, China/WTO, etc.  I have been arguing (to those
who will listen to my harangue) that this strategy is a mistake.  The
political costs outweigh the benefits, IMO.  We alienate soft
supporters of justice-oriented initiatives who are worried about
protectionism; they think that, if liberalization is defeated, the most
reactionary business interests will be the ones who pick up the pieces.
My view is that every alliance risks a corresponding alienation.  You
have to decide who you want to reach out to, and who you are willing to
write off.  As a political matter, I would rather extend myself to
hesitant left-liberals than cozy up to a North Carolina textile baron.
(And I am very willing to piss off liberals in other contexts...)
Peter

Yoshie Furuhashi wrote:

June 11, 2003

After Winning the War
The Empire Expands Wider and Still Wider
By ERIC HOBSBAWM
snip

But the global empire of Britain, the first industrial nation,
worked with the grain of the globalisation that the development of
the British economy did so much to advance. The British empire was a
system of international trade in which, as industry developed in
Britain, it essentially rested on the export of manufactures to less
developed countries. In return, Britain became the major market for
the world's primary products (2). After it ceased to be the workshop
of the world, it became the centre of the globe's financial system.
Not so the US economy. That rested on the protection of native
industries, in a potentially gigantic market, against outside
competition, and this remains a powerful element in US politics.
When US industry became globally dominant, free trade suited it as
it had suited the British. But one of the weaknesses of the 21st
century US empire is that in the industrialised world of today the
US economy is no longer as dominant as it was (3). What the US
imports in vast quantities are manufactures from the rest of the
world, and against this the reaction of both business interests and
voters remains protectionist. There is a contradiction between the
ideology of a world dominated by US-controlled free trade, and the
political interests of important elements inside the US who find
themselves weakened by it.


What should US leftists do about this contradiction -- the
contradiction that has been ignored by the US branch of the so-called
global justice movement?
--
Yoshie
* Calendars of Events in Columbus:
http://www.osu.edu/students/sif/calendar.html,
http://www.freepress.org/calendar.php,  http://www.cpanews.org/
* Student International Forum: http://www.osu.edu/students/sif/
* Committee for Justice in Palestine: http://www.osudivest.org/
* Al-Awda-Ohio: http://groups.yahoo.com/group/Al-Awda-Ohio
* Solidarity: http://solidarity.igc.org/


Re: Spreading the cost, legitimizing aggression

2003-03-30 Thread Peter Dorman
The American invasion of Iraq is essentially a hostile takeover -- 
financing the acquisition of another country by liquidating the latter's 
assets.  Truly government along modern business lines...

Peter

k hanly wrote:

http://www.zmag.org/content/showarticle.cfm?SectionID=15ItemID=3341

Aid Conundrum

by Phyllis Bennis; March 28, 2003

 

snip

Should oil-for-food funds be released and used to pay for emergency
supplies?
 No -- international law, specifically Geneva Conventions, requires
belligerent --and occupying power -- to take responsibility (meaning pay)
for humanitarian needs of civilian population under occupation. Currently
that includes most of Iraq. The oil-for-food money is Iraqi money; it
belongs to the people of Iraq, and should remain in the bank until there is
a functioning government in Iraq to whom it can be turned over.
2) Then how should emergency food, medicine, other needs be paid for? The
U.S., the occupying power and belligerent, should pay all costs for
emergency care and initial rehabilitation efforts, at least during period
while hostilities continue.
etc.



Re: Re: The Stalingrad thesis.

2003-03-30 Thread Peter Dorman
I hate to say this -- it's really pretty ugly -- but the reason Baghdad 
will not be Stalingrad is fairly simple.  The US has the power to 
destroy as much of the city and its inhabitants as it wants.  There is 
no military impediment to this, only the political cost of such 
slaughter.  It comes down to a very cold calculation: how many civilian 
deaths and visible leveling of the city can they get away with?  My 
guess is that, if Iraqi resistance is stiff, they will aim at the upper 
end of what they perceive to be the politically feasible range.  It 
sickens me to imagine what this could mean.

Peter

Michael Perelman wrote:

I don't think were talking about Stalingrad here.  I suspect it will be
more like Jenin, but this means that the US would have a hard time
installing a new Karzai.
--
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929
Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 




Re: Rumsfeld papers over strategic split

2003-03-30 Thread Peter Dorman
FWIW, the Russian GRU report is predicting no operational pause, but a 
major attack to clear the way to Baghdad within 48 hours.

Peter

Chris Burford wrote:

War tactics split is denied by US

http://www.guardian.co.uk/Iraq/Story/0,2763,926226,00.html

Ahead of a New Yorker report published today, Monday,

America's military and civilian war leaders made an aggressive effort 
to present a united front yesterday, amid claims that US troops are 
beginning an enforced pause of days or weeks before advancing on Baghdad.


However the British media reported over the weekend very much a 
picture of Rumsfeld on the defensive.

This is the result of Iraqi resistance, and counterattacks by the 
British government, the US military, and the CIA. The story has been 
gently amplfied by news sources in London.

Saturday's Guardian had a feature on General Shinseki who has been 
humilated by being sidelined by Rumsfeld by a retirement announced 18 
months ahead of its time, although he is officially Tommy Franks superior.

It also seemed significant that Richard Myers, as Chair of the Joint 
Chiefs, the equivalent of Colin Powell's position at the time of the 
Gulf War, waited to give his first televised interview of the war to 
the David Frost programme on BBC on Sunday morning. He emphasised that 
one thing we are using is patience. We can afford to take our time. 
The US will want us to be patient.

He signalled a geopolitical awareness: It is inherent on great powers 
to use restraint. Three times he praised the British strategy and 
tactics [I will post separately on this]

Clearly he also spoke with the authority of a deal that agreed to 
double the number of US troops in Iraq, announced shortly after the 
Bush Blair summit. Later on Sunday he was speaking on US television.

Confirmation of the shift in strategy was suggested by the next 
interview on the Frost programme by the former comander of UK forces 
at the time of the Gulf War, Sir Peter de la Billiere, very discreet 
in his style of discourse, who would probably know the thinking of 
many retired generals with links to the current military on both sides 
of the Atlantic. He welcomed Myers' s interview as very refreshing 
and stated military commanders are not going to perform according to 
the timetable of politicians. He stressed the flexibility of the UK 
military approach. He also argued for fighting easy rather than 
fighting hard even if it took six months.

By midday London time, the ultra-reliable Foreign Office minister Mike 
O'Brien, really second to Jack Straw, said We are now in a situation 
where the politicians are listening very carefully to what the 
generals, the military are saying. This position was echoed by Peter 
Hain, another senior minister in the Foreign Office on the commercial 
channel within an hour.

It is clear that there is a coodinated line enthusiastically endorsed 
by the Brits that the politicians (including quite possibly Rumsfeld) 
should shut up a bit and let the generals take greater responsibility, 
and the head of the US Chiefs of Staff is signalling enthusiasm for 
the UK military strategy and tactics.

One of the paradoxes of imperialism is that the military is often more 
cautious and humane than the imperialist ideologues.

Myers is smoothing things over saying the war plan is fine and it 
works. Rumsfeld is saying the war plan is actually Tommy Franks's, and 
it works. But yesterday's Sunday Telegraph, which is well-briefed on 
military affairs had a headline quoting a former National Security 
Adviser with close links to the White House (!) saying Not everybody 
wants to be seen too close to Don Rumsfeld right now.

You would expect such a  mini-revolution in the war plan to need quite 
a bit of papering over. Not least because it actually reflects a 
global battle between two imperialist strategies. Meanwhile the 
surface debate is all about whether there has been a pause. Which is a 
mere epiphenomenoninherent to any war.

Chris Burford
London
PS

No one has yet thought to ask, if the war was going to take six months 
anyway, with hegemonic troops stuck in an unpleasant desert through 
the height of summer, why did they have to fall out with France at the 
Security Council which was seeking a mere 3 months more of inspections?








Re: RE: New Alazeera wesite in English

2003-03-25 Thread Peter Dorman
They've been knocked off the web by what is said to be either a 
technical problem (underestimating incoming traffic) or a 
denial-of-service attack.  Is there a news update on this?

Peter

Alan Jacobson wrote:

I get a 404 error (server not found) when I try that URL.

Alan Jacobson

-Original Message-
From: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
[mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED] Behalf Of k hanly
Sent: Tuesday, March 25, 2003 12:40 PM
To: pen
Cc: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: [PEN-L:36091] New Alazeera wesite in English
The URL is:
http://english.aljazeera.net/?tag=nl
 




Re: RE: RE: Re: Clash of Currencies and the Iraq War

2003-03-24 Thread Peter Dorman
Im just getting back to this thread  apologies if Im way behind the 
flow. Anyway, Krugman is OK as far as he goes. As I mentioned before, 
the euro-vs-dollar conspiracy crowd is simply wrong on the mechanics of 
how these things work. Whether oil is denominated in dollars or not is 
relevant, as K also says. And I doubt that US planners think in terms of 
the IPE concept of key currencies. If I were sitting in on their 
planning meetings, I suspect I would hear a lot about leadership, 
access to [or of] capital, etc.

Nevertheless, the US has a persistent current account surplus in excess 
of half a trillion dollars a year. Robert Blecker, Dean Baker, Jamie 
Galbraith, Wynn Godley and others have demonstrated, convincingly to me, 
that this is unsustainable even before the long run comes calling. The 
relative attractiveness of US asset markets has taken a big hit in the 
last year or so; hence it is extremely likely that our payments are 
being balanced by a buildup of external reserves. (Krugman thinks this 
as well.) That is a dangerous situation. It is also a politically 
anomalous situation, because it suggests that foreign governments, 
through their ostensibly autonomous central banks, have increasing 
leverage over US financial prospects.

The advantages of the privileged position of that dollar are not so much 
the seigniorage that Krugman refers to, as they are the ability to 
acquire a very large external debt. At some point in the future, this 
will not look like such a great deal, but right now it means that 
Americans as a group can enjoy relatively high living standards without 
have to do the grubby work producing stuff that we or others actually want.

To repeat: left economists who specialize in these things should be 
writing popular pieces discussing the political economic relationship 
between global finance and war. The best response to faulty analysis is 
better analysis.

Peter

Max B. Sawicky wrote:

Krugman argues that the issue is a crock:

http://www.wws.princeton.edu/~pkrugman/oildollar.html

His argument looks right to me.

max




Re: Re: Re: US opinion polls

2003-03-24 Thread Peter Dorman
Many thanks, Doug.  There is a big difference, but I would have expected 
more lopsided oppose numbers from those who don't see an Al Qaeda 
connection.  Perhaps a later poll would have revealed this.

Peter

Doug Henwood wrote:

Michael Perelman wrote:

Doug Henwood posted data on this to his list.  Maybe he could resend them
here.  There was a striking difference according whether or not people
held the evil Saddam responsible for 9-11 or not.
On Sat, Mar 22, 2003 at 01:13:07PM -0800, Peter Dorman wrote:

 The New York Times presented more polling data today.  One question 
that
 interests me is how opinion is split based on the role of
 disinformation.  Specifically, how do the percentages of those for or
 against the war differ depending on whether respondents believe that
 Iraq was responsible for the 9/11 attacks (i.e. conditional
 probabilities)?  Does anyone on this list have this information, either
 for the present or the recent past?

  Peter


Yes I've posted quite a bit on this. Here's the latest. Other polls 
tell pretty much the same story. Another stunning factoid: only 17% of 
US respondents could give the correct number of Iraqis among the 9/11 
hijackers (0, of course).

Doug



[this is from the director of polling for ABC]

This except from our 1/28/03 ABC News poll analysis may help.

AL QAEDA - Bush's assertion in his speech that Saddam Hussein aids 
and protects terrorists, including members of Al Qaeda is one that 
confirms a perception already held by many Americans. Any number of 
polls since Sept. 11, 2001, have shown that most do think Iraq 
supports those terrorists; in this survey, 68 percent say so.

This perception is an important one in fueling support for military 
action, in that such support is premised to a large extent on the 
sense of threat Americans feel from Iraq. Among those who think Iraq 
directly supports Al Qaeda, 73 percent favor taking military action to 
oust Saddam. Among those who don't think he supports Al Qaeda, support 
for military action drops to 45 percent.

9. Do you think Iraq has or has not provided direct support to the Al 
Qaeda terrorist group?
ProvidedNot provided No
support   support  opinion
1/28/0368   17   15

Xtab: Military action vs Iraq
 Support   Oppose
Provided support to Al Qaeda (68%) 73%   24
Not provided support (17%) 4551




Re: Clash of Currencies and the Iraq War

2003-03-22 Thread Peter Dorman
I'm both happy and a bit embarrassed at the way this dollar-euro story 
is being picked up by the antiwar movement.  I'm happy because the 
extreme vulnerability of the US payments situation is crucial to any 
analysis of the geopolitics of the current moment.  Talking about this 
represents an advance in sophistication and perhaps preparedness for 
what may come.  I'm embarrassed because the analyses that are floating 
around are highly flawed in their particulars and make it look as though 
our side is not very together.  I think the fault may lie with us lefty 
economists; we who have been studying this for years should be writing 
about it, but instead we are leaving it to folks who are trying to 
figure it out on the fly...

Peter

Carrol Cox wrote:

This article by Geoffrey Heard is one of the better I've seen on the
war. This URL takes you to the printer-friendly version.
Carrol

http://slash.autonomedia.org/print.pl?sid=03/03/20/1330253
 




US opinion polls

2003-03-22 Thread Peter Dorman
The New York Times presented more polling data today.  One question that 
interests me is how opinion is split based on the role of 
disinformation.  Specifically, how do the percentages of those for or 
against the war differ depending on whether respondents believe that 
Iraq was responsible for the 9/11 attacks (i.e. conditional 
probabilities)?  Does anyone on this list have this information, either 
for the present or the recent past?

Peter



Re: RE: Re: Re: quiet... too quiet

2003-03-19 Thread Peter Dorman
While adamant opposition to war remains correct, the left would be in a 
better position (politically and ethically) if it had consistently 
supported constructive initiatives on human rights.  The suppression of 
hundreds of millions of people under absolute despotisms, and the 
oppression of minorities everywhere, are burning issues, and denouncing 
them is not an adequate response.  Just as we organize against war, we 
should be organizing for institutions to defend human rights.  I for one 
do not think of the International Criminal Court as a distraction or 
pointless bit of bourgeois puffery.  It is far too restricted in scope, 
of course, but it's our job to put forward a vision of a genuine 
international human rights court of appeal.  Similarly, the 
international solidarity movement is a prototype of an international 
peace force -- third parties who could provide on-the-ground protection 
for people at extreme risk.  It should not just be well-healed youth 
from the richer countries who do this; we need a global fund to finance 
human rights intervention work by people from third world and low income 
communities too.  These are all elements of the other world that is said 
to be possible.

The big obstacle to overcome on the left is, to put it very bluntly, 
nationalism.  The idea that national sovereignty is a higher principle 
than human rights has widespread currency, but to me it is a great 
mistake.  Whenever the left has chosen nationalism over 
internationalism, it has ended in disaster.  Nationalism is a bad idea 
not just for the powerful countries, but also for the dominated.  It 
presents itself as a defender of human and economic rights, but it 
tramples these rights in order to save them.  If we buy into the 
dichotomy between imperialism and nationalism, we lose.  Our chose is 
between either of those and international solidarity.

Sorry for the lecture, but recent events have put me into a soapbox mode.

Peter

Devine, James wrote:

We should help the Iraqi people as they see fit (within reason, of 
course). One thing that would help is regime change in the US.

JD
 

-Original Message-
From: Bill Lear
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: 3/19/2003 4:32 AM
Subject: [PEN-L:35742] Re: Re: quiet... too quiet
On Tuesday, March 18, 2003 at 19:34:07 (-0800) Devine, James writes:
...
In any event, it's for the Iraqi people to overthrow their dictator.
It's
not _our_ job.
It is our responsibility to help them in any way they see fit,
if we helped put him there and supported him, is it not?
Bill




Martin Feldstein??

2003-03-19 Thread Peter Dorman
I just received an e-mail from ECAAR about the antiwar petition that I 
and many of you signed.  As I scanned the ad copy with the list of 
names, I was struck by the inclusion of Martin Feldstein.  OK, it wasn't 
exactly Martin Feldstein but Martin Feldstei -- but then I was Peter 
Dorma.  So is it true?  Do I have to rethink my position?

Peter



Re: quiet... too quiet

2003-03-18 Thread Peter Dorman




I am quiet on this list because I am struggling to catch up with my work
after two days of personal devastation following the news about Rachel Corrie.
Everyone who was active about anything here in Olympia knew this woman and
what she stood for. It is a terrible loss.

Peter

Devine, James wrote:

  
  quiet... too quiet
  pen-l is very quiet today. Is it because Fatherland
Security Minister Tom Ridge has raised the alert level to burnt umber?
  Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
  http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine
  
  





Olympia demonstration

2003-02-17 Thread Peter Dorman
We had a spirited turnout on Saturday in Olympia, WA.  My own estimate 
would be about 1500, although the organizers claimed 2500 -- in either 
case, not bad for a small town, especially since many activists went to 
Seattle to demonstrate there instead.  The crowd was diverse, and it 
included quite a few vets (several of whom spoke), older folks, etc.  I 
saw several people I recognized as mainstream Democrats.  Coverage in 
the local newspaper was very positive and supportive.  The overall mood 
was definitely we are the mainstream.  Speakers ranged from slightly 
left of center to hard left; there was music, poetry, etc.

Incidentally, I was very impressed by the large number of dogs in 
attendance.  This shows the depth of antiwar sentiment, given their long 
evolutionary history of aggression and pack-oriented behavior.

Peter



Re: What is wrong with the mainstream economics?

2003-02-13 Thread Peter Dorman




Mainstream economics can be stretched and bent to deal with many non-mainstream
concerns, but I think there are three conceptual limits and one sociology-of-knowledge
limit.

Conceptual:

1. "Exchange", what markets presumably consist of, is a metaphor. Economic
interactions often have important elements of exchange, but crucial aspects
are missing, particularly those having to do with direct social and productive
interaction. Once this metaphor is taken for the substance of what economics
is, there are limits to what you can do.

2. Time has never been properly represented and probably can't be. The asymmetry
of temporal activity (time flows forward but not backward) butts up against
models of equilibration, as in the celebrated (on this list) Debreu-Sonnenschein-Mantel
critique of GET. Market theory is based almost entirely on one-shot games
and cannot accommodate repeated interaction over time. Fundamental uncertainty
(not knowing the probability distribution) is another stumbling block.

3. Neoclassical economics has never divested itself of 18th century monistic
individualism. Individuals and the products of their work never interact
outside markets (except when markets are "missing"). Of course, you could
have a market for every conceivable commodity, and dense interaction would
still give you multiple equilibria, path dependence, a strategic role for
power relations, etc. And our physical interventions in the world interact
ecologically.

Sociological:

Mainstream economics, by its methodology and internal organization, is systematically
closed to other social sciences and their methodologies. There are spectacular
exceptions, but they are exceptions. It is extremely difficult to gain acceptance
in the mainstream for work that takes political theory, psychology, sociology
or other fields seriously.

In compiling this list, I'm thinking of extensions of mainstream economics
to Marxism, worker-managed economies, the environment ("natural capital"),
and so on. These extensions exist, but they do not do justice to their objects.

Peter

Mengen Lucy wrote:

  Hi everyone. In 3 weeks
time I will be giving a talk titled what is wrong with the mainstream economics
and the audience will be mostly mainstream economists and students! I feel
this is a good opportunity to influence some students but also feel very
nervous:o( I am quite confident about my own area, which is international
trade. However, I cannot limit my talk to international trade and I need
help. Any good books/articles (including internet), your own notes, any ideas
 advice  just anything would be greatly appreciated. Particularly
the philosophical/methodological weaknesses of the mainstream economics are
off interest. For example, do you know a good criticism of the utility concept?
The assumptions of the mainstream economics about human nature? Excessive
mathematicasion of economics? Anything will do.
  Many thanks for your help.
  Lucy
  
  
  With Yahoo! Mail you can get a bigger mailbox -- choose
a size that fits your needs





Re: FW: Economists' statement opposing the Bush taxcuts

2003-02-13 Thread Peter Dorman
Right, this is why I didn't sign it either (despite the enormous 
persuasive power of my endorsement).

Peter

Forstater, Mathew wrote:

This statement is so frustrating--chronic deficits exacerbating the
long term budget outlook reduce the capacity of the government to
finance... Just keep backing yourselves further an further into the
corner, so you can never support common sense budgetary policy again, or
only do so at the risk of having this thrown back in your face. Why not
just criticize it for what its real problems are, instead of exploiting
the misunderstandings about federal budgetary matters? 

http://www.epinet.org/stmt/
 





Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: doublethink

2003-02-11 Thread Peter Dorman
Sorry about linear algebra.  You didn't find eigenvectors beautiful?

Peter

joanna bujes wrote:


I only like math because it's beautiful and elegant, but I have no 
desire (and probably no ability) to understand why it is so. I 
made it through Calculus and vector calculus...was bored to tears 
through linear algebra...gave up after that. Took a philsophy of 
science course that was all p's and q's. Hated it.

So sorry,

Joanna





Re: Iraq war driven by a crisis of overproduction inthe USA?

2003-02-10 Thread Peter Dorman
In the last few days I've seen a number of posts indicating that the US 
obsession with deposing the Iraqi government is based on warding off the 
euro's threat to the dollar, by making sure oil is traded in dollars. 
I'm appending a reply I wrote to a friend who sent me one of these, 
asking for comment. FWIW, I still think the main impetus behind the war 
is the view that the security problems of concern to Washington 
(terrorist attacks on US interests, Palestinian attacks on Israel and 
Israelis) are ultimately due to the fact that the Islamic world is 
poorly integrated with global capitalism. Iraq is a convenient beachhead 
for a region-wide initiative. But here's the reply:

Thanks, Martha. It was interesting to read this. The author is in the 
ballpark, so to speak, but gets some of the details wrong and is a 
little too conspiratorial for my taste.

The author is basically right about the central importance of the 
dollars reserve currency status. This, more than anything else, has 
permitted the US to run huge current account (trade and transfers) 
deficits with impunity. The reasons are twofold: there is limited 
exchange rate risk, since, as long as international transactions are 
conducted in dollars, there is considerable transaction demand for the 
dollar to help bolster its value. The foreign exchange markets run 
almost entirely on psychology (speculative activity is 99% of all 
currency dealing), and the role of the dollar as a reserve currency is 
like an anchor that stabilizes expectations about its future gyrations. 
Second, there is a large, elastic pool of dollar holdings in reserve, 
and this buffers the need of the US to match its outflow of dollars (due 
to trade and transfers) with a corresponding inflow (by selling off its 
assets). In a nutshell, this permanent line of credit makes a US 
foreign exchange crisis an impossibility, as long as it continues to exist.

It is not correct to say that the US is getting a no-interest loan, 
however: every year that we suck in half a trillion dollars or more in 
capital inflows (foreign purchases of bonds, stocks, etc.), we 
accumulate future obligations to remit profit and interest payments to 
those foreigners in dollars. This is very much analogous to the interest 
an individual would be required to pay on, say, credit card debt. I am 
not nit-picking in bringing this up, since the accumulation of these 
obligations expands the deficit on the current account and adds to the 
overall swelling of the dollar bubble.

Eventually the bubble must burst. We do not know what the consequences 
will be. The best-case scenario (assuming the continuation of capitalism 
as we know it, which I suppose means we are talking about the 
second-best case scenario) is that some combination of austerity 
(recession/depression) in the US combined with a massive devaluation of 
the dollar (no less than 30% on a trade-weighted basis) will solve the 
problem. Less appetizing scenarios evoke images of financial panic, 
state-of-emergency political coups, etc. Without a doubt, the trigger 
for such a crisis would be the end of the dollars role as the worlds 
reserve currency.

What holds the euro back, primarily, is the perceived (and actual) 
weakness of many of the peripheral countries in Euroland: Portugal, 
Spain, Italy, etc. These countries are at perpetual risk of running 
trade deficits with their EU partners, and with the consolidation of 
their various national currencies into a single euro, there is no longer 
an escape valve through devaluation. Thus, if these economies become 
uncompetitive and if their unemployment rates shoot up (Spains is 
pretty high already), either there will be a flood of southern Europeans 
trying to seek jobs in the wealthier, more productive regions (which 
would be a big political problem), or the euro as a whole would have to 
be devalued relative to the rest of the world. In other words, Germany 
and France might have to accept a currency whose value is set by the 
productivity and competitiveness of Iberia, Greece, etc. There is a 
pervasive sense that the targets set by the European monetary agreement 
that gave rise to the euro were achieved through smoke and mirrors, and 
that this could come apart at any moment. Perhaps the recent ascent of 
the euro indicates that those fears have receded; I dont know. We will 
find out soon enough, I suspect.

In the meantime, oil is not a big factor. It is an important component 
in international trade, but only one of many. Moreover, the reserve 
status of the dollar is also reflected in the willingness of central 
banks to hold their foreign exchange in the form of dollars, and even in 
the dollarization of whole peripheral economies (especially in Latin 
America). On this last note, however, it should be borne in mind that 
the quasi-dollarization of some east Asian countries (S. Korea and 
Taiwan) appears to have ended, and the experience of Argentina should 
scare 

Re: Re: Re: Iraq war driven by a crisis of overproductionin the USA?

2003-02-10 Thread Peter Dorman
I was reacting to a portion of the report which made the argument about 
pricing oil in euros.  (Iraq does this; that's one reason why they are 
going to be invaded.)  But the response I quoted was to a different 
piece in which that argument was the entire analysis.

Peter

e. ahmet tonak wrote:


Is this a response to JACOB LEVICH, who interpreted the Indian report, 
or to the report itself.  I didn't read the report yet, just briefly 
glanced and looked respectable to me.  I posted it, as a view from the 
South, in my web site.  If it is overtly conspiratorial let me know. 
Thanks.


Peter Dorman wrote:

In the last few days I've seen a number of posts indicating that the 
US obsession with deposing the Iraqi government is based on warding 
off the euro's threat to the dollar, by making sure oil is traded in 
dollars. I'm appending a reply I wrote to a friend who sent me one of 
these, asking for comment. FWIW, I still think the main impetus 
behind the war is the view that the security problems of concern to 
Washington (terrorist attacks on US interests, Palestinian attacks on 
Israel and Israelis) are ultimately due to the fact that the Islamic 
world is poorly integrated with global capitalism. Iraq is a 
convenient beachhead for a region-wide initiative. But here's the reply:


Louis Proyect wrote:

CounterPunch

February 8, 2003

New Iraq Report
Yes, Tony, There is a Conspiracy
by JACOB LEVICH




etc.










Re: Re: RE: $4 billion

2003-01-27 Thread Peter Dorman
As for the political response, it looks to me as though the Bushies are 
willing to risk a roll of the dice: they are betting that a war against 
Iraq will be swift, have few US casualties, lead to a few months of 
feel-good news stories about individuals or communities who now have 
hope (as there were after the invasion of Afghanistan) and result in a 
big bounce in the opinion polls.  The rest of the world, they think, 
will just adapt.  From this perspective, it's difficult to see how the 
peace movement can stave off the war.  I really hope I'm missing something.

Peter

Doug Henwood wrote:

Devine, James wrote:


BTW, I am wondering about the Bushies' response to the peace 
movement. Are they simply ignoring it? or are they doing Cointelpro 
again? or what?


What's your guess? These guys are total maximalists, rounding up 
people like old A. Mitchell Palmer. They've got to have some 
Cointelpro in the works. It'd be reckless to assume otherwise.

Doug





Re: tax theory/policy

2003-01-22 Thread Peter Dorman
Ian Murray wrote:


washingtonpost.com
An Economist On a Mission
R. Glenn Hubbard's Theory Anchors Bush's Tax Plan -- but Can It Survive?

By Jonathan Weisman
Washington Post Staff Writer
Wednesday, January 22, 2003; Page E01


 

snip


A tax system based on
consumption rather than savings and investment would remove a primary
impediment to economic growth.

It is not easy to find economists who disagree with that theory. 


more snip

Really?




interlocking directorates study

2003-01-16 Thread Peter Dorman




Here is a link to the article on interlocking directorates that has been
indexed in several places recently (including ATTAC). The title is "The
Network Topography of the American Corporate Elite, 1982-2001" by Gerald
Davis, Mina Yoo and Wayne Baker.

http://experiments.gsia.cmu.edu/speakers/Davis.pdf

Peter




Re: RE: The Democrats don't know their job

2003-01-15 Thread Peter Dorman




To Jim's list I would add this:

For structural and political reasons, the Keynesian option (public spending
to compensate for shortfalls in private investment) has shriveled. There
is a direct political economic consequence, the need to cater to capital,
and an ideological consequence, the recognition that only private investment
is productive as a litmus test for political respectability. This is true
in all capitalist countries. The US situation is even more extreme, however:
we are dependent on investment inflows (capital account surplus) to finance
our endless, enormous current account deficit. This puts financial markets
firmly in control. The US has been deep in the throws of structural adjustment
for two decades and we hardly recognize it.

Peter

Devine, James wrote:

  
  RE: [PEN-L:33865] "The Democrats don't know their job"
  Pfaff's analysis is far too superficial. The reason why
the U.S. Democratic Party has become increasingly useless on domestic-policy
issues is because (1) the labor movement has lost any power it had, so that
the DP doesn't see it as a group to cater to; (2) the civil-rights and anti-war
movements have also faded (partly because of perceived victories), so that
the DP doesn't see them as groups to cater to; (3) other reform movements
-- such as environmentalists -- have lost their power, so the DP ... you
get the idea; and (4) the big city political machines have lost their power
to influence the DP to serve urban constituencies. Given the shrinking of
these movements and/or their retreat into narrow interest-group politics,
the DP has shifted to trying to attract the suburban voters and of course
the big-money folks. They were led in that direction by the Democratic Leadership
Council (of Clinton, Gore, Lieberman, etc.) but the way the US political
system works has pushed them in that direction. If the DLC hadn't existed,
someone would have invented it. 
  It should be mentioned that the "good old days" of a
strong DP centered on cold war liberalism, the linking of the welfare state
(always anemic in the US, compared to Europe) to the warfare state and to
US international domination. Before the 1970s, the DP had major components
opposed to civil rights, environmentalism, and the like. So the good old
days weren't so good.
  
  Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]  http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine
  
  
  
   -Original Message-
   From: Chris Burford [mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
  
   Sent: Tuesday, January 14, 2003 11:06 PM
   To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
   Subject: [PEN-L:33865] "The Democrats don't know their
job"
   
   
   This list and LBO has been criticised in more antagonistic
  
   times as too 
   full of liberals. I thought this recent article in
the 
   International Herald 
   Tribune by its frequent liberal europhile correspondent
in Paris, was 
   interesting.
   
   http://www.iht.com/articles/82936.htm
   
   It occurs to me that if it is true, a list like this
which 
   spans left-wing 
   opinion, including marxist, may be of some indirect
help in 
   shifting the 
   centre of gravity of debate in civil society.
  
   
   It is interesting that the article concludes that part
of the 
   problem is 
   that the Democrats have lost touch with their working
class 
   consituency, 
   although it does not explicitly argue that this is
its way back to 
   strategic cohenence.
   
   In the UK New Labour was quietly influenced over ten
years in 
   its formation 
   by the eurocommunist Gramscian tendencies of "Marxism
Today", which 
   provided the theoretical basis for detaching New Labour
from its 
   traditional workerist rooots.
   
   The New Labour government has many problems but it
appears 
   strategically in 
   command of the theoretical agenda. Is William Pfaff's
  
   analysis correct?
   
   Chris Burford
   London
   





Re: Re: query: Game Theory

2003-01-07 Thread Peter Dorman




I like this book a lot, but it is not suitable for undergraduate students.
It is not really an introduction, but a critical essay which gets a bit
technical at times. I was persuaded by their general position, however.

Peter

Bill Lear wrote:

  On Tuesday, January 7, 2003 at 09:26:35 (-0800) Devine, James writes:
  
  
I've been reading GAME THEORY AND ECONOMIC MODELLING by David M. Kreps. It's
a useful survey because it doesn't get bogged down in the technical details
(as textbooks do) and provides some philosophical reflection on the whole GT
project. Most importantly, it's not a rah-rah book promoting GT but keeps
its praise tempered while explaining GT's limitations (even within the
narrow confines of the neoclassical world-view). 

The problem is that the book was published in 1990 and is thus out of date.
Does anyone know of a more recent book in this vein? 

  
  
Shaun Hargreaves Heap and Yanis Varoufakis Varoufakis published Game
Theory: A Critical Introduction in 1995.  Description from Amazon:

In recent years game theory has swept through all of the social
sciences. Its practi[ti]oners have great designs for it, claiming that it
offers an opportunity to unify the social sciences and that it it the
natural foundation of a rational theory of society. Game Theory is for
those who are intrigued but baffled by these claims, and daunted by
the technical demands of most introductions to the subject. Requiring
no more than simple arithmetic, the book: * Traces the origins of Game
Theory and its philosophical premises * Looks at its implications for
the theory of bargaining and social contract theory * Gives a detailed
exposition of all of the major `games' including the famous
`prisoner's dilemma' * Analyses cooperative, non cooperative,
repeated, evolutionary and experimental games.


I liked Varoufakis' intro econ book a lot.  Not sure if this is useful
to you or not.


Bill
  





Re: Re: Re: Rogoff: We're Not the Problem

2003-01-02 Thread Peter Dorman




You would be completely right if Rogoff thought that unemployment and falling
incomes were the problem. For him (and the IMF), however, a shortage of
foreign exchange for debt service is the problem (just like his brother's
inability to pay his loans was a problem). Here the fallacy is not the Keynesian
one, but the bogus collectivism by which an individual's debt is equated
with the external debt of a country. As we all know, a few ultra-rich folks
can engage in capital flight, and this becomes a problem to be solved on
the backs of the majority of working people who have never had the wherewithal
to be profligate in the first place.

I've always found it interesting that, in international trade and finance,
the "nation" is used as a unit of analysis by a profession that is so dogmatically
individualistic in the rest of its thinking...

Peter

Michael Pollak wrote:

  On Wed, 1 Jan 2003, Peter Dorman wrote:

  
  
Michael,

I don't think Rogoff is making the econ 101 mistake you attribute to
him. He is arguing against the post hoc ergo propter hoc fallacy that,
because austerity follows IMF intervention the IMF is necessarily
responsible for it.

  
  
Yes he tacks that on at the end.  But most of the article is taken up with
saying that austerity at his brother's house is like austerity in a
national budget -- missing the obvious difference that, unlike his
brother's baking business, if a government cuts down on its spending in
bad times, it doesn't save, it worsens the bad times.

Michael
  





Re: Rogoff: We're Not the Problem

2003-01-01 Thread Peter Dorman
Michael,

I don't think Rogoff is making the econ 101 mistake you attribute to 
him. He is arguing against the post hoc ergo propter hoc fallacy that, 
because austerity follows IMF intervention the IMF is necessarily 
responsible for it . The problem is not that the IMF loans money, 
however, or that it attaches conditions, but that the conditions are 
(mostly) ideologically driven and serve a very narrow set of interests. 
In other words, Rogoff is attacking a straw man and avoiding the real 
criticisms of the IMF.

Peter

Michael Pollak wrote:

[This seems kind of unbelievable.  Isn't the first fallacy that economics
101 sets out to refute the idea that a household budget is analogous to a
set of national accounts?  I thought it was regarded not only as a fallacy
but as the shibboleth of economic ignorance.  Has something changed that a
Harvard economics professor can base his whole case on it?  Or is Rogoff
just that completely disingenuous?]

[If something has changed, if some economists feel they've disproved this
fallacy in some subtle way, that would explain a lot -- like why the
Hooverism that was based on the fallacy now seems to be everywhere
respectable again.]

The IMF is Not the Problem
By Kenneth Rogoff
Economic Counselor and Director, Research Department
International Monetary Fund

Syndicated and Published in the following:
The Nation (Thailand) on October 30, 2002
L'Avenir (Congo), Business Day (South Africa),
Business World (Philippines), Taipei Times (Taiwan),
Aripaev (Estonia), Logos Press (Moldova)
Delovoy Peterburg (Russia), Finance (Slovenia),
El Cronista (Argentina), El Diario (Chile),
El Observador (Uruguay), Financial Mirror (Cyprus)
Independent (Bangladesh).

Throughout much of the world, the IMF is caricatured as a demon of
austerity. Wherever the IMF appears on the scene to provide financial
assistance, painful government budget cuts seem certain to follow. This
image of austerity appeals to the emotional need for stories with
villains. After all, good villains sell booksincluding books about
globalization that demonize the IMF. But does the image reflect reality?
Is the IMF, the member of the UN family charged to maintain global
financial stability, really so evil or misguided that it can only propose
policies that inflict economic pain instead of alleviating it?

I admit that the IMF has its faults, and I don't aim to gloss over them.
Until a year ago, when I left a professorship at Harvard University to
become the Fund's chief economist, I was a vocal, if perhaps not
vitriolic, critic of the IMF's management of the international monetary
system. Although the IMF has changed a lot in recent years, there is no
denying that there are still major holes in the international systemnot
least the lack of a fair and orderly procedure for dealing with highly
indebted countries that become insolvent. The IMF is working to fill that
gap now.

But the austerity charge is misconceived. Troubled countries knock on the
Fund's door for financial assistance only when all other creditors have
turned their backs. In most cases, a country is already in desperate
fiscal straits by the time IMF economists arrive on the scene to discuss a
loan. More often than not, the country has over-extended itself
financially through some combination of imprudence and bad luck. Countries
come to the IMF precisely because they know that it will lend to them when
no one else will, and at interest rates lower than most could only dream
of, even in the best of times. IMF loans thus relieve austerity: they help
governments limit the amount of budgetary belt-tightening required in a
crisis.

You think I am crazy? Allow me to draw an analogy from my personal
finances. Just after I finished school, my older brother Hal ran into some
financial difficulties. He and his wife had started ripping out all the
walls, plumbing, and wiring in their modest Washington apartment, hoping
to refurbish it prior to the arrival of their first child. It was an
ambitious plan, but it seemed doable -- until Hal started having problems
with his baking business. Suddenly they found themselves desperately
over-extended. Hal went to the bank for a loan, but with his business
struggling, he didn't qualify. With all his credit cards at their limit,
and all his cash gone, Hal finally came to me for a loan. I had managed to
put aside some modest savings, which I freely lent him indefinitely at
zero interest. Even with my help, things weren't easy. Hal had to work
longer hours than ever before, and he still had to sharply cut back on
household expenditures across the board. But my loan did help, eventually
Hal's business recovered, my nephew was born and -- much later -- the
apartment remodeling project came to a successful conclusion.

Now, did my brother blame me for the period of belt-tightening austerity
his family had to face? No, obviously not. Admittedly, this is a
simplistic analogy, but it captures the essence of the issue. Yes, I did

Christian economics [was Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: Bush AdministrationOn The Poor: Pay More Taxes!]

2002-12-19 Thread Peter Dorman




My litmus test for "Christian economists" is the jubilee.

Peter

Ian Murray wrote:

  - Original Message -
From: "andie nachgeborenen" [EMAIL PROTECTED]
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sent: Wednesday, December 18, 2002 7:03 PM
Subject: [PEN-L:33205] Re: Re: Re: Bush Administration On The Poor: Pay
More Taxes!


  
  

Nay, it's more complex than that. In the US, one would have to wade
through all the books and magazine articles espousing "Christian
economics"; yes such a beast does exist along the lines of Islamic
economics etc. Check out the nearest large Christian bookstore near
you.I'm not joking.


Does it call for driving the moneylenders out of the temple, giving

  
  all that you have the poor and following Him, while (of course)
rendering under Caesar what is Caesar's? jks
  
  =

If only it were as simple as that:

http://www.acton.org/publicat/m_and_m/2001_fall/pdf/MM-v4n2-Woehrling.pd
f

http://freebooks.entrewave.com/freebooks/docs/2236_47e.htm


Ian
  





Re: Re: Bush Administration On The Poor: Pay More Taxes!

2002-12-19 Thread Peter Dorman




Even the neoclassical view is that markets reward not effort or even productivity
in a physical sense, but the "value" of the marginal product--that is, contributions
or skills which are scarce in view of demand. This is an efficiency argument
at best, not an equity argument. But then throw in luck, connections, discrimination,
power that results from your place at the bottom or top of the hierarchy,
and it's not too difficult to argue that the reward inequalities stemming
from the system need to be sanded down...

Peter

Ian Murray wrote:

  - Original Message -
From: "Ellen Frank" [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  
  
What people deserve is exactly the issue the right wing will
raise -- the rich deserve their luxuries and the poor have no
right to take what others have earned fairly (I guess they'll
want to leave Ken Lay out if it).  How do supporters of
a progressive tax respond unless they are willing to say the
existing distribution of income is fundamentally unjust?

Ellen


  
  ==

Dismantling the right's use of desert arguments will need to encroach in
a big way upon the failings and strengths of the self-ownership thesis
we've inherited from Martin Luther and John Locke. This is extremely
difficult territory to navigate when explaining social causation and the
sources of selfhood in terms citizens can easily digest. The quotes I
posted from Frank Knight show how a "secular Calvinist" and darling of
the right can provide a toehold when the policy wonking begins in
earnest. Demonstrating that the libertarian approach to responsibility
and causation can no longer carry the explanatory and justificatory
burden many on the right simply assume to be valid has been taken up
quite a bit lately by political philosophers in the journals Philosophy
and Public Affairs and Ethics and are well worth checking out.


Ian
  





Re: EC subsidies redux

2002-12-16 Thread Peter Dorman
Does anyone know why Oxfam has jumped on this bandwagon?

Peter

Ian Murray wrote:


Oxfam savages EC farm export reforms

Andrew Osborn in Brussels
Tuesday December 17, 2002
The Guardian

Long-awaited proposals to abolish most of the EU's notorious farm export
subsidy regime drew a withering response from aid agencies yesterday.

Accusing the European commission of betraying the interests of farmers
in the developing world, the agencies said the proposals were belated,
half-baked and completely irrelevant, doing nothing to stop EU farmers
from dumping millions of tonnes of subsidised farm products on poor
countries every year.

The proposals, presented by the EC yesterday as the EU's contribution to
the latest round of global trade talks, offer to reduce import tariffs
by 36%, cut export subsidies by 45% and lower trade distorting domestic
farm support by 55%.

According to aid agencies, the proposals are not half as generous as
they seem and the fact that they are contingent upon the US following
the EU's example mean they are worth less than nothing.

It's either an act of malice or a pre-Christmas leg pull, Kevin
Watkins, head of research at Oxfam, said. If you read between the lines
it does almost nothing. The reduction in export subsidies will only take
effect by 2013, which means that the EU will still be paying out
billions of dollars in subsidies a year.

It talks of cutting trade-distorting subsidies but doesn't include
direct payments to farmers at all.

Crucially, some of the EU's biggest farm exports such as sugar, dairy
products and beef were excluded altogether.

A fifth of the world's population lives on a dollar a day and
three-quarters of those people are small farmers.

Many of those farmers are forced to compete against floods of EU farm
imports which have been heavily subsidised by European taxpayers and,
according to Oxfam, they were the biggest losers yesterday.

The commission has signalled that it is genetically incapable of
producing a proposal that takes account of the interests of developing
countries, Mr Watkins said. It is always going to put the interests of
its own agri-business first and that's a tragedy.

This is a dumpers' charter. It will allow the EU to continue to
subsidise big farmers. The EU is incapable of exercising global
leadership in this area.

Anticipating the criticism, Franz Fischler, EU farm commissioner, said
he had done the best he could. These are substantial changes. Let us
not underestimate them.

He noted that EU farm export subsidies had dwindled over the past 10
years from 30% to 8% of the bloc's budget.

Pascal Lamy, the EU trade commissioner, mounted a vigorous defence:
This is a win-win proposal. It is fair to others, particularly
developing countries, as it takes into account their development needs.

Oxfam said that the commission could have been far more generous. It
could and should have tackled all forms of export subsidies and done so
immediately, it claimed.

[The EC proposal] would leave untouched the great majority of subsidies
that ruin the lives of poor people in developing countries, said Justin
Forsyth, Oxfam's policy director.


 





Re: Easterbrook's claims

2002-11-20 Thread Peter Dorman




See the most recent State of Working America, put out by the Economic
Policy Institute (and available at the moment only in pre-pub form), or any
of the recent SoWA's. The evidence on inequality is mind-numbing in its
detail and thoroughness. Easterbrook doesn't have the slightest basis for
his claim about immigration. Which says that his economics is on the same
exalted level as his ecology.

Peter

F G wrote:
I followed the link posted
by Lou where Easterbrook review's Singer's new  book:
http://www.washingtonmonthly.com/features/2001/0211.easterbrook.html
  
Much of the article is not worth responding to, since it argues that  "globalization"
is good without bothering to define it. However, I was  interested in the
following claims:
  
snip
  
"(And the endless "widening gap between rich and poor" in the United States?
This is an artifact of the huge rise in legal immigration in the last two
decades. Factor out the low incomes of the newly arrived foreign-born, and
the gap between rich and poor Americans is shrinking. But that's a story
for  another day.)"
  
Any comments on this? Note that the massive rise in immigration is at least
in part due to global inequality and third world regression.
  
-Frank G.
  
  
_
Help STOP SPAM with the new MSN 8 and get 2 months FREE*  http://join.msn.com/?page=features/junkmail
  





Re: derailing trade talks

2002-11-19 Thread Peter Dorman
I for one am irritated with the new correct line on trade in 
agricultural goods: agricultural subsidies are bad, and free trade is 
the solution for impoverished farmers in the third world.  (1) If we 
want to reverse the continuing transformation of agriculture into 
unsustainable and de-cultured exploitation of nature, there is no 
alternative to large-scale subsidies.  There are legitimate questions, 
of course, in how the subsidies should be administered.  (2) Export-led 
development is no more the answer for third world agriculture than it is 
for third-world industry.  Even worse, it erases opportunities for 
subsistence at a time when extreme poverty is ubiquitous.  (3) What 
empirical research there is suggests that, even in narrowly-specified 
market terms, there is a very small gain to be had to third world 
farmers from free trade in agriculture.

Let's work to build a vibrant, sustainable rural culture in our own 
countries, and healthy domestic markets and egalitarian access to 
resources in the third world (and vice versa).

Peter

Ian Murray wrote:

Short takes a tilt at CAP

EU subsidies will wreck trade talks and drive up poverty, says development
secretary

Larry Elliott, economics editor
Tuesday November 19, 2002
The Guardian

Clare Short, the international development secretary, will today attack the
common agricultural policy with a warning to the European Union that failure
to cut huge farming subsidies will deepen poverty in developing countries by
wrecking global trade talks.

Her intervention is a clear sign of Britain's belief that last month's deal
between Germany and France to ring-fence spending on the CAP for the next 10
years will harm poor countries. She will say that resistance to measures
that would prevent over-production and the dumping of excess crops on world
markets will destroy the chances of trade liberalisation talks succeeding.

She will urge today's meeting of the EU general affairs and external
relations council in Brussels, which is finalising Europe's policy on trade
and development, to join opposition to production subsidies that lead to
goods being sold on world markets at prices lower than they cost to produce.

The World Trade Organisation launched the current round of talks in Doha
last No vember, but progress has so far been stymied by the failure of the
West to make good promises on agricultural reform. Pressure from seven of
the EU's 15 member states - France, Italy, Spain, Portugal, Greece, Austria
and Ireland - has resulted in any mention of CAP reform being omitted from
the draft to be discussed by ministers today.

Ms Short will tell the meeting that any money Europe spends on agriculture
must be diverted into support for rural communities rather than be used to
finance over-production. We must be committed to reform of the CAP to
deliver on the Doha measures. Failure to do so would cause fatal damage to
the prospects of Doha succeeding, she said last night.

Developing countries had only signed up for a new round of talks in Doha a
year ago because they had won assurances that the EU and the US would take
steps to scale back subsidies for farmers. Developing countries made it
clear that there would be no trade round unless they made gains. That's why
the promises were made. Now the European Union has to deliver.

Ms Short said that unless the EU agreed to disconnect pro duction from
subsidies, it will be destroying Doha. We had an unprecedented consensus a
year ago when the talks were launched.

If the Doha round goes sour it will break that up, it will endanger the WTO
and it will lead to the further marginalisation of poor countries.

Her intervention in the increasingly bitter row over the future of the CAP
comes as the chancellor, Gordon Brown, plans to call on the West to support
a new deal for Africa.

He will spend the next few months seeking support among the G7 industrial
nations for a four-part package, which would include better access to rich
western markets and a doubling of aid to $100bn (£63bn) a year in return for
economic stability and proposals by poor countries to root out corruption.

Britain was furious at last month's deal between France's Jacques Chirac and
Germany's Gerhard Schröder to maintain spending on the CAP, which costs
Europe £25bn a year. Sources said that France's avowed concern about the
plight of Africa and Spain's interest in Latin America were at odds with
their point-blank refusal to discuss meaningful CAP reform.
 





Re: protection rents, part 1

2002-11-19 Thread Peter Dorman
It's beginning to look like, financially, Iraq II will be the opposite 
of Iraq I.  Ten years ago, the US fought the war as a mercenary and was 
repaid by other capitalist powers; we ended up with an approximately 
$100B transfer on the current account.  This time around, the US will 
have to be the one to shell out for acquiescence to an unpopular war.

Peter

Ian Murray wrote:

U.S. Discusses Aid for Turkey to Defray Costs of an Iraq War


By Bradley Graham
Washington Post Staff Writer
Tuesday, November 19, 2002; Page A20


The United States has begun discussions about compensating Turkey for
economic losses and other costs likely to be incurred in a U.S.-led war
against Iraq, according to American and Turkish officials.

Both sides described the discussions as still at an early stage and marked
by a wide gap in what the Turks would like to receive and what the United
States is willing to pay. But the mere existence of the talks, which
participants said were initiated by the United States within the past two
months, reflects the importance that U.S. officials place on Turkey in any
war with Iraq.

A longtime NATO ally bordering northern Iraq, Turkey is in position to serve
as a crucial base for U.S. military operations. Its bases and airfields
would likely be prime staging areas for American forces, and Turkish troops
could play a significant role policing the flow of refugees from Iraq or
guarding prisoners of war. At the same time, U.S. officials have expressed
concern that Turkish forces may attempt to take advantage of a war and
occupy northern Iraq to block the creation of an autonomous Kurdish region,
which could serve as a base of operations for Turkey's own separatist Kurds.

Preparing for possible military conflict with Iraq, the Bush administration
has launched a number of diplomatic and military moves to secure basing,
overflight rights and other crucial assistance from countries in the Persian
Gulf region and elsewhere. But U.S. officials described the offer of
economic assistance to Turkey as unusual, saying similar discussions have
been initiated with only one other ally in the region -- Jordan.

We've told them that if there is military action against Iraq, we would
recognize that Turkey would have some losses and we would have to move in
some fashion to help them, a senior administration official said.

As another sign of the high-level attention that Turkey is receiving within
the administration, President Bush got involved yesterday in furthering
Turkey's bid to join the European Union. He phoned the EU president, Danish
Prime Minister Anders Fogh Rasmussen, and stressed the importance of
advancing Turkey's evolution toward membership when EU leaders convene in
Denmark next month, according to a White House spokesman. Bush also plans to
meet with Turkish President Ahmet Sezer on Wednesday while the two leaders
are in Prague for a NATO summit.

Turkey already allows U.S. and British warplanes to use an air base at
Incirlik to patrol a no-fly zone over northern Iraq established after the
1991 Persian Gulf War. U.S. authorities express little doubt that Turkey
would support the United States in another war with Iraq.

But Turkish officials fear the potential economic and political
consequences. Turkey lost billions of dollars in tourist revenue and trade
with Iraq as a result of the 1991 war and confronted a surge in Kurdish
refugees. With their economy now in recession, many Turks see another war as
undercutting the prospects of recovery and further straining their country's
massive debt burden, which is being helped by $16 billion from the
International Monetary Fund. They also express concern that a war could
reignite unrest in Turkey's mainly Kurdish southeast, where the military has
spent much of the last two decades fighting Kurdish separatists.

It was public outrage over the state of the economy that helped fuel a
victory in Turkey's national election earlier this month by the Justice and
Development Party, whose leaders hold strong Islamic beliefs. So far,
however, U.S. officials say they have been encouraged by some of the new
leading party's initial moves. We're favorably impressed with the quality
of people being mentioned for the top economic posts and other ministerial
jobs, another senior administration official said.

U.S. and Turkish officials familiar with the discussions over a war
compensation package said several options have been mentioned, including
outright grants, preferential trade terms for Turkish exports to the United
States, U.S. military equipment transfers and contracts for Turkish firms to
help in the reconstruction of a post-war Iraq.

We've heard a wish list from the Turkish side, a senior official said.
There's a whole host of ways it could be structured.

Turkish authorities said they also hope for a significant boost in U.S. aid
even if no war comes. They say just the talk of war has shaken Turkey's
economy, discouraging tourism and trade, raising oil 

Re: Birds of a feather

2002-11-19 Thread Peter Dorman
In his first paragraph, Easterbrook reveals he hasn't read Singer, but 
rather the people who write about Singer.  Given his rather loose 
standards of  intellectual accountability (also revealed in his past 
writings on environmental issues), his endorsement of this latest book 
is of little interest.

Singer is not my favorite philosopher, but he's not bad for a utilitarian.

Peter

Louis Proyect wrote:

(Sooner or later it had to happen. Peter Singer, an animal rights 
leftist, who also argues that handicapped children should be killed 
for their own good, has written a new book promoting globalization in 
the Thomas Friedman Lexus and the Olive Tree mold. What's next? A 
proposal to turn famine victims in Africa into cattle feed? The 
reviewer Gregg Easterbrook is a knucklehead of long standing who has 
made a career out of debunking such hysterical fears that nuclear 
power, DDT, GM crops, etc. might be bad for you.)


Washington Monthly Online

Greatest Good for the Greatest Number

Philosopher Peter Singer will anger his traditional lefty fans with a 
clear-eyed account of the benefits of globalization.

By Gregg Easterbrook
 


Yes, it's that Peter Singer. The one who has suggested that animals 
sometimes have the same rights as people, that the old should be 
euthanized to divert resources to the young (though he would spare his 
own infirm mother), that Americans should give away almost everything 
they possess to the developing world and live themselves like the 
developing world's poor (Singer donates to charity but he hasn't given 
almost everything away, as he advised others to do, and won't give to 
bums on the street). The Peter Singer who has said that utilitarian 
arguments can justify killing the innocent if benefits to others are 
large (a chilling thought, but also U.S. policy, as it is on 
utilitarian grounds that U.S. forces have killed some innocent people 
during the campaign against al-Qaeda in Afghanistan; presumably, 
Singer supports this). The Peter Singer who has suggested that 
severely handicapped infants should be killed for their own good 
(strangely, only people who were not born severely handicapped take 
this view), whom The New Yorker has called the world's most 
influential living philosopher (which mainly tells us how little 
anyone cares about living philosophers, a state of affairs which the 
profession has largely brought on itself), and whose appointment to a 
chair at Princeton University aroused considerable alumni protests and 
the cancellation of some pledges. People have even protested the name 
of the chair he holds--Singer is now the Ira DeCamp Professor of 
Bioethics at the University Center for Human Values of Princeton. How 
can Singer have a chair at the University Center for Human Values, the 
line goes, when he is inhuman?

Yes, that Peter Singer. Since his views are much hashed over, it may 
be best to skip beyond his prior statements here, other than to make 
two points. First, as I wrote in the previous paragraph, Singer has 
suggested most of his notorious positions. There is, in fact, an 
awful lot of high-class weasel-wording in his work, indicating either 
that he can't make up his mind or that he wants to have it both ways, 
grabbing attention by saying stark things, then indignantly claiming 
misquotation and pointing to some buried caveat when attacked. Second, 
when The New Yorker called him out on how he can say that other 
people's aging mothers should be put down like old horses but that his 
own should receive only the very best care in an expensive nursing 
home, Singer replied, Perhaps it's more difficult than I thought 
before, because it is different when it is your mother. So my grand 
pronouncements apply to everyone else but not me! There's a word for 
this. And, as Peter Berkowitz has written, someone who presents 
himself to the world as an ethicist is supposed to have thought 
through the practical consequences of his ethics.

These points aside, One World is a pretty good book; if it did not 
come with Peter Singer baggage, I might say a darn good book. Singer, 
generally a hero to the loony left, struggles with the issues of 
globalization in a rigorously hard-headed manner rarely seen on this 
topic. Singer discards, or even shreds, much anti-globalization cant, 
focusing on which international economic policies will have the 
utilitarian outcome of raising living standards for the developing 
world's poor. (Singer does not much care for the term utilitarianism, 
but it is the best shorthand for his value system, whose fine points 
cannot be fit into this space; broadly, he wants to raise the 
standards at which the human race lives as a whole to the highest 
aggregate level, which entails focusing upon the disadvantages of the 
developing world, and thinks our obligations to all members of genus 
Homo have about the same standing as 

Re: Re: Re: Birds of a feather

2002-11-19 Thread Peter Dorman
Singer doesn't take the positions Easterbrook has attributed to him. 
You don't have to agree with Singer (I often don't) to appreciate this. 
There was an article in the Chronicle of Higher Ed about a year ago 
that was fair-minded, I thought, on Singer and his critics.  The man is 
not a monster...

Peter

e. ahmet tonak wrote:

How did you conclude that Easterbrook hasn't read Singer?

Peter Dorman wrote:


In his first paragraph, Easterbrook reveals he hasn't read Singer, 
but rather the people who write about Singer.  Given his rather loose 
standards of  intellectual accountability (also revealed in his past 
writings on environmental issues), his endorsement of this latest 
book is of little interest.

Singer is not my favorite philosopher, but he's not bad for a 
utilitarian.

Peter 







Re: RE: Re: economics on pen-l

2002-11-17 Thread Peter Dorman




Devine, James wrote:

  
  RE: [PEN-L:32288] Re: economics on pen-l
  Peter D writes:...
  I'm wondering whether foreign central banks are already
financing the 
  US current account deficit, in light of the weakness in
US financial 
  markets. 
  don't you think that it's foreign financiers that are
doing so, rather than central banks? they're buying up US assets, allowing
the US to run a current account deficit. If the CBs are doing anything, it's
accumulating dollars and dollar-denominated short-term assets because they
are useful reserves (since the dollar acts as world money). Do you think
that the CBs play a big role?

My suspicion is that the private inflow of investment has not kept up with
the US need for half a trillion a year. Certainly not in equities, and perhaps
also not in debt assets, due to possible exchange rate risk. The dollar
is indeed the world's liquidity, but its days (OK, years) are certainly numbered,
and sensible investors would want to avoid too much exposure. As I recall,
there was also a year during the early 80s when foreign CB's stepped in to
cover for the reluctance of private wealth-holders. I'm guessing that 2002
will also turn out to be such a year, but I could be wrong.

As to why the CB's would do this, you could take your pick from (1) it's
not in anyone's interest to have the dollar crash and bring down the global
economy with it, (2) they are protecting the private positions in the dollar
taken by their own nationals in particular, (3) they are supporting the US
as a bastion of free-market rectitude, and (4) they are supporting an overvalued
dollar to sustain their own export surpluses.

   
  ... If so, what implications, if any, does this
have for global 
  political economy? How can we explain Bushite unitaleralism
and 
  in-your-face hegemony in light of the increasing fragility
of the US 
  external position?
  the role of the dollar as world money is based on the
power of the US. Bushite hegemonism seems just one way to maintain and extend
that power, centering on the military side. The Clintonoids put greater emphasis
on the financial/economic side of US power along with trying to encourage
consent among the governed, don't you think? But these are variations on
a theme.

The strength of the dollar depends entirely on the willingness of the rest
of the world to accumulate them at the rate of one-half trillion a year.
Private wealth-holders will do so based on expectations of risk (exchange
rate and liquidity) and rate of return. Public dollar repositories (CB's)
will do so for either economic (including liquidity) or political reasons.
It seems to me that the Bushies cannot afford to alienate the interests
that govern CB decision-making. The current military power buildup may be
seen as a basis for supporting the dollar (an implicit quid pro quo if you
will), or it may be seen as reckless and overly unilateral. How would you
analyze the effect of US militarism on the willingness of CB's to accumulate
dollars?


  Moreover, if we assume that serious money is now
international 
  (international portfolios and their mirror-image, international
  
  ownership of corporations, financial institutions and tradeable
funds), 
  how do we think about the constraints, if any, on US economic
policy? 
  (It doesn't look like we have vehicles for domestic constraints
at the 
  moment.) Or is US policy really reflective of a global
consensus among 
  the rich?
  maybe a consensus, but one that reflects US power. 
  
  It's quite possible that the value of the dollar is currently
too high given the level of US power. But we can't know for sure. 
  Jim





Re: economics on pen-l

2002-11-15 Thread Peter Dorman
Agreed -- let's hear more analysis of the near-term economic situation. 
I'm wondering whether foreign central banks are already financing the 
US current account deficit, in light of the weakness in US financial 
markets.  (We won't know until the numbers come out, some time from 
now.)  If so, what implications, if any, does this have for global 
political economy?  How can we explain Bushite unitaleralism and 
in-your-face hegemony in light of the increasing fragility of the US 
external position?

Moreover, if we assume that serious money is now international 
(international portfolios and their mirror-image, international 
ownership of corporations, financial institutions and tradeable funds), 
how do we think about the constraints, if any, on US economic policy? 
(It doesn't look like we have vehicles for domestic constraints at the 
moment.)  Or is US policy really reflective of a global consensus among 
the rich?

Peter

Michael Perelman wrote:

The sh* is hitting the fan.  I think that knowledge of Bush's economics
plans will be very important in the coming months.  Some of us will be
called upon to make public statements about what is afoot.

Isn't it important that we do more to get us up to speed on such matters?

The bankruptcy bill, as Robert Manning has insisted, would have be strong
drag on the economy.  Tax cuts and privatizing employment will not have a
positive aggregate effect over and above its redistributional effects.

Also, the Repugs are trying to shift liability in a number of ways --
curtailing punative awards by electing conservative state courts,
restricting suits on vaccines, giving subsidies to terrorism insurance

--
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 530-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 






Political Economy of US foreign policy

2002-11-12 Thread Peter Dorman
Here's request #2 in my never-ending effort to put together a syllabus
for next quarter.  Does anyone have a suggestion for readings on the
political economy of US foreign policy, particularly military strategy?
The ideal reading would be fairly up to date, grounded in official
policy documents and descriptive of the iron fist that enforces the
invisible hand.  It would not be overly rhetorical, tendentious or
wedded to an idiosyncratic economic or political philosophy.  It could
be a book or a fairly comprehensive article.  It could be a case study
if it is grounded in a broader framework.

Please reply offlist.  Thanks.

Peter




Re: Oh!...uh...

2002-11-06 Thread Peter Dorman
Gil Skillman wrote:

 (Was: uh-oh ii)

 Will the Republicans quickly overreach themselves?  How much long-term damage
 can they do in two years?  Will the Democrats ever wake up?

 As for the third question, perhaps the
 adverse election results will finally shock the Demos into realizing that
 they're not going to succeed by acting like pseudo-Republicans.  If they're
 going to lose anyway, they might as well lose by addressing the issues,
 providing real alternative, and potentially energizing the alienated and
 marginalized who right now see now real choices.


Perhaps, but we should not forget that the implosion of the institutional left
(labor parties, social democratic parties, reformist parties like the Democrats,
etc.) has occurred in every advanced capitalist country.  The same vacuum on the
center-left can be found in the UK, France, Germany, Japan, you name it.
Obviously, something structural has taken place in the world economy that has
changed the balance everywhere.  I have some thoughts on this, but I'm ducking out
right now -- going offline for the next two days.  People usually don't reply to
my posts on this list, but I would be interested in seeing what speculations you
folks come up with.  Why is 2002 so different from 1962 or 1972?

Peter




Re: Roach on Asia

2002-11-01 Thread Peter Dorman
I'm still trying to book up on this topic, but it seems to me that China's entry
into the export-led growth game has been a crucial factor for many years now,
and probably played a contributing role in the 97 financial crisis.  Export-led
growth of the east asian variety has always been zero or near-zero sum, so the
infusion of Chinese supply capability is of overwhelming importance.  If this
view is correct, it suggests that an era is over (except perhaps for China),
particularly if US demand pulls back into a long-term equilibrium with income.

Peter

Ian Murray wrote:

 Global: Asia Is Now a Zero-Sum Game
 Stephen Roach (from Shanghai)

 Apart from China, there is no dynamism in Asia these days. At the end of a
 two-week Asian tour, I am struck by a grim sense of foreboding that is
 evident throughout this once vibrant region. While the growth story in China
 is alive and well, economies elsewhere in the region are sputtering, at
 best. As America slows, a US-centric global economy is in desperate need of
 a new growth engine. That engine is not to be found in Asia.

 The year 2002 has turned out to be an important stress test for a US-centric
 global economy. A sputtering American growth dynamic has taken a
 surprisingly heavy toll on the rest of the world. The reverberations have
 been especially acute in two key regions of the world -- Europe and Asia.
 Not only has the engineless global growth dynamic unmasked serious
 structural flaws in Euroland, but it has also revealed serious deficiencies
 in Asia's externally led growth model. As I have traveled extensively
 throughout the region over these past two weeks, the only question that
 seems to matter is the prognosis for the US economy. Needless to say, my
 answer does not exactly provide for a very uplifting discussion.

 It's always risky to generalize about a region so diverse as Asia. There are
 really three distinct stories to tell in Asia these days -- Japan, China,
 and the rest of the region. After all these years, I continue to be amazed
 at how Japan still has the potential to disappoint. And yet that's exactly
 what has happened to the latest reform effort. During my visit to Tokyo 10
 days ago, you could literally feel a sense of movement in the air. The
 Takenaka effort at bank reform, in the aftermath of the Bank of Japan's
 radical purchase of equities, spoke of a new potential to break a dozen
 years of inertia. And I fell for it. But the leadership of the ruling LDP
 party demonstrated once again what makes Japan's case for reform so
 hopeless. Yet another effort at cleaning up the banking system was quashed
 by the power structure. The moral hazard of Japan's convoy system emerges
 once again very much intact -- banks remain too big to fail, as do their
 zombie-like corporate borrowers. Meanwhile, the Japanese economy has taken
 yet another turn for the worse, as evidenced by recent disappointing trends
 in industrial production, inventories, employment, and personal consumption.
 It's déjà vu all over again. Sadly, Japan just doesn't seem as if it will
 ever get up off the mat again.

 Nor is the rest of Asia (excluding China) standing on its own and resisting
 the pressures of a tough global climate. Korea -- where hope for vigor was
 highest in the first half of this year -- has suddenly slowed. Industrial
 output growth screeched to a near halt in September, and private consumption
 growth has slowed markedly; even Korean export growth has slipped from the
 heady gains recorded earlier this year. In Taiwan, the recent US port strike
 appears to have prompted some August-September gyrations; however, looking
 through the noise, rising unemployment and likely fourth quarter moderation
 in output and export growth all point to a decided deceleration of the
 Taiwanese economy well into 2003. Meanwhile, manufacturing output growth has
 slowed appreciably in Singapore and Thailand, whereas Hong Kong remains
 trapped by the twin forces of deflation and rising unemployment. Lacking in
 domestic demand, the smaller economies of Asia have little to show for
 themselves in the face of a US-led slowdown in external demand.

 And then there's China -- an entirely different story. In contrast to the
 near synchronous slowing elsewhere in Asia, the Chinese economy is on an
 accelerating growth path. All of the September numbers were sending
 unambiguous signals of a quickening of economic activity. That's true of
 industrial output, exports, infrastructure spending, and foreign direct
 investment. It's also true of an equally impressive acceleration in GDP
 growth to an 8.1% YoY rate in 3Q02 (see my October 17 dispatch, The China
 Factor). China continues to be the fastest-growing economy in Asia, or for
 that matter, the world. And that's true irrespective of the slowdown in the
 broader global economy.

 The math of China's growth contribution underscores the key role this
 country is playing in driving Asian and global growth. At current 

Re: RE: Re: against lesser of two evils

2002-11-01 Thread Peter Dorman


"Devine, James" wrote:
> This is not principled politics.
It is
> old-fashioned liberal pragmatism.
so are you saying that Leon Trotsky should have rejected
any connection with John Dewey, because he was the leader of liberal pragmatism?
Jim
As a fan of Dewey in his more radical moments (see Westbrook's bio), I've
sometimes wondered whether he should have associated with Trotsky...
Of course, the Moscow trials were the greater of any number of evils.
Peter



Re: Now for the real fight over Iraqi oil

2002-10-30 Thread Peter Dorman
I can understand the concerns of European capitalists that they will be locked
out of Iraq, but if I were the betting type, I would put my money on the
probability of a compromise by the Bushies on this.  They will probably gouge a
little (old habits die hard), but I think they would put mending fences among
major capitalist interests above goodies for their cronies.  Russia could well
be out in the cold after the rubble clears, however.

In the end, the war is more than just a financial investment.

Peter

Chris Burford wrote:

  From today's Guardian, no lightweight article:-

 BP chief fears US will carve up Iraqi oil riches
 
 Terry Macalister Wednesday October 30, 2002 The Guardian
 
 Lord Browne, chief executive of BP and one of New Labour's favourite
 industrialists, has warned Washington not to carve up Iraq for its own oil
 companies in the aftermath of any future war.
 
 The comments from the most senior European oil executive, who has
 impeccable political connections in the UK, will be seen by anti-war
 protesters as further proof that US president George Bush has already made
 his mind up about an early attack.
 
 They will also serve to underline concern that the US is primarily
 concerned with seizing control of Saddam Hussein's oil and handing it over
 to companies such as ExxonMobil rather than destroying his weapons of mass
 destruction.
 
 Britain's biggest company is reviewing what impact a regime change in
 Baghdad would have on its own business and global crude supplies.
 
 Both London and Washington have been lobbied by the UK oil giant, which is
 concerned that European companies could be left out in the cold.
 
 We have let it be known that the thing we would like to make sure, if
 Iraq changes regime, is that there should be a level playing field for the
 selection of oil companies to go in there if they're needed to do the work
 there, said Lord Browne yesterday at a briefing on the company's results.
 
 Lord Browne said that most exploration for new supplies had halted there
 when the Iraqis nationalised their industry. But he believed there was a
 plenty of oil and gas waiting to be discovered in Iraq and that BP should
 be in prime position to capitalise because it had found most of the
 country's oil before being thrown out in the 1970s.
 
 BP said it had had no contact with Baghdad since 1989. Iraq's reserves
 amount to 115bn barrels of oil, making it the biggest source of oil in the
 world behind Saudi Arabia.
 
 Lord Browne's views will be listened to carefully in Downing Street
 because the BP executive team has such close links with the UK government
 that it was once dubbed Blair Petroleum. A number of former BP executives,
 such as Lord Simon, have been seconded into Whitehall while one of Mr
 Blair's personal assistants, Anji Hunter, joined Lord Browne's team.
 
 Impending war with Iraq has given a financial boost to BP and other
 western oil firms by driving up the price of oil to $27 per barrel.

 Could there be a folk memory here of past imperialist glories and intimate
 relationships with government?

 Google comes up with a BBC briefing of 11 Aug 1998:

   the company's origins go back to 1901, when a wealthy Englishman,
  William Knox D'Arcy, ventured into the Iranian desert to search for oil.
 
 For seven years, Mr D'Arcy battled with difficult terrain, an uncertain
 political situation and rising costs.
 
 But in 1908 the venture found oil in southwest Persia. One year later,
 Anglo-Persian Oil was formed.
 
 However, by then most of the company was owned by the Burmah Oil company.
 
 Government backing
 
 Shortly before World War I, Anglo-Persian managed to find a new backer -
 and good customer.
 
 After lengthy negotiations, the oilmen promised Winston Churchill, then
 First Lord of the Admiralty, secure supplies of oil.
 
 In exchange the British government injected £2m of new capital into the
 company, acquired a controlling interest and became de-facto the hidden
 power behind the oil company.
 
 The years between the wars were an era of expansion, with exploration in
 Canada, South America, Africa, Papua and Europe.
 
 In 1935 the company was renamed Anglo-Iranian Oil Company.
 
 
 British Petroleum
 
 1951was a crucial year in the company's history. Iran decided to
 nationalise the company's assets, which back then were the UK's largest
 single investment overseas.
 
 Three years later the conflict was resolved - in the same year that the
 company was renamed British Petroleum Company.
 
 The Iranian crisis had convinced BP that it had to broaden its activities.
 In the following years the company started explorations in other Middle
 East countries, like Kuwait, Libya and Iraq.

 Forget about Sadaam Hussein, lets sort out the real imperialist battle once
 and for all, with the USA, unless they are prepared to give us intrepid
 Brits a genuine level playing field!Willie Knox D'Arcy would have
 demanded no more and no less.

 Chris Burford

 London

globalization text

2002-10-30 Thread Peter Dorman
Can anyone out there help me find a suitable book for an undergraduate
course that covers, among other things, globalization?  The ideal book
would have description of the main institutions, economic and political
history since at least 1980, discussion of global economics and economic
outcomes and linkages between economics, politics, and the other
dimensions (military force, race, gender, culture, etc.).  The political
stance is largely irrelevant, since the students will be getting plenty
of PE theory and immersion in specific issues elsewhere.

So far, I've looked at the new Tabb books (Elephant, Uneven Partners),
and I don't find nearly enough substance in them for students new to the
topic.  Last night I checked out recent books by Gilpin and Scholte, as
well as a reader edited by Held and McGrew.  Scholte and HM were much
too soft: very little factual information, with mostly theoretical
debates of interest to globalization academics (is glob new or old, do
states have more power or less, what is the fate of postmodernism, and
so on).  Scholte appears to have no background whatsoever in economics;
the closest he comes is second-hand Marxism.  Hence no significant
discussion of global finance, etc.  As for Gilpin, there's actually too
much economic material -- he's too detailed in his treatment of
technical questions in international economic negotiations.  His
neoclassical mindset becomes a problem in that he foregrounds some
issues (like the putative imperative of overcoming protectionism) at the
expense of others that need much more treatment (like alternative
development strategies).

So none of the above are adequate.  I'm open to other suggestions.
Again, I couldn't care less what the analytical bias of the author is,
so long as the relevant material gets covered.  Students here (at
Evergreen) seminar on all their readings, and they will take apart
anything we put in front of them (usually).  Other readings have already
armed them for the task.  A cogent right-wing text would serve our
purposes just as well as a more sympatico left-wing one -- and much
better than a flabby progressive text.

You can reply offlist if you want, and I will summarize for our vast and
growing public.

Thanks,
Peter




Re: RE: globalization text

2002-10-30 Thread Peter Dorman


Too narrow -- it focuses just on the financial architecture problems that
were debated by the mainstream after the '97 panic. I'm really surprised
Robin wrote such a narrowly-fucused (and unradical) book.
Peter


"Devine, James" wrote:

how about Robin Hahnel's skinny book?

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]  http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine

> -Original Message-
> From: Peter Dorman [mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
> Sent: Wednesday, October 30, 2002 9:54 AM
> To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
> Subject: [PEN-L:31687] globalization text
>
>
> Can anyone out there help me find a suitable book for
an undergraduate
> course that covers, among other things, "globalization"?
The
> ideal book
> would have description of the main institutions, economic
and
> political
> history since at least 1980, discussion of global economics
> and economic
> outcomes and linkages between economics, politics,
and the other
> dimensions (military force, race, gender, culture,
etc.).
> The political
> stance is largely irrelevant, since the students will
be
> getting plenty
> of PE theory and immersion in specific issues elsewhere.
>
> So far, I've looked at the new Tabb books (Elephant,
Uneven Partners),
> and I don't find nearly enough substance in them for
students
> new to the
> topic. Last night I checked out recent books
by Gilpin and
> Scholte, as
> well as a reader edited by Held and McGrew. Scholte
and HM were much
> too "soft": very little factual information, with mostly
theoretical
> debates of interest to globalization academics (is
glob new or old, do
> states have more power or less, what is the fate of
postmodernism, and
> so on). Scholte appears to have no background
whatsoever in
> economics;
> the closest he comes is second-hand Marxism.
Hence no significant
> discussion of global finance, etc. As for Gilpin,
there's
> actually too
> much economic material -- he's too detailed in his
treatment of
> technical questions in international economic negotiations.
His
> neoclassical mindset becomes a problem in that he foregrounds
some
> issues (like the putative imperative of overcoming
> protectionism) at the
> expense of others that need much more treatment (like
alternative
> development strategies).
>
> So none of the above are adequate. I'm open to
other suggestions.
> Again, I couldn't care less what the analytical bias
of the author is,
> so long as the relevant material gets covered.
Students here (at
> Evergreen) seminar on all their readings, and they
will take apart
> anything we put in front of them (usually). Other
readings
> have already
> armed them for the task. A cogent right-wing
text would serve our
> purposes just as well as a more sympatico left-wing
one -- and much
> better than a flabby progressive text.
>
> You can reply offlist if you want, and I will summarize
for
> our vast and
> growing public.
>
> Thanks,
> Peter
>
>



Re: Request for comments on the debt crisis

2002-10-28 Thread Peter Dorman
I'm not an expert on it, but my sense of the literature on economic dualism
is that the US is among the countries with the greatest disparity between
small and large firms.  Large firms live in a world largely sheltered from
market risk (although see Ford); small firms are fully exposed with little
support.  It's as if there were a two-stage process: a darwinian struggle
for start-ups and near-socialism for the big guys.

Peter

Michael Perelman wrote:

 I am including a short comment in a new ms. in a section on the rhetoric
 of risk.  I would appreciate any comments, suggestions 

 Walter Wriston once wrote:
 ##The men and women who founded our country were ... adventurers who
 took personal risks of the most extreme kind   Today, however, the
 idea is abroad in the land that the descendants of these bold
 adventurers should be sheltered from risk and uncertainty as part of our
 national heritage   At bottom, democracy itself rests on an act of
 faith, on a belief in individual responsibility and the superiority of
 the free marketplace.  [Wriston 1986]
 People unfamiliar with Wriston's career might not fully appreciate the
 humor in his words.  At the time he was writing, Citibank had only
 recently become deeply enmeshed in the Latin American debt crisis.
 Citibank was getting nearly 50 percent of its income from its loans to
 Latin America.  The bank was intent on selling as much credit as
 possible to Latin America.  It made these loans without much thought
 about the ability of Latin American to repay them.  Citibank did not
 have to worry much about default.
 Later, the United States, in part through the IMF, forced a brutal
 austerity on Latin America to squeeze as much repayment as possible out
 of these loans.  In short, the loans involved serious risk, but those
 who bore the brunt of the risk were the poor of Latin America who are
 still suffering the consequences.

 --

 Michael Perelman
 Economics Department
 California State University
 [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Chico, CA 95929
 530-898-5321
 fax 530-898-5901




Re: Bush Chavez: strange bedfellows?

2002-10-24 Thread Peter Dorman


Boy, is that NPR person off-base. Chavez is an OPEC militant who
wants oil prices to go up. While the short run effect of an attack
on Iraq would be exactly that, if the US sets up its intended protectorate,
you can bet the spigot will be wide open. Could Chavez really be
that dumb?
Peter (back on pen-l but still totally frantic)


"Devine, James" wrote:

Today's "Morning Edition" on U.S. National Public Radio
reported that Pres. Hugo Chavez has refrained from criticizing Bush in
recent months (despite the U.S.-backed coup attempt) and speaks under a
banner labeled "Venezuela and the U.S. More United Than Ever" (or something
like that). He has not criticized the seemingly forthcoming attack on Iraq.
According to NPR's reporter, it's because of convergence of interests surrounding
oil.

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]  http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine



signing off

2002-03-21 Thread Peter Dorman

I'm signing off PEN-L for the spring, since I'll be on leave, and it's a
bother to download large numbers of e-mail messages on my college's
web-based mail server.  If anyone needs to reach me for any reason, you
can still send mail to me individually.

Bon voyage, moi.

Peter




Re: Nash game theory

2002-03-19 Thread Peter Dorman

I very much like the critique of Nash's approach in GAME THEORY: A
CRITICAL INTRODUCTION by Hargreaves Heap and Varoufakis.

As a very general statement, my main gripe with the mainstream economics
appropriation of game theory is its fixation with solutions.  Game
theory is too abstract to have much value as a predictive machine, and
what value is there to assuming a very specific set of rules, payoffs
etc. just to get a particular outcome?  I think the main point of game
theory is to present a syntax for analyzing complex strategic
interactions.

Peter

Ian Murray wrote:

 - Original Message -
 From: Justin Schwartz [EMAIL PROTECTED]

 
  But Nash  Harsanyi made real contributions to
 economics.

 ==

 For an excellent comparative critique of GT see
 Wolfgang Balzer's Game Theory and Power Theory: A
 Critical Comparison in Thomas Wartenberg ed.
 Rethinking Power.




Re: RE: Re: Systems of innovation

2002-03-07 Thread Peter Dorman

Interesting question.  I just got back from a conference in which I hung out
with mid-upper level policy-makers.  I get the sense that there is an acceptable
zone for economic policy from the vantage point of the permanent government,
and that, for the most part, lobbying, bribery, etc. move decisions within that
zone.  In that respect economic policy is different from, say, enviro policy.

Peter

Devine, James wrote:

 I think there is a perception in Washington that US-based firms have a
 durable technological advantage in both financial and nonfinancial services,
 and that any measure that increases their scope and market access is good
 national economic policy. 

 to what extent do our fearless leaders care about good national economic
 policy? I get the impression that everything is in terms of what's good for
 the most influential businesses, what fits with the ideology du jour
 (neoliberalism), and what won't cause a big public relations stink.
 Jim Devine




Re: Re: Re: RE: Re: Re: Re: Yen still overvalued

2002-03-07 Thread Peter Dorman

In this context I'm referring to the specific problem of changing over the installed
capital stock.  There is another restructuring problem in the CEE, which is more
social (i.e. social relations of production) and has to do with disseminating a
management system capable of competing with W. Europe.  Again, this is not about
what should take place in a better world -- simply adapting to the dictates of the
existing capitalist context, under the (possibly false) assumption that countries
smaller than the US have little leeway on these questions.

Peter

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 Peter,

 What are you suggesting here?  What kind of restructuring are you
 referring to? As someone who has spent the last 10 years studying
 and publishing on the Slovenian transition process, I'm mystified at
 what you are referring to.

 Paul Phillips,
 Economics,
 Universityof Manitoba

  2. Except for Slovenia (where there was arguably not too much restructuring to
  perform), it hasn't been completed yet.




Sweatshops

2002-03-06 Thread Peter Dorman

The critique of the neoclassical argument is straightforward.  We are not
saying people would be better off in the informal sector or on the land than in
a sweatshop.  We are saying that there are other, repressed alternatives that
are better than any of these.

Hell, just unlocking the doors (so people don't get cremated on the job) and
not firing women if they get pregnant is a superior, repressed alternative.

Peter

 Doug Henwood wrote:A friend of mine who spent a few years as a reporter
 in
 Vietnam interviewed Nike workers who told her that they prefer their
 sweatshop jobs to what they would have been  doing otherwise - things like
 chasing rats in rice paddies (not much fun to be a woman on the farm).
 




Re: Re: Yen still overvalued

2002-03-06 Thread Peter Dorman

Responses:

Charles Jannuzi wrote:

  Peter Dorman

  Let me try another tack here.  My understanding has been that Japan has
  been historically locked into a pattern of development characterized by
  high savings rates and high investment shares of GDP (the
  exhilirationist model).

 What do you mean by high investment shares of GDP? Aren't all developing
 countries that are growing rapidly (actually developing) like this? Japan
 went from worse than the Philippines in 1945 to a fully developed country by
 most standards by 1970. This historical fact, more than anything, was what
 was most appealing to other Asian countries looking for a development model.
 For one thing, it was the Japanese, not the Americans, who could understand
 where these countries were and where they wanted to go. Also, Japanese
 products and services often better fit these countries not for cultural
 reasons but just for the fact that Japan was a modern country with two
 living  generations who had experienced and remembered disaster and grinding
 poverty (which might help explain the personal penchant for stressing
 savings in big banks and postal savings and insurance). How Americans in
 2002 could say their town or family business benefited from a World Bank
 loan?

I'm not saying the high savings -- high investment rates weren't warranted, just
that this pattern can be difficult to maintain.


 Each validates the other, and both are made
  feasible by a large trade surplus: this prevents the high rate of
  savings from becoming a Keynesian burden and it generates the induced
  demand for investment.

  According to this view, Japan is in the midst of a protracted adjustment
  crisis, which can either be explained by increased competition with
  other east Asian exporters for the available (i.e. US) markets, or by
  the maturation thesis, according to which domestic consumption can no
  longer be constrained and the economy loses its export advantage.

 This obsesses on exports as if they were something other than just
 something you shipped and sold overseas for a loss or profit. They are not
 the key to understanding deflation or lack of profitability in the domestic
 economy. The Japanese didn't lose the car market in America to cheap
 exporters from Asia. Rather, the high yen squeezed their profits on the
 quotas they have been allowed to sell in the American market. Meanwhile,
 profits have always been limited in Japan in cars because of the intense
 competition among all the Japanese producers of cars.  Take away automobiles
 and parts and some very advanced electronics, and Japan runs trade deficits
 with the rest of the world. Yet no where in the developed world even has it
 been agreed that by principles of free trade these industries should be
 surrendered to Japanese dominance. In fact, quite the opposite is the case
 if you track trade policy and its results from about Reagan II onward.


My comment was not about profits but the adequacy of effective demand.  High
investment leads to high capacity which requires high demand.  If it ain't
domestic, it comes from net exports.  In recent years Japan has run bilateral
trade deficits with several east Asian countries, no?


  In
  either case, much of the capital stock is revealed as misinvested --
  and this on top of the bad bets made during the bubble period.

 If companies and their banks can't decide what is and what is not well
 invested, who can? God?

 Also, what is normally a good bet in a modestly growing economy can be
 something quite different in a recession, don't you think?


Yes, that's my point.  With changing sources and patterns (and levels) of
demand, investments that made sense during the planning phase can be revealed as
mistaken ex post.


 The
  Japanese system of pooling financial risk supposedly slows down the
  adjustment process; hence the outside calls for restructuring via
  write-offs and default.

 I think if you could think like an 'analyst' at an investment bank in Tokyo
 (most linked to interests in the US) you would see the calls have nothing to
 do with a slow Japanese adjustment process and the ineluctable need for
 'restructuring' but rather the need to find profits now that the North
 American equity market is flat. I say Japanese companies operating on
 microeconomic principles not much different than what Americans or Europeans
 are used to have restructured and altered radically in the past decade.
 Perhaps far more radically than anything that's been going on in North
 America or Europe.
 This hasn't miraculously turned around the non-growing economy or deflation.


There is debate about this, as I understand.  The question I've seen posed is,
how can you accelerate the writeoff of nonperforming loans if doing so would
erase the equity position of much of the banking system?  I realize there are
powerful vultures out there, but that doesn't mean that any critical analysis of
Japanese financial practices is purely self

Re: Systems of innovation

2002-03-06 Thread Peter Dorman

There are definitely elements of this.  I think there is a perception in
Washington that US-based firms have a durable technological advantage in
both financial and nonfinancial services, and that any measure that
increases their scope and market access is good national economic policy.
This would go against what I said back in '98.  It's too soon to say for
sure, but my hunch is that no such advantage can be durable any more.  Also,
one of the questions people are asking post-Enron is to what extent the
apparent advantages of US corp's was an artifact of devious accounting
practices.

Peter

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 G'day Peter,

 You write:

  Right.  I argued in Actually Existing Globalization (published in a
  collection a
  few years ago) that industrial policy is ultimately understandable
  only as
  technology policy, but that the era of national technology (or
  innovation) systems
  is largely over.  At the time I reviewed some of the literature pro
  and con; I
  think there are some references in my article.  I'll be glad to send
  an electronic
  copy to anyone interested.
 
  Peter
 

 I've not seen the paper (and I'd really like to ... ), but I'd argue the
 US has exhibited many signs of an almost mercantilist corporatist policy
 approach to optimising intial advantage in IT - pushing TRIPs into the
 Uruguay Round, allowing anti-competitive mergers and such to ensure
 world-beating economies of scope and scale, pressuring the rest of the
 world into abandoning public telecommunications backbones - in fact -
 policy timing, from the ATT transformation, to fighting off Japanese
 HDTV standards, to the shift of the public/private internet debate in
 the early nineties, to letting the money-rich but opportunity-poor
 BabyBells off the leash in '96, to allowing media monoliths to
 consolidate across media in '02 - well, it all looks like a technology
 policy of sorts - perhaps at a structural (diffusion and control) rather
 than technical (invention and innovation) level (the DoD drove a lot of
 the latter before the end of the space race and Vietnam War occasioned a
 need for civvie market opportunities, in the context of the post '73 dip
 in national competitiveness and national accounts all 'round), but
 arguably a technology policy nevertheless.

 Or not?

 Cheers,
 Rob.




Re: RE: Re: Re: Re: Yen still overvalued

2002-03-06 Thread Peter Dorman

We shouldn't underestimate the problem of shifting the structure of production.
This was the same problem (only on an even larger scale) faced by the east
Europeans, and it was accomplished through massive downsizing.  But there are
two points to bear in mind:

1. The equity writeoffs accrued to compliant state owners, not capitalists with
the means and will to resist, and

2. Except for Slovenia (where there was arguably not too much restructuring to
perform), it hasn't been completed yet.

(None of the above should be construed as an endorsement of the particularly
restructuring going on in the CEE countries.  I offer it simply by way of
example and to suggest why Keynesian methods alone are not sufficient.)

Peter

Devine, James wrote:

 Gil writes:The interesting question, in light of Peter's assessment, is why
 the Japanese
 government can't use traditional Keynesian fiscal tools to pull itself out
 of
 the recession.

 1) the IMF and the assembled economic pooh-bahs argue against it.
 2) they've already done it a lot, building a lot of infrastructure, much of
 it useless, but never enough to get the Japanese economy moving again.
 3) they don't want to get into raising government consumption (building
 pyramids, as Keynes suggested) and they're still restricted from doing
 Military Keynesianism.

 But that doesn't mean that fiscal policy couldn't be used. My idea is that
 they should stimulate the Japanese economy by giving foreign aid to poor
 areas (such as East St. Louis, IL) that's tied, i.e., can only be spent on
 Japanese goods. This is what the U.S. did for many years.

 Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine






Re: Re: Yen still overvalued

2002-03-05 Thread Peter Dorman

Let me try another tack here  My understanding has been that Japan has
been historically locked into a pattern of development characterized by
high savings rates and high investment shares of GDP (the
exhilirationist model)  Each validates the other, and both are made
feasible by a large trade surplus: this prevents the high rate of
savings from becoming a Keynesian burden and it generates the induced
demand for investment

According to this view, Japan is in the midst of a protracted adjustment
crisis, which can either be explained by increased competition with
other east Asian exporters for the available (ie US) markets, or by
the maturation thesis, according to which domestic consumption can no
longer be constrained and the economy loses its export advantage  In
either case, much of the capital stock is revealed as misinvested --
and this on top of the bad bets made during the bubble period  The
Japanese system of pooling financial risk supposedly slows down the
adjustment process; hence the outside calls for restructuring via
write-offs and default

If this is true, the problem shows up in Keynesian fashion (reduced net
exports), deflationary pressure (competition with lower-wage producers
in the region), and persistent financial fragility

Comments?

Peter




Re: Systems of innovation

2002-03-05 Thread Peter Dorman

Right.  I argued in Actually Existing Globalization (published in a collection a
few years ago) that industrial policy is ultimately understandable only as
technology policy, but that the era of national technology (or innovation) systems
is largely over.  At the time I reviewed some of the literature pro and con; I
think there are some references in my article.  I'll be glad to send an electronic
copy to anyone interested.

Peter

Bill Rosenberg wrote:

 Is anyone familiar with the National Systems of Innovation approach to
 economic development?  The Labour/Alliance government has announced an economic
 strategy which is said to owe much to this. I understand that Chris Freeman
 (UK), Bengt-Åke Lundvall (Denmark), Charles Edquist (Sweden) and Richard Nelson
 (New York) are leaders in the field. Any views would be welcome.

 Bill




Is there a left program at the global level?

2002-02-08 Thread Peter Dorman

At first, I was irritated by Uchitelle's assertion that concrete proposals for change 
are not coming
from the streets but from more moderate types like Dani Rodrik.  But then I thought 
about it, and it
seemed to be more or less correct.  The excellent critiques of the existing system 
usually end with a
brief wish list of desired outcomes but not actual proposals, or where there are 
proposals they are
disappointingly nonradical.  (Perhaps the only exception is the demand for widespread 
debt relief, but
isn't this also defined in terms of the outcome and not the concrete mechanism?)

I'd like to be wrong.  I would love to say that our side has carefully thought-out 
demands to fight for,
and that the problem is just that they are being ignored or blacked out.  Please 
convince me that this
is so.

(And, no, the Tobin tax does not qualify as a radical proposal.)

Peter

Ian Murray wrote:

 [NYTimes]
 February 9, 2002
 Challenging the Dogmas of Free Trade
 By LOUIS UCHITELLE


snip


 The anti-globalization protests, including the protests near the Waldorf last 
weekend, have rallied
 tens of thousands of people against globalization and above all against its 
laissez-faire guiding
 principle. But the alternative visions that are beginning to be offered are not 
coming from the
 streets. They are coming instead from Mr. Rodrik, a professor at Harvard's Kennedy 
School of
 Government, and a handful of other economists, sociologists and political scientists.




Re: Export tax subsidies that aren't?

2002-02-05 Thread Peter Dorman

Well, we have theories of speculative dynamics in asset markets, and we have
case studies in policy outcomes for countries facing BOP/forex issues, and there
are Thirwall's Post Keynesian Lance Taylor's structuralist approaches.  Am I
missing anything?

The main point, though, is that there is a defensible notion of competitiveness
on a national level, and that cost-changing measures (subsidizing exports,
assassinating union leaders) are not simply offset by exchange rates; they have
impacts on aggregate flows.

Peter

Max Sawicky wrote:

  In a world in which transaction demand on the current account was the sole
  basis for forex markets, with constant PPP and never a whiff of pricing to
  market, then this type of analysis would make sense.  We're not
  in that world, however. Peter
 

 AND . . . . ???

 mbs




Re: Re: RE: Export tax subsidies that aren't?

2002-02-04 Thread Peter Dorman

In a world in which transaction demand on the current account was the sole
basis for forex markets, with constant PPP and never a whiff of pricing to
market, then this type of analysis would make sense.  We're not in that world,
however.

Peter

Michael Pollak wrote:

 On Wed, 30 Jan 2002, Max Sawicky wrote:

  The mainstream argument is that exchange rates adjust to wash away all
  tax advantages, whether legal or illegal.
 
  Not being a trade person, the best argument I can think of goes like
  this: If you want to buy US goods, you need dollars to pay for them.  A
  cost reduction in said goods [due to tax rebates for exports] increases
  demand for dollars relative to other currencies,

 Wouldn't a decrease in the total cost of goods lead to a *decrease* in the
 demand for dollars?  In which case, the rest of the mechanism:

  cost of dollar (and good, in importer's currency) go up, cost advantage
  disappears.

 would be thrown into reverse, and the currency swings would reinforce the
 effect of the original subsidy.

 Michael
 __
 Michael PollakNew York [EMAIL PROTECTED]




Re: RE: Re: RE: Export tax subsidies that aren't?

2002-02-04 Thread Peter Dorman

Max, this is governed by the, ahem, Marshall-Lerner conditions: the sum of
import and export price elasticities must be greater than one.  People who study
such things say the conditions are always met, but the structuralist tradition
holds that they are met only within limits.  This is something I've always
wanted to look at but never got around to.

Peter

Max Sawicky wrote:

 Depends on the price elasticity.  If the price of jellybeans goes down,
 do you spend more or less on jellybeans?  But I should beg off on this.
 I don't do trade.  --mbs

  Wouldn't a decrease in the total cost of goods lead to a *decrease* in the
  demand for dollars?  In which case, the rest of the mechanism:
 
   cost of dollar (and good, in importer's currency) go up, cost advantage
   disappears.
 
  would be thrown into reverse, and the currency swings would reinforce the
  effect of the original subsidy.
 
  Michael
  __
  Michael PollakNew York [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 




Re: World Economic Forum

2002-02-04 Thread Peter Dorman

Right, and meanwhile the politicians from mainstream social democratic parties
are hobnobbing with the World Social Forum in Brazil.  What does it take to some
real contestation these days?

Peter

Devine, James wrote:

 today's L.A. TIMES op-ed column by Arianna Huffington (not available on-line
 yet) makes it sound like the WEF in NYC is just a talk-shop, co-opting some
 of the outsiders who had demonstrated against such meetings in the past.
 Forum organizers had disinvited Ken Lay but invited community activist Van
 Jones, who was teargassed in Seattle protesting the World Trade Organization
 and hit by a police car in Washintone [DC] protesting the International
 Monetary Fund. In fact, they honored Jones as a 'global leader for
 tomorrow.'

 Going along with such co-optation, I am sure, is a disappearance of any real
 power that may have existed for the WEF. If there were any substantive
 decisions being made in the past, I'd bet that they've shifted over to some
 much less public venue.
 Jim Devine




Re: Re: Free Trade Game

2002-02-04 Thread Peter Dorman

You got it.

Peter

Robert Scott Gassler wrote:

 Sounds cool. How do I get one?

 Scott

 At 20:31 31/01/02 -0800, you wrote:
 I am able to announce, at long last, that I have finished the shipping
 version of Rice and Beans, a game I developed to demonstrate the
 critique of orthodox trade theory and its significance for the
 trade/environment debate.  (The same critique is easily extended to the
 trade/labor debate.)  The game is not especially fun to play -- it
 consists of six rounds, each illustrating a trade-and-regulation
 scenario -- and a lot of numbers get concocted and added up, but it does
 take players rather far into a stylized Post Keynesian universe
 (unemployment, imbalanced trade) in which a race to the bottom is a real
 possibility.  It is suitable for groups of 10-50 or so, and it takes
 about two hours to play, including the final discussion.  It has been
 classroom-tested.  (Please, no criticism from People for the Ethical
 Treatment of Students.)
 
 The game is contained in three files, available as WordPerfect or pdf: a
 six-page handount distributed to all players, one-page forms for players
 playing key roles, and a three-page user guide.
 
 Ask (offline) and ye shall receive.
 
 Peter
 
 



User Guide.pdf
Description: Adobe PDF document


Handout.pdf
Description: Adobe PDF document


Forms.pdf
Description: Adobe PDF document


Re: Re: Re: Free Trade Game

2002-02-04 Thread Peter Dorman

Oops.  I apologize to the assembled multitude -- didn't check to see whether
the message was off-list.

Peter

Peter Dorman wrote:

 You got it.

 Peter

 Robert Scott Gassler wrote:

  Sounds cool. How do I get one?
 
  Scott




Free Trade Game

2002-01-31 Thread Peter Dorman

I am able to announce, at long last, that I have finished the shipping
version of Rice and Beans, a game I developed to demonstrate the
critique of orthodox trade theory and its significance for the
trade/environment debate.  (The same critique is easily extended to the
trade/labor debate.)  The game is not especially fun to play -- it
consists of six rounds, each illustrating a trade-and-regulation
scenario -- and a lot of numbers get concocted and added up, but it does
take players rather far into a stylized Post Keynesian universe
(unemployment, imbalanced trade) in which a race to the bottom is a real
possibility.  It is suitable for groups of 10-50 or so, and it takes
about two hours to play, including the final discussion.  It has been
classroom-tested.  (Please, no criticism from People for the Ethical
Treatment of Students.)

The game is contained in three files, available as WordPerfect or pdf: a
six-page handount distributed to all players, one-page forms for players
playing key roles, and a three-page user guide.

Ask (offline) and ye shall receive.

Peter




Re: Re: strong dollar

2002-01-29 Thread Peter Dorman

Personally, I wouldn't jump to realist conclusions.  It's not at all clear to
me that Europe and Japan want to face the crises that would follow a
precipitous fall in the dollar.

Peter

Chris Burford wrote:

 At 28/01/02 20:28 -0800, Peter Dorman wrote:
 In the narrow sense, the strength of the dollar can be attributed to the
 weakness of other currencies, especially the yen and the euro.  The
 downward pressure on those two will continue for some time, I think.  If
 there were a viable rival to the dollar, fundamentals (the chronic US
 current account deficit) would express themselves much sooner.

 Does that not mean it is in the interests of Europe and Japan to start
 creating, no doubt by stealth, an alternative to the dollar as world money?
 That would mean that the relative advantage of having your currency as
 world money, is shared out.

 In a larger perspective, US foreign policy has been run to create the
 structural conditions for continuing the dollar as the reserve/key
 currency.  It's not so simple, of course, but I think that's the main
 effect.  If/when the dollar falls, it will set off a political crisis of
 succession as severe perhaps as the economic crisis.

 Europe and Japan will presumably have to take advantage of this under cover
 of international cooperation. Could they be willing to let their currencies
 fall until the point at which this undermines the advantages that the USA
 gets from its strong dollar policy?

 Then would they have reforms ready that would change the system, or just
 make minor repairs so it essentially continues with the mechanisms of
 unequal exchange.

 I suspect that talk about international development of poor countries may
 be a proxy for this power play about the shape of the world economy.

 Chris Burford

 London




Re: strong dollar

2002-01-28 Thread Peter Dorman



In the narrow sense, the strength of the dollar can be attributed to the
weakness of other currencies, especially the yen and the euro. The
downward pressure on those two will continue for some time, I think.
If there were a viable rival to the dollar, "fundamentals" (the chronic
US current account deficit) would express themselves much sooner.
In a larger perspective, US foreign policy has been run to create the
structural conditions for continuing the dollar as the reserve/key currency.
It's not so simple, of course, but I think that's the main effect.
If/when the dollar falls, it will set off a political crisis of succession
as severe perhaps as the economic crisis.
I agree that it is good to be hawkish on worker rights and to recognize
that this is just a small piece of the larger package bearing down on workers
in the North (and South). My guess is that the two biggest pieces
are the permanent debt overhang (and associated addiction to trade surpluses
and inward capital flows) in the third world, and the "liberation" of financial
capital from national regulation. But the importance of the global
collapse of the political left (left parties in power or contending for
power) should not be discounted. (The rightward shift of the social
democrats such that they are no longer really "left" is one aspect of this
collapse.) This collapse is a result of the economic context, but
it also contributes to it.
My whirlwind version of a much longer argument...
Peter


"Stephen F. Diamond" wrote:

Isn't
the strong dollar the effect of foreigners continued, increasing willingness
to invest in dollar assets, as indicated by the 4-500 bn. net capital inflows
into the U.S. economy per annum over the last couple of years? This
would seem to contradict the idea the impact of China. I tend to
think of China, for example, as having a deflationary impact on certain
narrow strands of the economy, particularly characterized as having reached
near-commodity like production standards requiring relatively less sophisticated
labor. Though I am a hawk on advocating international labor rights, particularly
in China, I am not in agreement that that is somehow the most dominant
issue facing organized labor in the U.S. or Europe, relative to the dramatic
restructuring of the jobs that remain and in light of the fact that something
like 70% of cross border capital flows are between the triad countries.





Re: precautionary principle

2002-01-25 Thread Peter Dorman

Thanks for the plug, Jim.  At another point in the manuscript, I mention in
passing the role of Frank Knight in developing the distinction between risk and
fundamental uncertainty.  Knight's claim was that entrepreneurship is the
specialty of people with an abnormal tolerance for plunging into the unknown.
The system depends on the supply of such entrepreneurs who will put their (or
other folks') money on the line, even when accountants haven't a clue what's
going on.  In the case of Enron, however, the murky accounting appears to have
been deliberate.  All debate over Knightian entrepreneurship aside, there is no
evidence of it here.  (The more that comes out, the more the whole business
begins to look like a vast, interconnected Ponzi scam.  Look at the story in
the NYT today about the secret investment fund marketed on Wall St., which
paid dividends out of all proportion to the actual underlying returns.)

Peter

Devine, James wrote:

 reading a manuscript, I came upon the precautionary principle, defined as
 saying that when an activity raises threats of harm to the enviornment or
 human health, precautionary measures should be taken even if some cause and
 effect relationships are not fully established scientifically (from the
 Wingspread statement of 1998). (pen-l's Peter Dorman had an interesting
 paper on this subject at the recent URPE@ASSA conference.)

 The Enron and dot.con melt-downs suggest that a similar principle should be
 applied to accounting (in the face of new corporate forms that stretch
 traditional accounting norms).

 But can capitalism -- which centers on the aggressive accumulate-to-compete
 or compete-to-accumulate principle -- ever follow any precautionary
 principle without strict governmental restrictions?

 Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]   http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine




Re: RE: precautionary principle

2002-01-25 Thread Peter Dorman

Mat,

How do you deal with the argument that the apparent tradeoff between growth
(or full employment) and the environment is due to the failure of full cost
internalization?  The standard neoclassical position is that, for markets to
function properly, they have to reflect true social costs and benefits.
Without the polluter pays principle in effect (ideally enforced through
markets for eco-externalities), we don't have a true market solution.

I have my own problems with this argument, but I wonder what your take is?

Peter

Forstater, Mathew wrote:

 Jim, I have thought about this recently and come to the conclusion that,
 first, unregulated or badly regulated capitalism is both
 macroeconomically unsatisfactory and environmentally unsustainable.
 Second, traditional policy approaches to both unemployment and
 environmental degradation are insufficient to achieve either
 satisfactory macro outcomes (e.g., full employment) or ecological
 sustainability.  Moreover, policy approaches addressing either one of
 these (either full employment or environmental sustainability), even if
 successful, actually in most cases exacerbate the other one.  So, e.g.,
 attempting to achieve full employment through stimulating aggregate
 demand if successful would probably increase resource depletion and
 pollution.  So it may be that 'sustainable capitalism' really is an
 oxymoron.  Mainstream economics usually says that problems like
 discrimination or environmental degradation are due to market forces
 (e.g., competition) not being strong enough or associated institutions
 (e.g., private property) not being widespread enough.  But it is much
 more likely that, as you suggest, these are the normal outcomes of a
 capitalist system.  So the government intervention necessary to address
 these problems would probably be of a kind and of a degree that the
 resulting system would be something many would not define as capitalism.
 So the questions really come back to those that have long been at the
 heart of debates concerning socialism and communism and even various
 forms of anarchism: Is there any role for markets at all in a
 post-capitalist economy? Is there any role for money in a
 post-capitalist economy? Can a post-capitalist economy be attained
 without violence? Would a socialist society *necessarily* be
 environmentally sustainable (or non-racist or non-sexist)?  And so on.
 Mat




Re: RE: Re: RE: precautionary principle

2002-01-25 Thread Peter Dorman

Thanks!  Could you post some specific references for Ravetz and Funtowicz?
I agree with a lot (I think most) of the specifics you raise, but such a
diffuse critique runs the risk of not communicating itself beyond the small
circle of people who go through the whole thing systematically.  Is there a
bumper sticker version?

Peter

Forstater, Mathew wrote:

 Hi Peter -

 I have taken a multi-pronged approach that includes arguments about
 valuation problems (criticisms of contingent valuation, travel cost, and
 other methods); an alternative view of social costs based on Kapp's work
 that includes cumulative causation; critique of optimality notions
 based on preferences, productivity, and profitability (all narrowly
 defined) and the inability of cost-benefit solutions to fully consider
 what I call biophysical conditions for a sustainable economy;
 critiques of neoclassical-Coasian-'tragedy of the commons' notions of
 'property' and historical evidence concerning forms of property and the
 social institutions that mediate resource use; knowledge problems
 concerning human impact on the environment under conditions of radical
 or fundamental uncertainty (do you know the work of Ravetz and
 Funtowicz, by the way, some of the best stuff on this I know of?);
 alternative theories of price and value and critiques of neoclassical
 price theory; emphasis on the distinction between cost-benefit and
 cost-effectiveness analyses; etcetera, etcetera, etcetera.

 If by the time I'm done my opponents are not convinced, at least they
 are worn out or asleep.

 I admit that I have made some mistakes in the past (wow!) and have had
 to modify some of my claims.

 Once when I was giving a job talk for a position that was a joint appt
 in economics and environmental studies, after a long day of individual
 and group interviews with faculty and students of both programs, after
 going through all the above, elaborating during a long q and a period,
 someone in the audience asked me: but why does it matter if humanity
 survives [or survives longer than the amount of time it will take to
 wear out the earth if we continue on the present path]?

 Mat




John Culbertson

2001-12-16 Thread Peter Dorman

I'd like to put in a word for John Culbertson, whose death was reported
today in the New York Times.  John was one of two economics faculty who
influenced me when I was an undergraduate at the University of Wisconsin
-- without them, I doubt I would have had any interest in advanced
study.  I worked independently with Culbertson, who by that point (mid
1970s) was a Wisconsin Institutionalist, in spirit if not by
self-identification.  He was open-minded and willing to hear me out, no
matter how unorthodox my take on the subject matter.  Naturally, he
existed at the margins of the department -- all the flurry of grad
student activity bypassed his office, which was filled with books on
history and politics as well as economics.  His style was calm,
reflective and perpetually curious.

It's good he was part of the generation that entered the economics
profession in the 1940s and 50s.  There's no room for his kind any more.

Peter




Re: Re: RE: Re: Project for Pen-l

2001-12-05 Thread Peter Dorman

More generally, pricing to market is an important aspect of the critique of
trade theory.  There is plenty of empirical evidence for it, although the theory
is underdeveloped.  Assuming that this is a tool that can be used by global
oligopolists, its effects are likely to be asymmetric, as Michael says.

Peter

Michael Yaffey wrote:Gains may be assymetric because in manufactured goods there
is much

 more chance of manufacturers controlling prices down the chain,
 certainly to the cif level and maybe even retail, whereas farmers do
 not succeed in doing that. I did a survey on import price determination
 in Tanzania once in this very framework. In such a situation there is no
 possibility of free trade based on comparative advantage. The choice
 is between what I might call hegemonic free trade and intervention in
 the sectors concerned. What Peter has in mind is really a special case.

 Michael Yaffey




Re: Addition to last post...

2001-12-04 Thread Peter Dorman

Ken Hanly wrote:

 The second defense, pursued by Hicks (1941), was that even if the losers do
 not get compensated in the move, they might still benefit in the long-run
 if the criteria were followed consistently by society.   This argument is
 similar to that of trickle-down theory and in arguments for  free trade:
 some people may be worse off in the short-run, but in the long run, everyone
 will be better off.The underlying assumption, of course,  is that at
 some point, those who lost utility initially will come across a possible
 move in which they benefit and a society which follows the Kaldorian rule
 will move to it and thus they will gain in the end.Of course, as Little
 (1950) notes, this is completely hypothetical.   There is nothing to
 guarantee that there will eventually be a move in which the initial losers
 will be the ultimate winners.

My understanding is that this argument takes the following form: We conduct many
policy analyses.  In any given analysis, there is no justification for acting on
the potential pareto principle.  But as long as the beneficiaries of all the
various policies are more or less evenly distributed across society, the
combined result of applying this principle is to achieve something close to
pareto optimality.  People who say this imply that the burden of proof is on
critics to demonstrate that the same folks tend to be on the winning side across
the policy universe.

It seems clear to me that having lots of money and therefore running up the
market value of your preferences is exactly the sort of systemic bias that
undermines this argument.

Peter




Re: free trade CORRECTED YET AGAIN

2001-12-04 Thread Peter Dorman

For a more elaborate version of this critique, see the work of Metcalfe
and Steedman (lots of articles from the 1970s).

In this instance, it isn't clear why (a) absolute advantage is invoked or
(b) what the criterion is for evaluating trade.

(a) Comparative advantage depends on exchange rates in any model with
wages (such as this).

(b) The case for comparative advantage is potential pareto improvement
relative to autarchy.  Why doesn't this apply here.  (Note: advantage for
capitalists is not the criterion; rather, trade theory depends on a
calculation in which society is treated like one giant ant colony.)

Peter

Rakesh Bhandari wrote:

 oops i made another small error; here's the corrected version. i
 basically had to change the entry for English cloth production in my
 example of hours paid. sorry for the confusion. i am sure much better
 examples, with real perverse results, could be developed to make the
 point that I am trying to get across. Back to work.

 Taking my inspiration from Carchedi's For Another Europe.

 Ricardo's comparative advantage in terms of HOURS OF LABOR

   Port  Eng
 Wine 80120
 Cloth90100

 So it is more convenient for England to produce 2 units of clothing
 (for a total cost of 200 hours) and trade one unit of clothing for
 one unit of Portuguese wine.

 But let's now introduce Marx's concepts of the composition of capital
 and labor power.

 So let's say that in england t that capitalists only pay workers for
 half the labor that they perform--suppose that there is a huge
 reserve army of labor and maximum wage laws to boot and no
 exploitation in Portugal.   That is, the v advanced in England is
 only half the labor actually performed; the rate of exploitation is
 100%.

 Marx's comparative advantage in terms of HOURS OF LABOR PAID.

   PortEng
 Wine 80 (40c +  40v)75 (30c + 45v)
 Cloth90 (50c  + 40v)75 (50c + 25v)

 We can see that if English capitalists pay for the actual hours of
 labor performed, then England needs 120 hours for a bottle of wine
 (30 c + 90 v) and 100 hours  (50c + 50v) for a piece of cloth. But
 the British masters actually only pay for 75 hours (30c + 45 v) and
 75 hours (50c c + 25v)  in the production of wine and cloth
 respectively.

 Now absolute advantage shifts to England.

 For Portugual it would still be convenient (or labor saving) to
 produce 2 units of wine and trade one bottle for a unit of English
 cloth. But for the English capitalists there is nothing to be gained
 any longer from comparative advantage. In fact given the short term
 transitional costs implicit in a shift to an all cloth economy the
 english capitalists  would suffer a net loss by specialized trade
 around the principle of comparative advantage.

 Ricardo should have recognized that the exploitation of labor can
 prove to be an impediment to the rational saving of labor by means of
 trade. But he did not develop the distinction between labor and labor
 power.

 Rakesh




Re: Re: Re: free trade CORRECTED YET AGAIN

2001-12-04 Thread Peter Dorman

What you need to show is that, at an exchange rate that permits balanced trade,
there is not a set of voluntary trades (willingly entered into by the owners of
the respective commodities) that would produce a potential pareto improvement
in at least one country with no potential pareto loss in the other.

In pure production models (without relations of production), the implicit
exchange rate is 1:1 in labor hours.  As soon as you distinguish between hours
of work and commodity price (due to variable rates of exploitation), you need
to specify the exchange rate explicitly.  Incidentally, it is not necessarily
the capitalists who trade.  The capitalists may sell their output to trading
houses which then engage in trade (as was the Japanese case).  If your model is
properly specified, this should not make any difference.

Peter

Rakesh Bhandari wrote:

 What I am saying is that there is the possibility that trade that
 would deliver potential pareto improvement from the perspective of
 social labor may not have any such benefits for the capitalists. Is
 it possible to show this?

 Rakesh




Re: Re: Re: Re: Re: free trade CORRECTED YET AGAIN

2001-12-04 Thread Peter Dorman

Rakesh,

Could the Portuguese workers' collectives agree to exchange their wine
for slightly labor hour equivalence in British cloth?  This would still
enable them to procure their goods at slightly less labor cost.  And
would the British owners of cloth agree to this, seeing that they would
come out slightly ahead?

By the way, the point about trading companies was simply to emphasize
that the Ricardian moment is one of pure exchange; profit in
production is not at issue.  (Note: this is Ricardian trade theory
only.  There is some allowance for production in the 20th century
version.)

Peter




Re: RE: project for Pen-l

2001-12-02 Thread Peter Dorman

Eric,

I agree that the static case for free trade (in mainstream theory) provides a
one-time only increase in income.  There is also a dynamic case, which we haven't
discussed here, and which mainstreamers have come to rely on as the main argument.
The dynamic boost (whatever it might actually be) is viewed as ongoing.

And I agree completely that the pattern of trade is not in dispute -- you would see
approximately the same pattern with or without comparative advantage (which is to
say without or with absolute advantage).  Mainstream empirical work does not
distinguish between these two.  (But empirical work on forex markets does falsify
the assumptions about price equilibration, no?)  We are really concerned with the
effects of trade liberalization, both in the narrow economic sense (macro
instability for instance) and the broader political-economic sense.  I think we are
on the same page.

Peter

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 Mainstream theory does not necessarily claim that free trade should lead to a
 higher growth rate; at best it indicates a one-time increase in output due to
 reallocation of production internationally.

 By a fundamental challenge (referred to by Peter) is it meant that a
 fundamentally different theory of the EFFECTS of trade or a fundamentally
 different theory of the causes of the PATTERN of TRADE? Or both?

 The (potentially detrimental) effect of international trade on domestic
 economic and non-economic institutions are what I am most concerned about.

 Eric




Re: RE: project for Pen-l

2001-12-02 Thread Peter Dorman

Applied economics is based almost entirely on the potential pareto principle.  A
prime example is cost-benefit analysis.

Peter

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 Ken writes,

 I'm not an economist but my understanding of traditional
 welfare economics is that there would be an increase in
 welfare as long as there is a potential pareto improvement.

 By definition a pareto improvement helps some and doesn't hurt anyone. Only
 actual pareto improvements clearly improve welfare.

 Potential pareto improvements are not welfare improving. Saying that the gains
 exceed the loses and, so, that social welfare improves requires, first,
 interpersonal utility comparisions and, second, that you make more-or-less
 arbitary assumptions about how to weight individual utilities to aggregate up
 to a social welfare function.

 Interpersonal utility comparisions have been rejected by mainstream welfare
 economics for decades. Arbitary weightings of individuals' utilities functions
 are, well, arbitary and unsupported by any aspect of mainstream welfare
 economics.

 Others on the list are more knowledgeable about mainstream welfare economics
 and I hope they correct me if I'm wrong.

 Eric




Re: RE: project for Pen-l

2001-12-02 Thread Peter Dorman

My list:

1. Comparative advantage, if correct, refutes the race to the bottom idea.  It is
a very powerful concept.

2. Moreover, if comparative advantage is correct, those who understand it have a
moral imperative to shout down, buy off or otherwise overcome the resistance of
those who oppose free trade.  It is a theory with a mission.

3. The case for free trade (and comparative advantage) is, in the end, the same as
the case for free markets in general.

4. The arguments against free markets (market failure, path dependence) are, for
the most part, also arguments against free trade.

5. Comparative advantage relies on stringent assumptions regarding the trade
account which are falsified by experience.  In the real world, advantage is likely
to be absolute.  Thus the criticisms of labor and environmentalists have merit
after all.

6. The financial mechanisms that are responsible for advantage not being
comparative are also responsible for free trade systems being macroeconomically
unstable.  In other words, chronic trade imbalances exacerbate destabilizing
capital flows.

7. There is an important counter-tradition in economics associated with
nationalist trade policy.  It begins in the US with Hamilton, continues with List
(Germany) and includes 20th century Japanese policy.  It is different in important
respects from the newer social critique of free trade.

8. Modern trade agreements are about much more than trade.  They are wide-ranging
attempts to commoditize as much of the economic sphere as possible.

This is an ambitious list.  I can get to most of this in a two-quarter program in
political economy, but in other situations I have to pick  choose.  My rice and
beans game, for example, really addresses only 1 and 5 (with a tad of 6).

Peter

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 Peter wrote,

 An alternative approach would be to think about the general
 concepts we would like our students to take with them
 (i.e. a useful and mostly correct theory of trade)

 Okay, Peter, spill the beans ... what general concepts do you think students
 need to know?

 If I had a list it would likely include:

 -every international trade change leads to winners and losers;
 -institutions that can be constructed within a single domestic country can be
 undercut when a move to free trade occurs. Some of these institutions promote
 social justice;
 -exchange rate changes that are unrelated to anything fundamental can cause big
 changes in the pattern of trade;
 -capital is generally much more moble than is labor. This can have big
 consequences for the bargaining power between K and L
 -In an era in which businesses are so internationalized, it is not clear that
 US citizens benefit from supporting businesses than happen to be headquartered
 in the US. (Link to Reich's article Who is Us?)

 Eric




Re: RE: project for Pen-l

2001-12-02 Thread Peter Dorman

 Is there anything else the mainstream has mentioned as a source of dynamic
 benefit to trade? I'm not sure that much empirical evidence supporting these
 claims have been offered.

The main argument, at least for developed economies, seems to be the beneficial
effects of competition.  LDCs are supposed to benefit from technology transfer.
There is a huge literature on this, which I haven't pretended to keep up with.
(Unlike the other literatures I do pretend to keep up with...)  I've made a rather
different argument, that technology has become international in a sense that has
little historical precedent.  The training of engineers, the types of equipment
used, and so on, has been largely standardized.  Techniques bounce back and forth
in an almost frictionless way across borders.  The division of labor in innovation
(the interconnected flow of process and product innovations) is also
international.  Thus a high degree of openness is a precondition for participating
in the technologically advanced sectors of the economy.  This is an inescapable
argument for a certain type of liberalization, although it doesn't follow that
unmanaged trade is a good idea, either nationally or globally.  I sketched some of
the evidence for this view in an article I wrote several years ago, Actually
Existing Globalization.


 We are really concerned with the effects of trade liberalization,
 both in the narrow economic sense (macro instability for instance)
 and the broader political-economic sense.

 I'm with you on that.

 However, I think a good argument can be made that institutional differences
 between countries can shape the pattern of trade.

Yes, you've studied that, so I'll defer.  But can your approach be distinguished
empirically from the neoclassical endowments-and-preferences model?


 Eric

Peter




Re: RE: project for Pen-l

2001-12-01 Thread Peter Dorman

I realize that the non-compensation angle is one that can be pursued.  It has the
advantage of gaining sympathy from the more humane wing of mainstream econ.  I
think it concedes too much, however, and politically it is not too convincing.  We
are essentially saying, according to this argument, that economic growth should be
slowed because we haven't succeeded in compensating the losers from
growth-enhancing policies.  People will say, instead of shooting yourself in the
foot, why not enact the right trade policies and then institute programs for
displaced workers, etc.?  (I once had a job writing checks under the Trade
Readjustment Act, which did exactly that, albeit not enough.)

I advocate making a more fundamental challenge.

Peter

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 How can one rebut the claim that free trade is the best policy?

 A purely internal critique of this claim:

 Mainstream theory itself argues that free trade is the best policy only if very
 specific conditions exist. If these conditions do not exist, then mainstream
 theory indicates that we can't say that free trade is the best policy.

 For instance, mainstream trade theory indicates that any move to free trade
 will lead to some people losing out. Mainstream theory also makes clear that
 unless those who lose from trade are fully and completely compensated for their
 losses, then free trade does not benefit a nation.

 That is, mainstream theory does not say that free trade is the best policy.
 Rather, it says that free trade plus the full compensation of those who have
 lost out is the best policy.

 Eric




Re: what's the point?

2001-12-01 Thread Peter Dorman

An alternative approach would be to think about the general concepts we would like our 
students to take with them (i.e. a useful and mostly correct theory of trade) and then 
spend too much time trying to figure out a way to bring these concepts down to the 
introductory level, using case studies, games and simulations, etc.  That's how I do 
it...

Peter

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 Peter Dorman asks: But then what's the point, Jim?  That neoclassicals have a 
better handle on stuff than Ricardo did?  I'm sure you don't mean this, but I don't 
know what you do mean.

 The point depends on one's purpose: if one is simply doing theoretical and/or 
empirical research in trade theory, I agree that Ricardo should be dumped. On the 
other hand, if one has to present a simple trade theory to undergraduate students, 
who are totally opposed to anything that smacks of theory or abstraction (especially 
the biz majors), I see nothing wrong with starting with Ricardo, presenting such 
stuff as the role of migration  dynamic comparative advantage. BTW, one can use 
Ricardo to discuss Shaikh.
 Jim Devine

 _
 The simple way to read all your emails at ThatWeb
 http://www.thatweb.com




Re: RE:Re: what's the point?

2001-12-01 Thread Peter Dorman

There really isn't a good book, at least none that I know of.  I will take specific 
horror stories that advocacy groups tell -- runaway plants, sweatshops, etc. -- and 
try to get students to work through them theoretically.  (What is the mainstream 
economics story?  What specific outcomes would you expect to see if that story were 
true?  What seem to be the weak
links in that story?  What other story would make sense of the example, be logically 
consistent, etc.?)

I also have a game, rice and beans, which I've mentioned on this list before.  I'm 
going to be revising it again for my class next quarter; it's still rather cumbersome 
and difficult to play in a 1 1/2 hour time frame.  The game illustrates the 
consequences for a country's economy and its environment of a switch in the rules of 
the game from comparative to
absolute advantage based on different assumptions about international borrowing.

Peter

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 Peter writes:An alternative approach would be to think about the general concepts 
we would like our students to take with them (i.e. a useful and mostly correct theory 
of trade) and then spend too much time trying to figure out a way to bring these 
concepts down to the introductory level, using case studies, games and simulations, 
etc.  That's how I do it...

 I'd like to see how you do it. what book do you use? -- JD

 _
 The simple way to read all your emails at ThatWeb
 http://www.thatweb.com




Re: RE:Re: RE: project for Pen-l

2001-12-01 Thread Peter Dorman

Right, Jim.  I think you've just rediscovered social democracy ;)

Peter

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 Peter writes:I realize that the non-compensation angle [i.e., that the global 
gains from trade correspond to losses by many and the latter are never given the 
compensation that they could to make up for those losses] is one that can be pursued. 
It has the advantage of gaining sympathy from the more humane wing of mainstream 
econ. I
 think it concedes too much, however, and politically it is not too convincing. We 
are essentially saying, according to this argument, that economic growth should be 
slowed because we haven't succeeded in compensating the losers from 
growth-enhancing policies.

 a thought: one way of thinking of Marx's theory of exploitation is as a theory of 
non-compensation, i.e., the  non-payment of workers in compensation for their losses 
when capitalist relations of production (not just markets) change, even those that 
compensation could _in theory_ be paid. This fits with Marx's view that capitalism 
does raise the total ability of humanity to produce.  -- JD

 _
 The simple way to read all your emails at ThatWeb
 http://www.thatweb.com




Re: Project for Pen-l

2001-11-30 Thread Peter Dorman

I've been following this discussion with interest.  It's a good topic
for Pen-l -- constructive  useful.  A few thoughts:

1. Forget about Ricardo.  This stuff is interesting from a history of
thought point of view, but modern trade theory differs from Ricardian
theory in important ways.  Some of the criticisms lefties have hurled at
Ricardo bounce off the modern folks.  If you want a point of reference,
pick an influential contemporary textbook -- Salvatore for example.

2. I agree that the critique of global capitalism goes far beyond trade
in goods and services.  So-called trade agreements are now largely about
commoditization, disembedding capital and final output from
social/political constraints.  Some of these constraints are venal or
irrational, but others are necessary, and, in any event, commoditization
usurps the space available for democracy.  Nevertheless, trade theory
itself is vulnerable.  It embodies a laissez-faire ideology that has to
be criticized if we want to take a progressive stand.  Contrary to the
ravings of its accolytes, it is *not* a mathematic truth beyond debate;
it relies on falsifiable assumptions.  We desperately need a
well-written, methodologically sound rebuttal to mainstream trade theory
-- both a high-end critique for our footnotes and a demathematized
critique for our students.

3. In the meantime, here are the concluding paragraphs of a paper I
wrote on Joan Robinson's critique of trade theory:

Excerpt begins here:

In the end, economic persuasion comes down to simple stories—fables,
metaphors, or even bumper stickers—that encapsulate more complicated
visions of how the world does or ought to work.  The doctrine of free,
unregulated trade has succeeded magnificently on this terrain.  Why, we
are asked, should anyone want to interfere with trade?  No trade would
ever take place unless it were in the interest of both parties, so how
can the sum of all such trades be any less than the sum of all those
advantages?  If someone in a foreign country can make a good cheaper
than you can make it at home, why would you be so foolish as to not buy
it?  After all, among local stores you would shop at the one that
charges a lower price.  And the theory of comparative advantage appears
as nothing more than the obvious truth that two people, combining their
efforts and specializing in what they do best, can produce more than
they could singly.

JR would have no trouble recognizing the ideological core of this set of
fables; it is based on the assumption that there are only individuals in
this world of “international” trade—nations have no role.  On the
contrary, however, the division of the world’s people into nations has
always had and still has powerful effects on their well-being, and this
implies a different sort of fable.  The payments position of the
nation’s currency, its rates of economic growth and employment, and the
effectiveness of its democracy are public goods: most individuals
benefit or suffer from them even though they generally have no
individual incentive to promote them.  On the contrary, every time an
individual chooses to import a good, no matter how praiseworthy that act
might otherwise be, he or she is competing with the balance of payments
“space” available to the nation for publicly beneficial actions that can
also have negative payments effects.  There is only so much space
available, and a sensible nation that cared both for its citizens as
private individuals and for their well-being as participants in a shared
life would manage the two demands to enable both to be met tolerably.
To give play only to private interests is to sacrifice public interests
by default.  This is, in other words, simply the Keynesian fable that JR
did so well to promulgate transported to the international level.

On a more analytical note, we have seen that, in the absence of
intervention, it is typically not the case at the margin that an extra
dollop of imports is automatically financed by an extra dollop of
exports, yet this is what would be required in order for trade to adhere
to the principle of comparative advantage.  From a normative standpoint,
however, comparative advantage remains a very good thing, a circumstance
we should attempt to create among all the possible patterns of
international trade and finance.  This suggests that countries would be
wise to manage aggregate trade and capital flows, restoring comparative
advantage at the margin, and restricting or channeling external finance
so that its use in genuinely capacity-enhancing activities is
assured—or, in JR’s own 1946 words, “In short, the notion of a unique
natural position of equilibrium is a mirage, and for better or worse,
international trade must be directed by conscious policy.” (p. 112)

From, Why International Trade Theory Is Not a Theory of International
Trade: A Confirmation of Robinsonian Skepticism, 2000




Re: RE: Re: Project for Pen-l

2001-11-30 Thread Peter Dorman

Devine, James wrote:

 Peter Dorman writes:

 ... Forget about Ricardo.  This stuff is interesting from a history of
 thought point of view, but modern trade theory differs from Ricardian theory
 in important ways.  Some of the criticisms lefties have hurled at Ricardo
 bounce off the modern folks...

 however, Ricardo may be relevant to pedagogy. For example, it is really easy
 to explain the standard 2x2 Ricardian matrix and then say: what happens if
 Portugal decides to _change_ its comparative advantage? (Why should the
 secretary put up with specializing in filing, typing, etc.? why not learn
 how to be a boss?) in addition to this issue of dynamic comparative
 advantage, how about: suppose that some of the workers from Portugal _move
 to_ England, so that the labor productivity numbers apply to them. Then it's
 easy to show that the rise in the production in England exceeds the loss of
 production in Portugal (unless there extreme diminishing returns to labor,
 so that England's labor productivity falls and Portugal's rise,
 significantly).

But this was my point.  Mobility of capital (and therefore endogenous changes in
cost structures) and labor are built into the modern theory.  There are models
with one, the other and both.  And Krugman et al. have introduced economies of
scale and agglomeration, first mover advantage, etc.  Unless your critique
stands up to those models, you are not really debating neoclassical trade
theory.

Peter




Re: Re: Project for Pen-l

2001-11-30 Thread Peter Dorman

It would be interesting to have a discussion about the merits of the new trade
theory.  My opinion as of now is that there is not much there for progressives.  At
best, this theory shows how one part of the world can profit at the expense of
another.  Wonderful.  And, as the theorists say as they backpedal, optimal
protection has little room for error, and it is unlikely that real-world
governments would design their policies so objectively and precisely.  This may be
an exaggeration, but, in the end, I think the new trade theory will go down in
history as an opportunity for some folks at publish or perish institutions to get a
few more articles in print.

Peter

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 Peter wrote
Contrary to the ravings of its accolytes, [international
trade theory] is *not* a mathematic truth beyond debate...

 I haven't followed mainstream trade theory for about 15 years and, so I'm very
 out-of-date. All mainstream theories are moving targets and change constantly.
 But I think it is possible that the top mainstream trade theorists don't
 believe in the proof of the benefits of free trade.

 It seems to me that since the mid-1960s are large mainstream literature has
 developed which shows that, in principle, many types of trade interventions
 might benefit a country. Support for free trade from mainstream trade
 theorists comes mostly from their political theory -- that interest groups will
 hijack any trade intervention to help themselves at the expense of the nation.

 The problem is, however, that when any big name economist is trotted out in
 front of the public they CLAIM they support free trade for economic reasons
 when, in fact, I believe they are lying. They know the economic support for
 trade trade just ain't there. But to keep their membership in the AEA they know
 they have to claim economic support for free trade.

 Some have said, I think--or maybe I imagined this--, that if we tell people in
 public that some trade interventions might benefit the nation then we won't be
 able to stop the flood gates from opening and mostly bad trade interventions
 will happen due to interest group power. As a result the responsible thing to
 do is to lie to the public about the wonders of free trade.

 Eric




Re: Re: RE: Re: Project for Pen-l

2001-11-30 Thread Peter Dorman

As far as I know, Gar, trade theory is still in a comparative static world, so
speed of adjustment issues don't arise.  Does anyone know if recursive analysis or
other dynamic techniques have been applied to trade?

Peter

Gar Lipow wrote:

 It strikes me that there is an information  theory critique possible of
 too free a market in capital flows that may be supplementary to the
 other  criticims. (This applies to both international and national
 capital markets.) If markets are looked at as feedback mechanisms, then
 you have a problem anytime the capability for feedback exceeds the
 ability to respond. For example capital can be pulled out of firms, or
 entire nations or entire regions in a matter of minutes. But the actual
 means of production -- even in service industries -- cannot shift nearly
 so fast.  So it is like driving a car with an oversensitive steering
 mechanism, so that you cannot drive inside the lines, because the
 slightest pressure on the wheel takes you across four lane. Is this at a
 all a useful supplementary critique? Is this one of arguments used for
 the Tobin tax? Is there some standard economic term for excessive feedback?

 Devine, James wrote:

  Peter Dorman writes:
 
 
 ... Forget about Ricardo.  This stuff is interesting from a history of
 
  thought point of view, but modern trade theory differs from Ricardian theory
  in important ways.  Some of the criticisms lefties have hurled at Ricardo
  bounce off the modern folks...
 
  however, Ricardo may be relevant to pedagogy. For example, it is really easy
  to explain the standard 2x2 Ricardian matrix and then say: what happens if
  Portugal decides to _change_ its comparative advantage? (Why should the
  secretary put up with specializing in filing, typing, etc.? why not learn
  how to be a boss?) in addition to this issue of dynamic comparative
  advantage, how about: suppose that some of the workers from Portugal _move
  to_ England, so that the labor productivity numbers apply to them. Then it's
  easy to show that the rise in the production in England exceeds the loss of
  production in Portugal (unless there extreme diminishing returns to labor,
  so that England's labor productivity falls and Portugal's rise,
  significantly).
 
 
 In the end, economic persuasion comes down to simple stories-fables,
 
  metaphors, or even bumper stickers-that encapsulate more complicated visions
  of how the world does or ought to work.  The doctrine of free, unregulated
  trade has succeeded magnificently on this terrain.  Why, we are asked,
  should anyone want to interfere with trade?  No trade would ever take place
  unless it were in the interest of both parties, so how can the sum of all
  such trades be any less than the sum of all those advantages?  If someone in
  a foreign country can make a good cheaper than you can make it at home, why
  would you be so foolish as to not buy it?  After all, among local stores you
  would shop at the one that charges a lower price.  And the theory of
  comparative advantage appears as nothing more than the obvious truth that
  two people, combining their efforts and specializing in what they do best,
  can produce more than they could singly.
 
  one comment -- which is quite in line with Joan Robinson's ideas as Peter
  explained them -- is that the discussion above refers not to gains from
  trade _per se_ but to gains from specialization and cooperation. A simple
  analysis of solutions to the economic problem suggests that trade need not
  be the only solution: we could also rely on command (state control) or
  tradition. Further, I add decentralized command (mafias, corporations,
  etc.) and decentralized or grass-roots democracy to the list, while
  combinations are possible, such as grass-roots democratic control of the
  state.
 
  Jim Devine
 
 
 




Re: RE: project for Pen-l

2001-11-30 Thread Peter Dorman

Eric,

Absolute advantage matters enormously, because that's the basis for the race to the
bottom argument.  In a comparative advantage world, such a race is impossible.

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 I'm uncertain of the importance of arguing for absolute advantage. Such
 arguments might fall into a false dilemma--you're either for comparative
 advantage or for absolute advantage. And, I guess the underlying argument is,
 that since the neoclassicals have claimed comparative advantage we must take
 the other side, absolute advantage.




  1   2   3   4   5   6   >